This is the first time I've written an open peer review, although I always sign private peer reviews. Normally I'd make comments directed to the authors and the authors alone, but since this is open, I've also included a section for other readers of this paper. This may sound a bit like an Amazon or Airbnb review or something.
Short summary for readersThis is an excellent paper about the academic, economic, and societal benefits and impacts of Open Access. It's a good introductory text for people who don't know much about OA and would like to know more. It's also a good persuasive text for stakeholders in policy, universities, publishing, funding, etc. positions who may be interested in including OA in their decision making.
In addition to its attention to detail, its main strengths are its focus, its brevity, and its relative impartiality.
One of the difficulties with writing about OA is that there are so many overlapping issues; this paper is very good at giving a brief overview or description of the other issues, pointing the reader in the direction of somewhere with more information, and then getting back onto the topic.
Another thing about OA is that its advocates are very passionate about it. As with any cause, that's a good thing for its supporters, but overwhelmingly pro-OA resources can seem potentially off-putting to neutrals. This paper does an excellent job of presenting an evidence-based pro-OA viewpoint in a measured tone and without coming across as ideological.
One possible caveat is that the paper presents extensive evidence of what OA does, but it doesn't tackle the meatier issue of how to implement it successfully. However, I feel that's a separate issue which is beyond the scope and purpose of this paper.
Suggestions and comments for authorsFirst of all, great article! Well done and thank you for pulling together what is a disparate collection of links and literature into a one-stop shop which is both useful and coherent. I like this article a lot... but my role here is to criticise and make it better, so the rest of this review will focus on that.
This article is well-written and well-structured. That's made it much easier as a reviewer to simply go through the article and highlight my issues with it paragraph by paragraph, rather than having to make it coherent first and then sort out the smaller things.
The vast majority of the issues I have with this paper are minor ones, so it didn't make sense to have separate major/minor sections; rather, I'll just go through them in order in the text.
(I printed this out to underline/comment on, so for me, tables 1 and 2 came during the academic case for OA section. Online, they're supplementary materials, and I think it's best that way, but this is why I'm commenting on the tables during that section)
Abstract"We recommend that OA supporters focus their efforts on working to establish viable new models and systems of scholarly communication, rather than trying to undermine the existing ones..."
In general, I agree with this sentiment. However, I feel that its inclusion in the abstract is a bit jarring as the text of the article doesn't really cover recommendations to OA supporters at all, other than in the very last paragraph. I think that's good, as I feel this paper is best suited as relatively neutral source of information rather than a preaching to the converted or ideology discussion kind of purpose. So, I think this part can be left out of the abstract; it doesn't refer to any particular "recommendations to OA supporters" bit in the text and potentially clouds the strength of the relative impartiality of the paper.
A brief history of OA"BioMed Central and ... PLOS were founded in the early 2000s and remain successful businesses to date." (p3, col2)
Technically, PLOS is a non-profit. I suggest changing
successful businesses to successful business models. This both highlights the financial sustainability of OA (increased APCs at PLOS notwithstanding) and also sets it apart from traditional publishers, which are definitely successful businesses.
The academic case for OAfigure 1 (p4, top)
I have difficulty interpreting the y-axis on figure 1. It's labelled as cumulative number of PubMed articles relative to 2000, but I'm not sure how to read it. Reading off 2014, non-OA is c.22 on the y-axis, and OA is c.33 on the y-axis. Based on the figure 1 caption about the ratio, I'm interpreting this as meaning that, in 2014, the ratio of cumulative PubMed articles was approx 33:22 OA to non-OA, or in other words, 60% of PubMed articles in 2000-2014 were OA. However, I'm not sure if this is how it's meant to be interpreted. I think that it's well visualised, and really makes it clear how OA has taken off, but exactly what the numbers represent on the y-axis is unclear to me: number of articles? number of times more articles? It could use some relabelling.
"Napster moment" (p4, col1)
I like the comparison, but it could use a citation (even just the Napster wikipedia article) and/or a little more explanation to clarify what that means.
Table 1:
"1991 ... by the American physician Paul Ginsparg"
He's a physicist, not a physician.
Table 2:
Xu et al (2011)
I don't think this reference was very well cited. Firstly,
Oxford Open Journals are listed as a discipline, when they're the source of papers across disciplines. The actual disciplines were Medicine, Social Sciences, Mathematics & Physical Sciences, Life Sciences, and Humanities. Secondly, you list the citation advantage as 138.87%. However, one of the main findings of this paper was the disparity in citation advantages; it ranged from 163.16% for OA articles in Mathematics & Physical Sciences to an actual citation disadvantage of -49.24% for OA articles in Humanities. Given the pro-OA nature of the paper, I feel like you have an extra responsibility to report the few anti-OA pieces of evidence.
