Movatterモバイル変換


[0]ホーム

URL:


Wikipedia

Economic history

This article is about the academic field. For actual economic histories, seeEconomic history of the world. For the history of intellectual development of economic theory, seeHistory of economic thought.

Economic history is the study of history using methodological tools fromeconomics or with a special attention to economic phenomena. Research is conducted using a combination ofhistorical methods,statistical methods and theapplication of economic theory to historical situations andinstitutions. The field can encompass a wide variety of topics, including equality, finance, technology, labour, and business. It emphasizes historicizing the economy itself, analyzing it as a dynamic entity and attempting to provide insights into the way it is structured and conceived.

World GDP per capita, 1400–2003

Using bothquantitative data andqualitative sources, economic historians emphasize understanding the historical context in which major economic events take place. They often focus on the institutional dynamics of systems ofproduction,labor, andcapital, as well as the economy's impact on society, culture, and language. Scholars of the discipline may approach their analysis from the perspective of differentschools of economic thought, such asmainstream economics,Austrian economics,Marxian economics, theChicago school of economics, andKeynesian economics.

Economic history has several sub-disciplines. Historical methods are commonly applied infinancial andbusiness history, which overlap with areas ofsocial history such asdemographic andlabor history. In the sub-discipline ofcliometrics, economists usequantitative (econometric) methods.[1] Inhistory of capitalism, historians explain economic historical issues and processes from a historical point of view.[2]

Early history of the discipline

edit
 
Economic history department, London School of Economics (1971)

Arnold Toynbee made the case for combining economics and history in his study of theIndustrial Revolution, saying, "I believe economics today is much too dissociated from history. Smith and Malthus had historical minds. However, Ricardo – who set the pattern of modern textbooks – had a mind that was entirely unhistorical." There were several advantages in combining economics and history according to Toynbee. To begin with, it improved economic understanding. "We see abstract propositions in a new light when studying them in relation to historical facts. Propositions become more vivid and truthful." Meanwhile, studying history with economics makes history easier to understand. Economics teaches us to look out for the right facts in reading history and makes matters such as introducing enclosures, machinery, or new currencies more intelligible. Economics also teaches careful deductive reasoning. "The habits of mind it instils are even more valuable than the knowledge of principles it gives. Without these habits, the mass of their materials can overwhelm students of historical facts."[3]

In late-nineteenth-century Germany, scholars at a number of universities, led byGustav von Schmoller, developed thehistorical school of economic history. It argued that there were no universal truths in history, emphasizing the importance of historical context without quantitative analysis. This historical approach dominated German and French scholarship for most of the 20th century. Thehistorical school of economics included other economists such asMax Weber andJoseph Schumpeter who reasoned that careful analysis of human actions, cultural norms, historical context, and mathematical support was key to historical analysis. The approach was spread to Great Britain byWilliam Ashley (University of Oxford) and dominatedBritish economic history for much of the 20th century. Britain's first professor in the subject wasGeorge Unwin at theUniversity of Manchester.[4][5] Meanwhile, in France, economic history was heavily influenced by theAnnales School from the early 20th century to the present. It exerts a worldwide influence through its journalAnnales. Histoire, Sciences Sociales.[6]

Treating economic history as a discrete academic discipline has been a contentious issue for many years. Academics at theLondon School of Economics (LSE) and theUniversity of Cambridge had numerousdisputes over the separation of economics and economic history in theinterwar era. Cambridge economists believed that pure economics involved a component of economic history and that the two were inseparably entangled. Those at the LSE believed that economic history warranted its own courses, research agenda and academic chair separated from mainstream economics. In the initial period of the subject's development, the LSE position of separating economic history from economics won out. Many universities in the UK developed independent programmes in economic history rooted in the LSE model. Indeed, theEconomic History Society had its inauguration atLSE in 1926 and theUniversity of Cambridge eventually established its own economic history programme.

