![]() Cover of the first UK edition | |
Author | Friedrich Hayek |
---|---|
Language | English |
Subject | Political science,economics |
Published |
|
Publication place | United Kingdom |
Media type | |
Pages | 266 |
ISBN | 0-226-32061-8 |
OCLC | 30733740 |
338.9 20 | |
LC Class | HD82 .H38 1994 |
The Road to Serfdom is a book by the Austrian-Britisheconomist andphilosopherFriedrich Hayek. In the book, Hayek"[warns] of the danger oftyranny that inevitably results from government control of economicdecision-making throughcentral planning."[1] He further argues that the abandonment ofindividualism andclassical liberalism inevitably leads to a loss offreedom, the creation of an oppressive society, the tyranny of adictator, and theserfdom of the individual. Hayek challenged the view, popular among British Marxists, thatfascism (includingNazism) was acapitalist reaction againstsocialism. He argued that fascism, Nazism, and state-socialism had common roots in central economic planning and empowering the state over the individual.
Since its publication in 1944,The Road to Serfdom has been popular amongliberal (especiallyclassical liberal) andconservative thinkers.[2] It has been translated into more than 20 languages and sold over two million copies (as of 2010).[3][4][5] The book was first published in Britain byRoutledge in March 1944, duringWorld War II, and was quite popular, leading Hayek to call it "that unobtainable book", also due in part to wartime paper rationing.[6] It was published in the United States by theUniversity of Chicago Press in September 1944 and achieved great popularity. At the arrangement of editorMax Eastman, the American magazineReader's Digest published an abridged version in April 1945, enablingThe Road to Serfdom to reach a wider non-academic audience.
The Road to Serfdom was to be the popular edition of the second volume of Hayek's treatise entitled "The Abuse and Decline of Reason",[7] and the title was inspired by the writings of the 19th century French classical liberal thinkerAlexis de Tocqueville on the "road to servitude".[8] Initially written as a response to thereport written byWilliam Beveridge, theLiberal politician and dean of theLondon School of Economics where Hayek worked at the time, the book made a significant impact on 20th-century political discourse, especially Americanconservative andlibertarian economic and political debate.
While a professor at theLondon School of Economics in the early 1930s – in the era of theGreat Depression, the rise of autocracies inRussia,Italy andGermany, andWorld War II – Hayek wrote a memo toWilliam Beveridge, then the director there, to dispute the then-popular claim thatfascism represented the dying gasp of a failedcapitalist system. The memo grew into a magazine article, and he intended to incorporate elements of the article into a book much larger thanThe Road to Serfdom. However, he ultimately decided to writeThe Road to Serfdom as its own book.
The book was originally published for a British audience byRoutledge Press in March 1944 in the United Kingdom. The book was subsequently rejected by three publishers in the United States,[9] and it was only after economistAaron Director spoke to friends at the University of Chicago that the book was published in the U.S by theUniversity of Chicago Press on September 18, 1944.[10][11] The American publisher's expectation was that the book would sell between 900 and 3,000 copies. However, the initial printing run of 2,000 copies was quickly sold out, and 30,000 copies were sold within six months. In 2007[update], the University of Chicago Press estimated that more than 350,000 copies had been sold.[12]
A 20-page version of the book was then published in the April 1945 issue ofReader's Digest,[13] with a press run of several million copies. A 95-page abridged version was also published in 1945 and 1946.[14] In February 1945, a picture-book version was published inLook magazine, later made into apamphlet and distributed byGeneral Motors.[15] The book has been translated into approximately 20 languages and is dedicated "To thesocialists of allparties". The introduction to the 50th anniversary edition is written byMilton Friedman (another recipient of theNobel Prize in Economics 1976).
In 2007, the University of Chicago Press issued a "Definitive Edition", Volume 2 in theCollected Works of F. A. Hayek series. In June 2010, the book achieved new popularity by rising to the top of theAmazon.com bestseller list following extended coverage of the book onThe Glenn Beck Program. Since that date, it has sold another 250,000 copies in its print and digital editions.
