A jointPolitics andEconomics series |
Social choice andelectoral systems |
---|
![]() |
Single vote -plurality methods |
By results of combination By mechanism of combination By ballot type |
![]() |
Ranked Pairs (RP), also known as theTideman method, is atournament-style system ofranked voting first proposed byNicolaus Tideman in 1987.[1][2]
If there is a candidate who is preferred over the other candidates, when compared in turn with each of the others, the ranked-pairs procedure guarantees that candidate will win. Therefore, the ranked-pairs procedure complies with theCondorcet winner criterion (and as a result is considered to be aCondorcet method).[3]
Ranked pairs begins with around-robin tournament, where the one-on-one margins of victory for each possible pair of candidates are compared to find amajority-preferred candidate; if such a candidate exists, they are immediately elected. Otherwise, if there is aCondorcet cycle—a rock-paper-scissors-like sequence A > B > C > A—the cycle is broken by dropping the "weakest" elections in the cycle, i.e. the ones that are closest to being tied.[4]
The ranked pairs procedure is as follows:
At the end of this procedure, all cycles will be eliminated, leaving a unique winner who wins all of the remaining one-on-one matchups. The lack of cycles means that candidates can be ranked directly based on the matchups that have been left behind.
Suppose thatTennessee is holding an election on the location of itscapital. The population is concentrated around four major cities.All voters want the capital to be as close to them as possible. The options are:
The preferences of each region's voters are:
42% of voters Far-West | 26% of voters Center | 15% of voters Center-East | 17% of voters Far-East |
---|---|---|---|
|
|
|
|
The results are tabulated as follows:
A B | Memphis | Nashville | Chattanooga | Knoxville |
---|---|---|---|---|
Memphis | 58% 42% | 58% 42% | 58% 42% | |
Nashville | 42% 58% | 32% 68% | 32% 68% | |
Chattanooga | 42% 58% | 68% 32% | 17% 83% | |
Knoxville | 42% 58% | 68% 32% | 83% 17% |
First, list every pair, and determine the winner:
Pair | Winner |
---|---|
Memphis (42%) vs. Nashville (58%) | Nashville 58% |
Memphis (42%) vs. Chattanooga (58%) | Chattanooga 58% |
Memphis (42%) vs. Knoxville (58%) | Knoxville 58% |
Nashville (68%) vs. Chattanooga (32%) | Nashville 68% |
Nashville (68%) vs. Knoxville (32%) | Nashville 68% |
Chattanooga (83%) vs. Knoxville (17%) | Chattanooga 83% |
The votes are then sorted. The largest majority is "Chattanooga over Knoxville"; 83% of the voters prefer Chattanooga. Thus, the pairs from above would be sorted this way:
Pair | Winner |
---|---|
Chattanooga (83%) vs. Knoxville (17%) | Chattanooga 83% |
Nashville (68%) vs. Knoxville (32%) | Nashville 68% |
Nashville (68%) vs. Chattanooga (32%) | Nashville 68% |
Memphis (42%) vs. Nashville (58%) | Nashville 58% |
Memphis (42%) vs. Chattanooga (58%) | Chattanooga 58% |
Memphis (42%) vs. Knoxville (58%) | Knoxville 58% |
The pairs are then locked in order, skipping any pairs that would create a cycle:
In this case, no cycles are created by any of the pairs, so every single one is locked in.
Every "lock in" would add another arrow to the graph showing the relationship between the candidates. Here is the final graph (where arrows point away from the winner).
In this example, Nashville is the winner using the ranked-pairs procedure. Nashville is followed by Chattanooga, Knoxville, and Memphis in second, third, and fourth places respectively.
In the example election, the winner is Nashville. This would be true for anyCondorcet method.
Underfirst-past-the-post and some other systems, Memphis would have won the election by having the most people, even though Nashville won every simulated pairwise election outright. Usinginstant-runoff voting in this example would result in Knoxville winning even though more people preferred Nashville over Knoxville.
Of the formalvoting criteria, the ranked pairs method passes themajority criterion, themonotonicity criterion, theSmith criterion (which implies theCondorcet criterion), theCondorcet loser criterion, and theindependence of clones criterion. Ranked pairs fails theconsistency criterion and theparticipation criterion. While ranked pairs is not fullyindependent of irrelevant alternatives, it still satisfieslocal independence of irrelevant alternatives andindependence of Smith-dominated alternatives, meaning it is likely to roughly satisfy IIA "in practice."
Ranked pairs failsindependence of irrelevant alternatives, like all otherranked voting systems. However, the method adheres to a less strict property, sometimes calledindependence of Smith-dominated alternatives (ISDA). It says that if one candidate (X) wins an election, and a new alternative (Y) is added, X will win the election if Y is not in theSmith set. ISDA implies the Condorcet criterion.
The following table compares ranked pairs with other single-winner election methods:
Criterion Method | Majority winner | Majority loser | Mutual majority | Condorcet winner | Condorcet loser | Smith | Smith-IIA | IIA/LIIA | Cloneproof | Monotone | Participation | Later-no-harm | Later-no-help | No favorite betrayal | Ballot type | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
First-past-the-post voting | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | Single mark | |
Anti-plurality | No | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | Yes | Yes | No | No | Yes | Single mark | |
Two round system | Yes | Yes | No | No | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | No | Yes | Yes | No | Single mark | |
Instant-runoff | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | No | No | No | Yes | No | No | Yes | Yes | No | Ranking | |
Coombs | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | Yes | Ranking | |
Nanson | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | Ranking | |
Baldwin | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | Ranking | |
Tideman alternative | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | Ranking | |
Minimax | Yes | No | No | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | Yes | No | No | No | No | Ranking | |
Copeland | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | No | Yes | No | No | No | No | Ranking | |
Black | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes | No | No | No | No | Yes | No | No | No | No | Ranking | |
Kemeny–Young | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | LIIA Only | No | Yes | No | No | No | No | Ranking | |
Ranked pairs | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | LIIA Only | Yes | Yes | No | No | No | No | Ranking | |
Schulze | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes | No | No | No | No | Ranking | |
Borda | No | Yes | No | No | Yes | No | No | No | No | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | No | Ranking | |
Bucklin | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | No | Yes | No | No | Yes | No | Ranking | |
Approval | Yes | No | No | No | No | No | No | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes | Approvals | |
Majority Judgement | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | No | Yes | Yes | Scores | |
Score | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes | Scores | |
STAR | No | Yes | No | No | Yes | No | No | No | No | Yes | No | No | No | No | Scores | |
Quadratic | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | Yes | Yes | N/A | N/A | No | Credits | |
Random ballot | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Single mark | |
Sortition | No | No | No | No | No | No | No | Yes | No | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | None | |
Table Notes |
|