Movatterモバイル変換


[0]ホーム

URL:


Jump to content
WikipediaThe Free Encyclopedia
Search

Sincere favorite criterion

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Criterion that prevents lesser-evil voting
A jointPolitics andEconomics series
Social choice andelectoral systems
iconMathematics portal

Thesincere favorite orno favorite-betrayal criterion is aproperty of some voting systems that says voters should have no incentive to vote for someone else over their favorite.[1] It protects voters from having to engage inlesser-evil voting or a strategy called "decapitation" (removing the "head" off a ballot).[2]

Mostrated voting systems, includingscore voting, satisfy the criterion.[3][4][5]

Duverger's law says that systems vulnerable to this strategy will typically (though not always) developtwo-party systems, as voters will abandon minor-party candidates to support stronger major-party candidates.[6]

US Presidential elections

[edit]

The "sincere favorite criterion" suggests that a voter should always rank their sincere favorite candidate as their top choice, without strategizing based on the likely outcomes. However, in certain voting systems, this strategy can lead to suboptimal results, which makes the criterion less applicable.

The U.S. presidential election is a prime example where voters might avoid using a sincere favorite criterion. This is due to the Electoral College system, which is structured as a "first-past-the-post" (FPTP) election within each state. Here, if a voter's sincere favorite has no realistic chance of winning, it may be rational for them to vote for a more viable candidate to prevent a less preferred option from winning. This is known as "tactical voting."

Several sources discuss how the FPTP system (like the one used in U.S. presidential elections) can disincentivize the use of sincere voting strategies:

1. Gary Cox's "Making Votes Count: Strategic Coordination in the World’s Electoral Systems" explores strategic voting in FPTP systems and how they encourage tactical voting.

2. Steven Brams and Peter Fishburn's "Approval Voting" touches on how non-ranking systems like approval voting can mitigate the issues with sincere voting in FPTP contexts.

3. William H. Riker's "Liberalism against Populism" provides an analysis of the implications of various voting systems on strategic behaviors, including in U.S. elections.

These references can provide a deeper theoretical grounding on why the sincere favorite criterion is frequently not practical in FPTP and U.S. presidential elections.

Definition

[edit]

A voting rule satisfies the sincere favorite criterion if there is never a need to "betray" a perfect candidate—i.e. if a voter will never achieve a worse result by honestly ranking their favorite candidate first.[1]

Arguments for

[edit]

TheCenter for Election Science argues systems that violate the favorite betrayal criterion strongly incentivize voters to cast dishonest ballots, which can make voters feel unsatisfied or frustrated with the results despite having the opportunity to participate in the election.[7][8][9][10]

Other commentators have argued that failing the favorite-betrayal criterion can increase the effectiveness ofmisinformation campaigns, by allowing major-party candidates to sow doubt as to whether voting honestly for one's favorite is actually the best strategy.[11]

Compliant methods

[edit]

Rated voting

[edit]
Main article:Rated voting

Becauserated voting methods are not affected byArrow's theorem, they can be bothspoilerproof (satisfyIIA) and ensurepositive vote weights at the same time. Taken together, these properties imply that increasing the rating of a favorite candidate can never change the result,except by causing the favorite candidate to win; therefore, giving a favorite candidate the maximum level of support is always the optimal strategy.

Examples of systems that are both spoilerproof and monotonic includescore voting,approval voting, andhighest medians.

Anti-plurality voting

[edit]

Interpreted as a ranked voting method where every candidate but the last ranked gets one point,anti-plurality voting passes the sincere favorite criterion. Because there is no incentive to rank one's favorite last, and the method otherwise does not care where the favorite is ranked, the method passes.

Anti-plurality voting thus shows that the sincere favorite criterion is distinct fromindependence of irrelevant alternatives, and that ranked voting methods do not necessarily fail the criterion.

Non-compliant methods

[edit]

Instant-runoff voting

[edit]
See also:Instant-runoff voting

This example shows that instant-runoff voting violates the favorite betrayal criterion. Assume there are four candidates: Amy, Bert, Cindy, and Dan. This election has 41 voters with the following preferences:

# of votersPreferences
10Amy > Bert > Cindy > Dan
6Bert > Amy > Cindy > Dan
5Cindy > Bert > Amy > Dan
20Dan > Amy > Cindy > Bert

Sincere voting

[edit]

Assuming all voters vote in a sincere way, Cindy is awarded only 5 first place votes and is eliminated first. Her votes are transferred to Bert. In the second round, Amy is eliminated with only 10 votes. Her votes are transferred to Bert as well. Finally, Bert has 21 votes and wins against Dan, who has 20 votes.