Hayek argues thatWestern democracies, including theUnited Kingdom and theUnited States, have "progressively abandoned that freedom in economic affairs without which personal and political freedom has never existed in the past".[16] Society has mistakenly tried to ensure continuing prosperity by centralized planning, which inevitably leads to totalitarianism. "We have in effect undertaken to dispense with the forces which produced unforeseen results and to replace the impersonal and anonymous mechanism of the market by collective and 'conscious' direction of all social forces to deliberately chosen goals."[17] Socialism, while presented as a means of assuring equality, does so through "restraint and servitude", while "democracy seeks equality in liberty".[18] Planning, because it is coercive, is an inferior method of regulation, while the competition of afree market is superior "because it is the only method by which our activities can be adjusted to each other without the coercive or arbitrary intervention of authority".[19]
Centralized planning is inherently undemocratic in Hayek's view, because it requires "that the will of a small minority be imposed upon the people".[20] The power of these minorities to act by taking money or property in pursuit of centralized goals, destroys the Rule of Law and individual freedoms.[21] Where there is centralized planning, "the individual would more than ever become a mere means, to be used by the authority in the service of such abstractions as the 'social welfare' or the 'good of the community'".[22] Even the very poor have more personal freedom in an open society than a centrally planned one.[23] "While the last resort of a competitive economy is thebailiff, the ultimate sanction of a planned economy is the hangman."[24] Socialism is a hypocritical system because its professed humanitarian goals can only be put into practice by brutal methods "of which most socialists disapprove".[25] Such centralized systems also require effective propaganda, so that the people come to believe that the state's goals are theirs.[26]
Hayek argues that the roots of National Socialism lie in socialism,[27] and then draws parallels to the thought of British leaders:
The increasing veneration for the state, the admiration of power, and of bigness for bigness' sake, the enthusiasm for "organization" of everything (we now call it "planning") and that "inability to leave anything to the simple power of organic growth" ... are all scarcely less marked in England now than they were in Germany.[28]
Hayek believed that after World War II, "wisdom in the management of our economic affairs will be even more important than before and that the fate of our civilization will ultimately depend on how we solve the economic problems we shall then face".[29] The only chance to build a decent world is "to improve the general level of wealth" via the activities offree markets.[30] He saw international organization as involving a further threat to individual freedom.[31] He concluded: "The guiding principle that a policy of freedom for the individual is the only truly progressive policy remains as true today as it was in the nineteenth century."[32]
Although Hayek believed that government intervention in markets would lead to a loss of freedom, he recognized a limited role for government to perform tasks for which he believed free markets were not capable:
The successful use of competition as the principle of social organization precludes certain types of coercive interference with economic life, but it admits of others which sometimes may very considerably assist its work and even requires certain kinds of government action.[33]
While Hayek is opposed to regulations that restrict the freedom to enter a trade, or to buy and sell at any price, or to control quantities, he acknowledges the utility of regulations that restrict legal methods of production, so long as these are applied equally to everyone and not used as an indirect way of controlling prices or quantities, and without forgetting the cost of such restrictions:
To prohibit the use of certain poisonous substances, or to require special precautions in their use, to limit working hours or to require certain sanitary arrangements, is fully compatible with the preservation of competition. The only question here is whether in the particular instance, the advantages gained are greater than thesocial costs they impose.[34]
He notes that there are certain areas, such as the environment, where activities that cause damage to third parties (known to economists as "negativeexternalities") cannot effectively be regulated solely by the marketplace:
Nor can certain harmful effects of deforestation, of some methods of farming, or of the smoke and noise of factories, be confined to the owner of the property in question, or to those willing to submit to the damage for an agreed compensation.[35]
The government also has a role in preventing fraud:
Even the most essential prerequisite of its [the market's] proper functioning, the prevention of fraud and deception (including exploitation of ignorance), provides a great and by no means fully accomplished object of legislative activity.[36]
The government also has a role in creating a safety net:
There is no reason why, in a society which has reached the general level of wealth ours has, the first kind of security should not be guaranteed to all without endangering general freedom; that is: some minimum of food, shelter, and clothing, sufficient to preserve health. Nor is there any reason why the state should not help to organize a comprehensive system of social insurance in providing for those common hazards of life against which few can make adequate provision.[37][38]