Gargouri et al (2010) (page 8, col1)
This paragraph is about a possible confound for the OA citation advantage, where it could be that researchers choose to publish OA for extra cool findings, and you use the Gargouri et al. study to counter this... which is totally correct. You write:
"Gargouri et al. (2010) compared citation counts [for articles which were] self-selected as OA or mandated as OA. The study concluded that both were cited significantly more than non-OA articles. As such, these findings rule out a selection bias"
This is true that both OA types were cited more than non-OA. However, it's also missing the crucial point that there was no difference in citation between self-selected OA articles and mandatory OA articles. Including this would strengthen your point to show that it's OA itself which leads to the citation advantage.
The whole section about altmetrics (subhead societal impact of the academic case for OA, p8, col2) could use some attention. It's not clear until much later what the difference is between alternative metrics (i.e. altmetrics), i.e. the various types of metrics which are alternative to journal impact factors, and Altmetric, i.e. the company which is often confusingly referred to as Altmetrics (not in this paper, to be fair, but elsewhere). A quick disambiguating sentence or two would be really useful here.
In the following paragraph (page 8, col2), you write about OA altmetrics advantage, and say that there's a logical assumption that OA articles should have one. However, this doesn't consider the fact that the prestige of some journals is advertising in and of itself. You can, and do, get a lot of closed-access papers which generate high altmetrics (social media attention, Mendeley readhership) from academics who do have access. And sure enough, in the next paragraph, (page 8 and 9), the Wang et al. 2015 article finds that the OA altmetric advantage doesn't extend to the most impactful articles. I think this section can be made more nuanced and informative by quickly discussing the role of journal prestige. Nothing in depth, just as something that exists and needs to change (for example, you could point people to Brembs
et al.and the Deep Impact paper in Frontiers).
"Essentially, copyright is a tool wielded by traditional publishers for financial gain rather than fostering creativity..."
I don't disagree with this. However, I feel it comes on too strong. I think it's fair to say that most people's immediate opinion of copyright is "well, I'd like my stuff to be copyrighted, as that means people can't steal it and pass it off as their own". I think that you need a little more detail here, even just two or three sentences to explain how and why copyright is used for financial gain rather than author protection. Otherwise, it just sounds political/ideological, and counterintuitive for people who haven't read much about copyright.
Glenisson et al. (2005) citation (page 9, col2).
You write that TDM has "proven to be useful for a large variety of applications", and use the Glenisson citation to back this up. I have to say here that I know very little about TDM; however, following through to the Glenisson paper, I don't see how it supports that conclusion. I read it and it seems to show a proof-of-concept kind of study: that TDM can group a set of papers into themes in the same way that an expert can. This is really cool and everything, but I don't think that that substantiates your point that TDM is useful for a large variety of applications. Rather, I'd like to see a couple of specific examples, which you then describe more fully in the next paragraph. One good one is Swanson 1987 (I think - taken from here:
http://people.ischool.berkeley.edu/~hearst/papers/acl99/acl99-tdm.html), who used TDM to make the link between migraines and magnesium deficiency.
"...simply because one can no longer keep up with the published literature".
Small point, but I think it's worth stressing that this is due to the amount of literature that there is.
The economic case for OAthe pay-to-publish part (p10, col2)
I feel this glosses over problems with pay-to-publish. You come back to predatory OA later, but this isn't quite the same: I think it could use a couple of extra sentences describing what the conflict of interest for researchers is, and also stress that pay-to-publish makes it potentially in a journal's interest to accept more papers than they necessarily should. One of the most common anti-OA arguments I see in non-scientific media is that OA is pay-to-publish, which is often misrepresented as "pay-to-publish is publication bribery". I think this section needs a little more substance to it to acknowledge/address this.
"making publication costs dependent on the value added..." (page 11, col1)
When talking about the value added by journals, this paragraph ignores the elephant in the room: journal prestige. Again, I know that this isn't the purpose of this article, but I think it could really be strengthened by mentioning it before moving on.
"Much primary research actually takes place outside of academia inside research and development departments" (page 11, col2)
The part following this sentence is muddy. First, you talk about R&D outside academia (i.e. presumably private research), and then you talk about access to research results because they're publicly financed public goods. So, what does that mean, that R&D from private businesses who've invested their own capital in it should be made available to all? (maybe I agree with that, in some cases, but a lot of people sure won't)
I think this paragraph could be honed a bit; otherwise, it's straying into the ideological territory of saying that all private research should be made public for the public good. That transcends OA in scholarly publishing, and makes OA in scholarly publishing too easy to dismiss.
The cancer research paragraph (page 12, col1) is also unclear. It took me a while to figure out it's talking about UK expenditure - my first assumption of "total expenditure" meant worldwide. It's also not totally clear what the point is - the geographical origin of research is unrelated to its open status. I think that it's quite a leap to write (apologies for paraphrasing) "83% of UK economic benefit from cancer research comes from research outside UK, therefore open access is good", because I think it conflates two different things.