Votes in round/
Candidate
1st2nd3rd
Amy1010
Bert61121
Cindy5
Dan202020

Result:Bert wins against Dan, after Cindy and Amy were eliminated.

Favorite betrayal

[edit]

Now assume two of the voters who favor Amy (marked bold) realize the situation and insincerely vote for Cindy instead of Amy:

# of votersBallots
2Cindy > Amy > Bert > Dan
8Amy > Bert > Cindy > Dan
6Bert > Amy > Cindy > Dan
5Cindy > Bert > Amy > Dan
20Dan > Amy > Cindy > Bert

In this scenario, Cindy has 7 first place votes and so Bert is eliminated first with only 6 first place votes. His votes are transferred to Amy. In the second round, Cindy is eliminated with only 7 votes. Her votes are transferred to Amy as well. Finally, Amy has 21 votes and wins against Dan, who has 20 votes.

Votes in round/
Candidate
1st2nd3rd
Amy81421
Bert6
Cindy77
Dan202020

Result:Amy wins against Dan, after Bert and Cindy has been eliminated.

By listing Cindy ahead of their true favorite, Amy, the two insincere voters obtained a more preferred outcome (causing their favorite candidate to win). There was no way to achieve this without raising another candidate ahead of their sincere favorite. Thus, instant-runoff voting fails the favorite betrayal criterion.

Condorcet methods

[edit]
[icon]
This section is empty. You can help byadding to it.(May 2024)

See also

[edit]

External links

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^abAlex Small, “Geometric construction of voting methods that protect voters’ first choices,” arXiv:1008.4331 (August 22, 2010),http://arxiv.org/abs/1008.4331.
  2. ^Merrill, Samuel; Nagel, Jack (1987-06-01)."The Effect of Approval Balloting on Strategic Voting under Alternative Decision Rules".American Political Science Review.81 (2):509–524.doi:10.2307/1961964.ISSN 0003-0554.JSTOR 1961964.
  3. ^Baujard, Antoinette; Gavrel, Frédéric; Igersheim, Herrade; Laslier, Jean-François; Lebon, Isabelle (September 2017)."How voters use grade scales in evaluative voting"(PDF).European Journal of Political Economy.55:14–28.doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2017.09.006.ISSN 0176-2680.A key feature of evaluative voting is a form of independence: the voter can evaluate all the candidates in turn ... another feature of evaluative voting ... is that voters can express some degree of preference.
  4. ^Wolk, Sara; Quinn, Jameson; Ogren, Marcus (2023-03-20)."STAR Voting, equality of voice, and voter satisfaction: considerations for voting method reform".Constitutional Political Economy (Journal Article).34 (3):310–334.doi:10.1007/s10602-022-09389-3. Retrieved2023-07-16.
  5. ^Eberhard, Kristin (2017-05-09)."Glossary of Methods for Electing Executive Officers".Sightline Institute. Retrieved2023-12-31.
  6. ^Volić, Ismar (2024-04-02). "Duverger's law".Making Democracy Count. Princeton University Press. Ch. 2.doi:10.2307/jj.7492228.ISBN 978-0-691-24882-0.
  7. ^Hamlin, Aaron (2015-05-30)."Top 5 Ways Plurality Voting Fails".Election Science. The Center for Election Science. Retrieved2023-07-17.
  8. ^Hamlin, Aaron (2019-02-07)."The Limits of Ranked-Choice Voting".Election Science. The Center for Election Science. Retrieved2023-07-17.
  9. ^"Voting Method Gameability".Equal Vote. The Equal Vote Coalition. Retrieved2023-07-17.
  10. ^Hamlin, Aaron; Hua, Whitney (2022-12-19)."The case for approval voting".Constitutional Political Economy.34 (3):335–345.doi:10.1007/s10602-022-09381-x.
  11. ^Ossipoff, Michael (2013-05-20)."Schulze: Questioning a Popular Ranked Voting System".Democracy Chronicles. Retrieved2024-01-01.
Part of thepolitics andEconomics series
Single-winner
Proportional
Systems
Allocation
Quotas
Mixed
Semi-proportional
Criteria
Other
Comparison
Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Sincere_favorite_criterion&oldid=1256916729"
Category:
Hidden categories:

[8]ページ先頭

©2009-2025 Movatter.jp