He concludes: "In no system that could be rationally defended would the state just do nothing."[36]
Since publication, Hayek has offered a number of clarifications on words that are frequently misinterpreted:
In 2007[update], the University of Chicago Press estimated that more than 350,000 copies ofThe Road to Serfdom have been sold.[12] It appears onMartin Seymour-Smith's list of the100 Most Influential Books Ever Written, and it made number 1 on Human Events: Top Ten Books Every Republican Congressman Should Read in 2006.[41] It was influential enough to warrant mention during the1945 British general election, when according toHarold Macmillan,Winston Churchill was "fortified in his apprehensions [of aLabour government] by reading Professor Hayek'sThe Road to Serfdom"[42] when he warned in an election broadcast in 1945 that a socialist system would "have to fall back on some form ofGestapo". The Labour leaderClement Attlee responded in his election broadcast by claiming that what Churchill had said was the "second-hand version of the academic views of an Austrian professor, Friedrich August von Hayek".[43] TheConservative Central Office sacrificed 1.5 tons of their precious paper ration allocated for the 1945 election so that more copies ofThe Road to Serfdom could be printed, although to no avail, as Labour won a landslide victory.[44]
Political historianAlan Brinkley had this to say about the impact ofThe Road to Serfdom:[45]
The publication of two books ... helped to galvanize the concerns that were beginning to emerge among intellectuals (and many others) about the implications oftotalitarianism. One wasJames Burnham'sThe Managerial Revolution ... [A second] Friedrich A. Hayek'sThe Road to Serfdom ... was far more controversial—and influential. Even more than Burnham, Hayek forced into public discourse the question of the compatibility of democracy andstatism ... In responding to Burnham and Hayek ... liberals [in the statist sense of this term as used by some in the United States] were in fact responding to a powerful strain of Jeffersonian anti-statism in American political culture ... The result was a subtle but important shift in liberal [i.e. American statist] thinking.
The Road to Serfdom has been the subject of much praise and much criticism. It was placed fourth on the list of the 100 best non-fiction books of the 20th century[46] compiled byNational Review magazine, was ranked number 16 in reader selections of the hundred best non-fiction book of the twentieth century administered byModern Library,[47] and appears on a recommended reading list for thelibertarian right hosted on thePolitical Compass test website.[48]
John Maynard Keynes said of it: "In my opinion it is a grand book ... Morally and philosophically I find myself in agreement with virtually the whole of it: and not only in agreement with it, but in deeply moved agreement."[49] However, Keynes did not think Hayek's philosophy was ofpractical use; this was explained later in the same letter, commenting: "What we need therefore, in my opinion, is not a change in our economic programmes, which would only lead in practice to disillusion with the results of your philosophy; but perhaps even the contrary, namely, an enlargement of them. Your greatest danger ahead is the probable practical failure of the application of your philosophy in the United States."[50]
George Orwell responded with both praise and criticism, stating, "in the negative part of Professor Hayek's thesis there is a great deal of truth. It cannot be said too often – at any rate, it is not being said nearly often enough – that collectivism is not inherently democratic, but, on the contrary, gives to a tyrannical minority such powers as the Spanish Inquisitors never dreamt of." Yet he also warned, "[A] return to 'free' competition means for the great mass of people a tyranny probably worse, because more irresponsible, than that of the state."[51][52]
Milton Friedman describedThe Road to Serfdom as "one of the great books of our time", and said of it:
I think the Adam Smith role was played in this cycle [i.e. the late twentieth century collapse of socialism in which the idea of free-markets succeeded first, and then special events catalyzed a complete change of socio-political policy in countries around the world] by Friedrich Hayek'sThe Road to Serfdom.[45]
Herman Finer, aFabian socialist, published a rebuttal in hisThe Road to Reaction in 1946. Hayek called Finer's book "a specimen of abuse and invective which is probably unique in contemporary academic discussion".[53]
In his review (collected inThe Present as History, 1953)MarxistPaul Sweezy joked that Hayek would have you believe that if there was an over-production of baby carriages, the central planners would then order the population to have more babies instead of simply warehousing the temporary excess of carriages and decreasing production for next year. Thecybernetic arguments ofStafford Beer in his 1973 CBC Massey Lectures,Designing Freedom[54] – that intelligent adaptive planning can increase freedom – are of interest in this regard, as is the technical work ofHerbert A. Simon andAlbert Ando on the dynamics of hierarchical nearly decomposable systems in economics – namely, that everything in such a system is not tightly coupled to everything else.[55]