Also, small point, "17% of the annual net-monetary was estimated" is missing the word benefit after net-monetary.
The societal case for OASmall point: as somebody who wears a linguistics hat quite often, it rankles to read on page 11 "Examples of [non-academic] groups who might benefit include... those who work in linguistics and translation". Translation, for sure, but linguistics is an academic field - you even mention the Lingua to Glossa movement organised by academic linguists later in the manuscript! To me, this is like writing "...those who work in biology and vets", lumping the academic field and a practical use of that field together. Just referring to translation is fine.
Citizen engagement (page 13, col 1)
I agree that these are great examples of citizen engagement with science, but at the risk of sounding like an Elsevier representative, interest in projects like Galaxy Zoo does not entail desire to download and read papers. In fact, you could even make the (spurious) argument that those projects come into existence precisely because citizens aren't interested in downloading and reading papers. I don't actually agree with that, I agree with your general point... but I think that citizen science project interest and citizen science paper interest. Obviously I think it is in the public interest to have science journals OA, but this isn't the right argument (and I think the sentence "Such statements conflate a lack of desire or need for access with the denial of opportunity to access research" is perfect). I think a stronger argument would be to look at existing OA journals, such as PLOS and Frontiers, and see how many views and downloads come from people who aren't academics. If you can point to, say, some of the most viewed/downloaded PLOS papers and say "look, 30% (or whatever, that's a random number) of these readers aren't academics, they're real people who are interested in it", that would make for a stronger argument.
Quibble about the "yes, we were warned about Ebola" example: the finding from that paper (that Liberians have Ebola antibodies in their blood, suggesting the endemic presence of Ebola) is actually written on the first page preview of the paper (
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0769261782800282/part/first-page-pdf, accessed from my laptop outside my institution). It could be argued that anybody could see this finding anywhere in the world, meaning that it's not a problem of OA, it's a problem about searching and indexing. A good counterargument to
thatis obviously that this paper would have been unsearchable with TDM at the start of the outbreak when people were combing through all West African Ebola literature.
" 'green' model of OA adoption" (page 13, col2)
You generally refer to Green and Gold routes, with the colours capitalised. Just a small terminology thing to keep consistent.
A much more important thing is also on page 13, col2:
"The pay-to-publish system is a potentially greater burden for authors in
developedcountries, considering that they are not used to paying publication costs, and funding systems for OA are not as well-established as those in the Western world."
--> developing countries, not developed countries!
Predatory publishers (page 14, col1)
I agree with Ross Mounce's comment on the paper: you give Beall too much importance. I think it can be a useful list and should be mentioned, but definitely include some caveats like the ones Ross writes, or the fact that he added Frontiers to the list because of a couple of editorial mistakes.
ConclusionsPeter Suber (page 16, col1)
You describe him as "a leading voice in the OA movement", but I think you should write what his positions are (see
http://cyber.law.harvard.edu/~psuber/wiki/Peter_Suber) in order to justify his importance.
Other general thingsThere are no proposed solutions in this paper, which is totally fine, because it's beyond the scope of the paper. I feel it could benefit by putting in a couple of sentences here and there about who is needed for driving this change: academics, funders, governments, etc.
I was disappointed not to see anything about the Dutch government and university library organisations' collective drive towards OA. They've changed the national law on copyright, they've reached agreements with most major publishing groups, they may well introduce mandatory OA publishing in the Netherlands in 2016, and they've made it one of the main priorities of their EU presidency this year. It's like the best example of how a whole country can take the lead and sort it out. I think including a quick reference to the Netherlands as an example of excellent OA policy (in the same way that you mention sciELO in Latin America) would go a long way towards convincing the people who are reading this thinking, "ah, yes, I guess OA makes sense in the developing world, but we're doing fine here in the West and it would be too difficult to change things". A good summary of that is here:
http://openaccess.nl/en/in-the-netherlands/current-situationFinal remarksThat's the end of my 2800-odd word review. I really enjoyed reading this paper, going through it, and trying to find ways to improve it. Thanks to the authors for writing an excellent paper.
Non-financial: I'm an Open Access advocate, and so I have a vested ideological interest in seeing papers like this succeed and reach wide audiences. However, if anything, I believe that makes my peer review more critical, as I want this paper to be the best paper it can be.
Many thanks for pointing out that typo. It looks like just a keyboard malfunction of some sort! We'd be happy to fix it in future versions of ...Continue readingDear Ruth,
Many thanks for pointing out that typo. It looks like just a keyboard malfunction of some sort! We'd be happy to fix it in future versions of our paper.
Many thanks for pointing out that typo. It looks like just a keyboard malfunction of some sort! We'd be happy to fix it in future versions of our paper.