In the United States, the field of economic history was largely subsumed into other fields of economics following the cliometric revolution of the 1960s.[7][8] To many it became seen as a form ofapplied economics rather than a stand-alone discipline.Cliometrics, also known as the New Economic History, refers to the systematic use of economic theory andeconometric techniques to the study of economic history. The term was originally coined by Jonathan R. T. Hughes andStanley Reiter and refers toClio, who was themuse of history and heroic poetry inGreek mythology. One of the most famous cliometric economic historians isDouglass North, who argued that it is the task of economic history to elucidate the historical dimensions of economies through time.[9] Cliometricians argue their approach is necessary because the application of theory is crucial in writing solid economic history, while historians generally oppose this view warning against the risk of generating anachronisms.

Early cliometrics was a type ofcounterfactual history. However, counterfactualism was not its distinctive feature; it combined neoclassical economics with quantitative methods in order to explain human choices based on constraints.[10] Some have argued that cliometrics had its heyday in the 1960s and 1970s and that it is now neglected by economists and historians.[11] In response to North andRobert Fogel'sNobel Memorial Prize in Economics in 1993,Harvard University economist (and future Nobel winner)Claudia Goldin argued:

Economic history is not a handmaiden of economics but a distinct field of scholarship. Economic history was a scholarly discipline long before it became cliometrics. Its practitioners were economists and historians studying the histories of economies... The new economic history, or cliometrics, formalized economic history in a manner similar to the injection of mathematical models and statistics into the rest of economics.[12]

The relationship between economic history, economics and history has long been the subject of intense discussion, and the debates of recent years echo those of early contributors. There has long been a school of thought among economic historians that splits economic history—the study of how economic phenomena evolved in the past—from historical economics—testing the generality of economic theory using historical episodes. US economic historianCharles P. Kindleberger explained this position in his 1990 bookHistorical Economics: Art or Science?.[13] Economic historianRobert Skidelsky (University of Cambridge) argued thateconomic theory often employs ahistorical models and methodologies that do not take into account historical context.[14]Yale University economistIrving Fisher already wrote in 1933 on the relationship between economics and economic history in his "Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions":

The study of dis-equilibrium may proceed in either of two ways. We may take as our unit for study an actual historical case of great dis-equilibrium, such as, say, the panic of 1873; or we may take as our unit for study any constituent tendency, such as, say, deflation, and discover its general laws, relations to, and combinations with, other tendencies. The former study revolves around events, or facts; the latter, around tendencies. The former is primarily economic history; the latter is primarily economic science. Both sorts of studies are proper and important. Each helps the other. The panic of 1873 can only be understood in light of the various tendencies involved—deflation and other; and deflation can only be understood in the light of various historical manifestations—1873 and other.[15]

Scope and focus of economic history today

edit

The past three decades have witnessed the widespread closure of separate economic history departments and programmes in the UK and the integration of the discipline into either history or economics departments.[16] Only the London School of Economics (LSE) retains a separate economic history department and stand-alone undergraduate and graduate programme in economic history.Cambridge,Glasgow,LSE,Oxford,Queen's, andWarwick together train the vast majority of economic historians coming through the Britishhigher education system today, but do so as part of economics or history degrees. Meanwhile, there have never been specialist economic history graduate programs at universities anywhere in the US. However, economic history remains a special field component of leading economics PhD programs, includingUniversity of California, Berkeley,Harvard University,Northwestern University,Princeton University, theUniversity of Chicago andYale University.