Mises Institute economistWalter Block has observed critically that whileThe Road to Serfdom makes a strong case against centrally planned economies, it appears only lukewarm in its support of afree market system andlaissez-fairecapitalism, with Hayek even going so far as to say that "probably nothing has done so much harm to the liberal cause as the wooden insistence of some liberals on certain rules of thumb, above all the principle of laissez-faire capitalism". In the book, Hayek writes that the government has a role to play in the economy through the monetary system (a view that he later withdrew),[56] work-hours regulation, social welfare, and institutions for the flow of proper information. Through analysis of this and many other of Hayek's works, Block asserts that: "in making the case against socialism, Hayek was led into making all sort of compromises with what otherwise appeared to be his own philosophical perspective – so much so, that if a system was erected on the basis of them, it would not differ too sharply from what this author explicitly opposed".[57]
Jeffrey Sachs argues thatempirical evidence suggestswelfare states, with high rates of taxation and social outlays, outperform the comparatively free-market economies.[58]William Easterly wrote a rebuttal criticizing Sachs for misrepresenting Hayek's work and for criticizing the book on issues it did not actually address, such as welfare programs for the elderly or sick, something Hayek did not oppose. Easterly noted thatThe Road to Serfdom was about the dangers of centralized planning and nationalization of industry, including the media.[59] In Sachs' counter-rebuttal, he argued that he was addressing Hayek's foreword in the 1976 adaptation which stated that efforts to bring about large-scale welfare states would bring about serfdom, although much more slowly than under centralized planning. Sachs cited the Nordic states which remained economically free and relatively capitalist, despite a large welfare state that Hayek was wrong about such programs leading to serfdom.[60]
Gordon Tullock has argued Hayek's analysis incorrectly predicted governments in much of Europe in the late 20th century would descend intototalitarianism. He usesSweden, in which the government at that time controlled 63 percent ofGNP, as an example to support his argument that the basic problem withThe Road to Serfdom is "that it offered predictions which turned out to be false. The steady advance of government in places such as Sweden has not led to any loss of non-economic freedoms." While criticizing Hayek, Tullock still praises the classical liberal notion of economic freedom, saying, "Arguments for political freedom are strong, as are the arguments for economic freedom. We needn't make one set of arguments depend on the other."[61] However, according toRobert Skidelsky, Hayek "safeguarded himself from such retrospective refutation". Skidelsky argues that Hayek's argument was contingent, and that, "By the 1970s there was some evidence of the slippery slope ... and then there wasThatcher. Hayek's warning played a critical part in her determination to 'roll back the state.'"[62]
Economic sociologistKarl Polanyi made a case diametrically opposed to Hayek, arguing that unfettered markets had undermined the social order and that economic breakdown had paved the way for the emergence of dictatorship.[63]
Barbara Wootton wroteFreedom under Planning[64] after reading an early copy ofThe Road to Serfdom, provided to her by Hayek. In the introduction to her book, Wootton mentionedThe Road to Serfdom and claimed that "Much of what I have written is devoted to criticism of the views put forward by Professor Hayek in this and other books."[65] The central argument made inFreedom under Planning is that "there is nothing in the conscious planning of economic priorities which is inherently incompatible with the freedoms which mean most to the contemporary Englishman or American.Civil liberties are quite unaffected. We can, if we wish, deliberately plan so as to give the fullest possible scope for the pursuit by individuals and social groups of cultural ends which are in no way state-determined."[66] Wootton criticizes Hayek for claiming that planningmust lead to oppression, when, in her view, that is merely onepossibility among many. She argues that "there seems hardly better case for taking for granted that planning will bring the worst to the top than for the opposite assumption that the seats of office will be filled with angels".[67] Thus, Wootton acknowledges the possibility that planning may exist alongside tyranny but claims that it is equally possible to combine planning with freedom. She concludes that "A happy and fruitful marriage between freedom and planning can, in short, be arranged."[68] However,Frank Knight, founder of theChicago school of economics, disputes the claim thatFreedom under Planning contradictsThe Road to Serfdom. He wrote in a scholarly review of the Wootton book: "Let me repeat that the Wootton book is in no logical sense an answer toThe Road to Serfdom, whatever may be thought of the cogency of Hayek's argument, or the soundness of his position."[69]
Eric Zencey wrote that the free market economy Hayek advocated is designed for an infinite planet, and when it runs into physical limits (as any growing system must), the result is a need for centralized planning to mediate the problematic interface of economy and nature. "Planning is planning, whether it's done to minimizepoverty and injustice, as socialists were advocating then, or to preserve the minimum flow ofecosystem services that civilization requires, as we are finding increasingly necessary today."[70]
On 9 June 2010, the book became the #1 book sold at Amazon.com, achievingbest seller status.
{{cite book}}
:ISBN / Date incompatibility (help){{cite book}}
:ISBN / Date incompatibility (help)