Despite the pessimistic view on the state of the discipline espoused by many of its practitioners, economic history remains an active field of social scientific inquiry. Indeed, it has seen something of a resurgence in interest since 2000, perhaps driven by research conducted at universities in continental Europe rather than the UK and the US.[17] The overall number of economic historians in the world is estimated at 10,400, with Japan and China as well as the U.K and the U.S. ranking highest in numbers. Some less developed countries, however, are not sufficiently integrated in the world economic history community, among others, Senegal, Brazil and Vietnam.[18]

Part of the growth in economic history is driven by the continued interest in big policy-relevant questions on the history of economic growth and development.MITeconomistPeter Temin noted that development economics is intricately connected with economic history, as it explores the growth of economies with different technologies, innovations, and institutions.[19] Studying economic growth has been popular for years among economists and historians who have sought to understand why some economies have grown faster than others. Some of the early texts in the field includeWalt Whitman Rostow'sThe Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto (1971) which described how advanced economies grow after overcoming certain hurdles and advancing to the next stage in development. Another economic historian,Alexander Gerschenkron, complicated this theory with works on how economies develop in non-Western countries, as discussed inEconomic Backwardness in Historical Perspective: A Book of Essays (1962). A more recent work isDaron Acemoglu andJames A. Robinson'sWhy Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty (2012) which pioneered a new field ofpersistence studies, emphasizing the path-dependent stages of growth.[20] Other notable books on the topic includeKenneth Pomeranz'sThe Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy (2000) andDavid S. Landes'sThe Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some are So Rich and Some So Poor (1998).

Since the2007–2008 financial crisis, scholars have become more interested in a field which may be callednew 'new economic history'. Scholars have tended to move away from narrowly quantitative studies toward institutional,social, andcultural history affecting the evolution of economies.[21][a 1] The focus of these studies is frequently on "persistence", as past events are linked to present outcomes.[22][23]Columbia UniversityeconomistCharles Calomiris argued that this new field showed 'how historical (path-dependent) processes governed changes in institutions and markets.'[24] However, this trend has been criticized, most forcefully byFrancesco Boldizzoni, as a form of economic imperialism "extending the neoclassical explanatory model to the realm of social relations."[25]

Conversely, economists in other specializations have started to write a new kind of economic history which makes use of historical data to understand the present day.[a 2] A major development in this genre was the publication of Thomas Piketty'sCapital in the Twenty-First Century (2013). The book described the rise inwealth andincome inequality since the 18th century, arguing that large concentrations of wealth lead to social and economic instability. Piketty also advocated a system of globalprogressive wealth taxes to correct rising inequality. The book was selected as aNew York Times best seller and received numerous awards. The book was well received by some of the world's major economists, includingPaul Krugman,Robert Solow, andBen Bernanke.[26] Books in response to Piketty's book includeAfter Piketty: The Agenda for Economics and Inequality, by Heather Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong, and Marshall Steinbaum (eds.) (2017),Pocket Piketty by Jesper Roine (2017), andAnti-Piketty: Capital for the 21st Century, by Jean-Philippe Delsol, Nicolas Lecaussin, Emmanuel Martin (2017). One economist argued that Piketty's book was "Nobel-Prize worthy" and noted that it had changed the global discussion on how economic historians study inequality.[27] It has also sparked new conversations in the disciplines of public policy.[28]

In addition to the mainstream in economic history, there is a parallel development in the field influenced byKarl Marx andMarxian economics.[29][30] Marx used historical analysis to interpret the role of class and class as a central issue in history. He debated with the "classical" economists (a term he coined), includingAdam Smith andDavid Ricardo. In turn, Marx's legacy in economic history has been to critique the findings of neoclassical economists.[31] Marxist analysis also confrontseconomic determinism, the theory that economic relationships are the foundation of political and societal institutions. Marx abstracted the idea of a "capitalist mode of production" as a way of identifying the transition fromfeudalism tocapitalism.[32] This has influenced some scholars, such asMaurice Dobb, to argue that feudalism declined because of peasants' struggles for freedom and the growing inefficiency of feudalism as a system of production.[33] In turn, in what was later coined theBrenner debate,Paul Sweezy, a Marxian economist, challenged Dobb's definition of feudalism and its focus only onwestern Europe.[34]

 
Thomas Piketty, economist and author ofCapital in the Twenty-First Century

History of capitalism

edit

A new field, called "history of capitalism" by researchers engaged in it, has emerged in US history departments since about the year 2000. It includes many topics traditionally associated with the field of economic history, such as insurance, banking and regulation, the political dimension of business, and the impact of capitalism on the middle classes, the poor and women and minorities. The field has particularly focused on the contribution of slavery to the rise of the US economy in the nineteenth century. The field utilizes the existing research ofbusiness history, but has sought to make it more relevant to the concerns of history departments in the United States, including by having limited or no discussion of individual business enterprises.[35][36] Historians of capitalism have countered these critiques, citing the issues with economic history. AsUniversity of Chicago professor of history Jonathan Levy states, "modern economic history began with industrialization and urbanization, and, even then, environmental considerations were subsidiary, if not nonexistent."[37]

Scholars have critiqued the history of capitalism because it does not focus on systems of production, circulation, and distribution.[38] Some have criticized its lack of social scientific methods and its ideological biases.[39] As a result, a new academic journal,Capitalism: A Journal of History and Economics, was founded at theUniversity of Pennsylvania under the direction of Marc Flandreau (University of Pennsylvania), Julia Ott (The New School, New York) and Francesca Trivellato (Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton) to widen the scope of the field. The journal's goal is to bring together "historians and social scientists interested in the material and intellectual aspects of modern economic life."[40]

Academic journals and societies

edit

The first journal specializing in the field of economic history wasThe Economic History Review, founded in 1927, as the main publication of theEconomic History Society. The first journal featured a publication by Professor SirWilliam Ashley, the first Professor of Economic History in the English-speaking world, who described the emerging field of economic history. The discipline existed alongside long-standing fields such aspolitical history,religious history, andmilitary history as one that focused on humans' interactions with 'visible happenings'. He continued, '[economic history] primarily and unless expressly extended, the history of actual human practice with respect to the material basis of life. The visible happenings with regard-to use the old formula-to "the production, distribution, and consumption of wealth" form our wide enough field'.[41]

Later, theEconomic History Association established another academic journal,The Journal of Economic History, in 1941 as a way of expanding the discipline in theUnited States.[42] The first president of the Economic History Association,Edwin F. Gay, described the aim of economic history as to provide new perspectives in the economics and history disciplines: 'An adequate equipment with two skills, that of the historian and the economist, is not easily acquired, but experience shows that it is both necessary and possible'.[43] Other related academic journals have broadened the lens with which economic history is studied. These interdisciplinary journals include theBusiness History Review,European Review of Economic History,Enterprise and Society, andFinancial History Review.

TheInternational Economic History Association, an association of close to 50 member organizations, recognizes some of the major academic organizations dedicated to study of economic history: theBusiness History Conference,Economic History Association,Economic History Society,European Association of Business Historians, and theInternational Social History Association.[44]

Nobel Memorial Prize-winning economic historians

edit

Have a very healthy respect for the study of economic history, because that's the raw material out of which any of your conjectures or testings will come.

Paul Samuelson (2009)[45]

Several economists have won Nobel prizes for contributions to economic history or contributions to economics that are commonly applied in economic history.

  • Simon Kuznets won theNobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences ("the Nobel Memorial Prize") in 1971 "for his empirically founded interpretation of economic growth which has led to new and deepened insight into the economic and social structure and process of development".
  • John Hicks, whose early writing was on the field of economic history, won the Nobel Memorial Prize in 1972 due to his contributions togeneral equilibrium theory andwelfare theory.
  • Arthur Lewis won the Nobel Memorial Prize in 1979 for his contributions in the field ofeconomic development through historical context.
  • Milton Friedman won the Nobel Memorial Prize in 1976 for "his achievements in the fields of consumption analysis, monetary history and theory and for his demonstration of the complexity of stabilization policy".
  • Robert Fogel andDouglass North won the Nobel Memorial Prize in 1993 for "having renewed research in economic history by applying economic theory and quantitative methods in order to explain economic and institutional change".
  • Claudia Goldin, who won the Nobel in 2023 for 'having advanced our understanding of women's labor market outcomes', began her career researching the history of the US southern economy and was President of the Economic History Association in 1999/2000.

Notable works of economic history

edit
 
Karl Marx,Capital: A Critique of Political Economy (1867)

Foundational works

edit

General

edit
  • Robert C. Allen,Global Economic History: A Very Short Introduction (2011)
  • Gregory Clark,A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World (2007)
  • Ronald Findlay andKevin O’Rourke,Power and Plenty: Trade, War, and the World Economy in the Second Millennium (2007)
  • Robert Heilbroner,The Worldly Philosophers: The Lives, Times and Ideas of the Great Economic Thinkers (1953)
  • Eric Roll,A History of Economic Thought (1923)

Ancient economies

edit

Economic growth and development

edit

History of money

edit

Business history

edit

Financial history

edit
 
Thomas Piketty,Capital in the Twenty-First Century (2013)

Globalization and inequality

edit

Notable economic historians

edit
 
Notable economic historians:Irving Fisher,Anna Schwartz,Milton Friedman,Stanley Fischer,Carl Menger,Edward C. Prescott,Alfred Marshall andFranco Modigliani

See also

edit

Notes

edit
  1. ^For example:
       •Gregory Clark (2006),A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World,DescriptionArchived 2011-10-18 at theWayback Machine,contentsArchived 2011-12-30 at theWayback Machine, ch. 1linkArchived 2011-12-30 at theWayback Machine, andGoogle previewArchived 2023-01-15 at theWayback Machine.
       • E. Aerts andH. Van der Wee, 2002. "Economic History",International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences pp. 4102–410.AbstractArchived 2011-10-28 at theWayback Machine.
  2. ^For example:Carmen M. Reinhart andKenneth S. Rogoff (2009),This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton.DescriptionArchived 2013-01-18 at theWayback Machine, ch. 1 ("Varieties of Crises and their Dates", pp.3–20)Archived 2012-09-25 at theWayback Machine, and chapter-previewlinks.Archived 2023-01-15 at theWayback Machine

References

edit
  1. ^See, for example, "Cliometrics" by Robert Whaples in S. Durlauf and L. Blume (eds.),The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. (2008).AbstractArchived 2012-05-28 at theWayback Machine
  2. ^Rockman, Seth (2014). "What Makes the History of Capitalism Newsworthy?".Journal of the Early Republic.34 (3):439–466.doi:10.1353/jer.2014.0043.S2CID 143866857.
  3. ^Arnold Toynbee's The Industrial Revolution: A Translation into Modern English, Kindle edition, 2020, pages1-2.ISBN 9780906321744. First published 1884.
  4. ^Berg, Maxine L. (2004) 'Knowles , Lilian Charlotte Anne (1870–1926)',Oxford Dictionary of National Biography, Oxford University Press,accessed 6 Feb 2015Archived 15 January 2023 at theWayback Machine
  5. ^Berg, M. (1992). The first women economic historians.The Economic History Review, 45(2), 308–329.
  6. ^Robert Forster, "Achievements of the Annales school."Journal of Economic History 38.01 (1978): 58–76.in JSTORArchived 2018-10-31 at theWayback Machine
  7. ^Margo, Robert A. (2021-01-01)."The economic history of economic history: the evolution of a field in economics".The Handbook of Historical Economics:3–16.doi:10.1016/B978-0-12-815874-6.00009-5.ISBN 9780128158746.S2CID 236731927.Archived from the original on 2021-05-07. Retrieved2021-05-06.
  8. ^Cioni, Martina; Federico, Giovanni; Vasta, Michelangelo (2021-01-01)."The two revolutions in economic history".The Handbook of Historical Economics:17–40.doi:10.1016/B978-0-12-815874-6.00008-3.hdl:10419/247122.ISBN 9780128158746.S2CID 226605299.Archived from the original on 2021-05-06. Retrieved2021-05-06.
  9. ^North, Douglass C. (1978). "Structure and Performance: The Task of Economic History".Journal of Economic Literature.16 (3):963–978.JSTOR 2723471.
  10. ^North, Douglass C. (1978). "Structure and Performance: The Task of Economic History".Journal of Economic Literature.16 (3).
  11. ^Whaples, Robert (2010). "Is Economic History a Neglected Field of Study?".Historically Speaking.11 (2): 17–20 & 20–27 (responses).doi:10.1353/hsp.0.0109.S2CID 162209922.
  12. ^Goldin, Claudia (1995)."Cliometrics and the Nobel".Journal of Economic Perspectives.9 (2):191–208.doi:10.1257/jep.9.2.191.S2CID 155075681.Archived from the original on 2020-05-22. Retrieved2020-04-24.
  13. ^Charles P. Kindleberger (1990),Historical Economics: Art or Science?Archived 2020-04-06 at theWayback Machine, University of California Press, Berkeley
  14. ^"Economic History – How & How NOT to Do Economics with Robert Skidelsky".Youtube. 10 September 2019.Archived from the original on 2021-12-11.
  15. ^Fisher, Irving (1933). "Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions".Econometrica.1 (4):337–38.doi:10.2307/1907327.JSTOR 1907327.
  16. ^Blum, Matthias; Colvin, Christopher L. (2018), Blum, Matthias; Colvin, Christopher L. (eds.), "Introduction, or Why We Started This Project",An Economist's Guide to Economic History, Palgrave Studies in Economic History, Springer International Publishing, pp. 1–10,doi:10.1007/978-3-319-96568-0_1,ISBN 978-3-319-96568-0
  17. ^Galofré Vilà, Gregori (13 January 2020)."The past's long shadow: A network analysis of economic history".VoxEU.Archived from the original on 14 January 2020. Retrieved19 April 2020.
  18. ^Baten, Jörg; Muschallik, Julia (2012). "On the Status and Future of Economic History".Economic History of Developing Regions.27:93–113.doi:10.1080/20780389.2012.682390.S2CID 155697900.
  19. ^Diebolt, Claude; Haupert, Michael."We are Ninjas: How Economic History has Infiltrated Economics"(PDF).American Economic Association.Archived(PDF) from the original on 2020-02-22. Retrieved2020-02-22.
  20. ^Cirone, Alexandra; Pepinsky, Thomas B. (2022)."Historical Persistence".Annual Review of Political Science.25 (1):241–259.doi:10.1146/annurev-polisci-051120-104325.ISSN 1094-2939.
  21. ^Douglass C. North (1965). "The State of Economic History",American Economic Review, 55(1/2) pp.86–91Archived 2023-01-15 at theWayback Machine.
  22. ^Frankema, Ewout (2021-01-01)."Why Africa is not that poor".The Handbook of Historical Economics:557–584.doi:10.1016/B978-0-12-815874-6.00035-6.ISBN 9780128158746.S2CID 236697047.Archived from the original on 2021-05-06. Retrieved2021-05-06.
  23. ^Voth, Hans-Joachim (2021-01-01)."Persistence – myth and mystery".Archived copy(PDF). Academic Press. pp. 243–267.doi:10.1016/B978-0-12-815874-6.00015-0.ISBN 9780128158746.S2CID 235911335.Archived(PDF) from the original on 2022-12-22. Retrieved2022-11-23.{{cite book}}:|journal= ignored (help)CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  24. ^Calomiris, Charles W. (2000). "Financial History and the Long Reach of the Second 30 Years War".Political Science.S2CID 154817653.
  25. ^Boldizzoni, Francesco (2011).The Poverty of Clio: Resurrecting Economic History. Princeton University Press. p. 18.ISBN 9780691144009.Archived from the original on 2012-05-05. Retrieved2012-05-05.
  26. ^Irwin, Neil (30 March 2015)."The New York Times".Now That Ben Bernanke Is Blogging, Here's What He Should Write About.Archived from the original on 17 December 2019. Retrieved17 December 2019.
  27. ^Atz, Ulrich (22 May 2014)."Thomas Piketty's Capital changed the global discussion about inequality because of its great data – now make it open".LSE Impact Blog.Archived from the original on 17 December 2019. Retrieved17 December 2019.
  28. ^Krugman, Paul (8 May 2014)."Why We're in a New Gilded Age".The New York Review of Books.Archived from the original on 4 April 2015. Retrieved22 February 2020.
  29. ^Heller, Henry (2018).A Marxist History of Capitalism. Routledge.
  30. ^Meek, Ronald L. (1956).Studies in the Labour Theory of Value. New York.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  31. ^Brewer, Anthony (2002)."The Marxist Tradition in the History of Economics"(PDF).History of Political Economy.34:361–377.doi:10.1215/00182702-34-Suppl_1-361.S2CID 88510540.Archived(PDF) from the original on 2019-07-10. Retrieved2020-01-06.
  32. ^Cohen, Jon S. (1978). "The Achievements of Economic History: The Marxist School".The Journal of Economic History.38 (1):29–57.doi:10.1017/S002205070008815X.S2CID 153934134.
  33. ^Dobb, Maurice (1946).Studies in the Development of Capitalism. Routledge.
  34. ^Sweezy, Paul (1950). "The Transition From Feudalism To Capitalism".Science & Society.14 (2).
  35. ^See Jennifer Schuessler "In History Departments, It's Up With Capitalism"The New York Times April 6, 2013Archived August 3, 2017, at theWayback Machine
  36. ^Lou Galambos, "Is This a Decisive Moment for the History of Business, Economic History, and the History Of Capitalism?Essays in Economic & Business History (2014) v. 32 pp. 1–18onlineArchived 2018-04-26 at theWayback Machine
  37. ^Levy, Jonathan (2017)."Capital as Process and the History of Capitalism".Business History Review.91 (3):483–510.doi:10.1017/S0007680517001064.
  38. ^Adelman, Jeremy; Levy, Jonathan (December 2014)."The Fall and Rise of Economic History".The Chronicle of Higher Education.Archived from the original on 2019-12-19. Retrieved2019-12-19.
  39. ^Hilt, Eric (2017)."Economic History, Historical Analysis, and the "New History of Capitalism"".The Journal of Economic History.77 (2):511–536.doi:10.1017/S002205071700016X.S2CID 41971400.
  40. ^"Capitalism and History"(PDF).Columbia University.Archived(PDF) from the original on 2020-07-22. Retrieved2019-12-17.
  41. ^Ashley, William (1927). "The Place of Economic History in University Studies".The Economic History Review.1 (1):1–11.doi:10.2307/2590667.JSTOR 2590667.
  42. ^Heaton, Herbert (1941). "The Early History of the Economic History Association".The Journal of Economic History.1.
  43. ^Gay, Edwin F. (1941). "The Tasks of Economic History".The Journal of Economic History.1:9–16.doi:10.1017/S0022050700052128.S2CID 250121256.
  44. ^"Members".International Economic History Association.Archived from the original on 2019-12-31. Retrieved2019-12-31.
  45. ^Clarke, Conor (June 18, 2009)."An Interview With Paul Samuelson, Part Two".The Atlantic.Archived from the original on June 3, 2017. RetrievedNovember 26, 2011.

Further reading

edit
Wikimedia Commons has media related toEconomic history.
Wikisource has original works on the topic:Economic history and conditions

[8]ページ先頭

©2009-2025 Movatter.jp