Open Accessfggd policies - Figure 3?
Open Accessfggd policies - Figure 3?
Open Accessfggd policies - Figure 3?
Thank you very much for your response and your focus on copyright. Unfortunately we did not have enough time to devote to the fine issues of copyright and ...Continue readingElizabeth,
Thank you very much for your response and your focus on copyright. Unfortunately we did not have enough time to devote to the fine issues of copyright and OA and hope that others will take up the opportunity to do that. However, here are some explanations of our thinking on these two particular points:
Thanks again,
Lauren (on behalf of the authors)
Thank you very much for your response and your focus on copyright. Unfortunately we did not have enough time to devote to the fine issues of copyright and OA and hope that others will take up the opportunity to do that. However, here are some explanations of our thinking on these two particular points:
Thanks again,
Lauren (on behalf of the authors)
I would query two points you make:
...Continue readingI really enjoyed this paper - a great overview of the key themes and issues around open access. Thank you.
I would query two points you make:
Whilst CC-BY gives authors the right to be properly acknowledged and cited, it does not give authors control over the integrity of their work. A CC-BY licence allows anyone to do anything with the work, even for commercial purposes. This is something academic authors are very uneasy about.
See: Gadd, E., Oppenheim, C. & Probets, S., 2003. RoMEO Studies 2: How academics want to protect their open-access research papers. Journal of information science. Available at: http://jis.sagepub.com/content/29/5/333.short [Accessed March 4, 2013].
2) You write: "The majority of ‘born OA’ journals and publishers do not request or receive copyright from authors. Instead, publishers are granted non-exclusive rights to publish, and copyright is retained by authors through a Creative Commons license (typically CC-BY)."
When an author signs a non-exclusive agreement with a publisher, copyright is retained by the author by virtue of copyright law, not by virtue of a Creative Commons licence. However, users of the research may engage with it by virtue of a Creative Commons licence. Is this what you mean?
I would query two points you make:
Whilst CC-BY gives authors the right to be properly acknowledged and cited, it does not give authors control over the integrity of their work. A CC-BY licence allows anyone to do anything with the work, even for commercial purposes. This is something academic authors are very uneasy about.
See: Gadd, E., Oppenheim, C. & Probets, S., 2003. RoMEO Studies 2: How academics want to protect their open-access research papers. Journal of information science. Available at: http://jis.sagepub.com/content/29/5/333.short [Accessed March 4, 2013].
2) You write: "The majority of ‘born OA’ journals and publishers do not request or receive copyright from authors. Instead, publishers are granted non-exclusive rights to publish, and copyright is retained by authors through a Creative Commons license (typically CC-BY)."
When an author signs a non-exclusive agreement with a publisher, copyright is retained by the author by virtue of copyright law, not by virtue of a Creative Commons licence. However, users of the research may engage with it by virtue of a Creative Commons licence. Is this what you mean?
Additionally, in this article we only wanted to stress that the APC model does not necessarily destroy all business and that it does seem to work for some journals/publishers. Nonetheless, you raise a valid point and we will stress in the revised version of the article that not all OA models necessarily sustain the current ecosystem. The discussion you raise about the level of APCs and the necessity of journals as publishing systems are interesting, and we fully agree that they are relevant to the question whether journals survive. We will add this remark, but refrain from providing an answer to these issues, because they are normative and hence do not fit in the scope of this review.
Additionally, in this article we only wanted to stress that the APC model does not necessarily destroy all business and that it does seem to work for some journals/publishers. Nonetheless, you raise a valid point and we will stress in the revised version of the article that not all OA models necessarily sustain the current ecosystem. The discussion you raise about the level of APCs and the necessity of journals as publishing systems are interesting, and we fully agree that they are relevant to the question whether journals survive. We will add this remark, but refrain from providing an answer to these issues, because they are normative and hence do not fit in the scope of this review.
So just to pick a point, you say "The comment that APCs will be unable to sustain the current journal ecosystem is also not supported by current evidence."
That is not what I said.
My point is that there are several obvious reasons why APCsmight not sustain the current journal ecosystem, not that theywill not, as your authors claim. (We are talking about possibilities here, not making predictions. At least I am not and I hope you are not.)
The first reason is that switching the journal ecosystem to APCs requires massive systematic changes by millions of people and thousands of institutions. This is unlikely to occur, to say the least. Other scenarios are at least equally possible and these need to be considered. One cannot just say that since the money is there now nothing is going to change, which is essentially what these macroeconomic studies are saying. That is not how the world works.
But the second reason is far stronger. There is a large OA constituency that advocates the transition to a low APC model. Something on the order of a few hundred dollars an article, or less, compared to the thousands of dollars per article funding the present ecosystem.
Clearly it is impossible to cut revenue by an order of magnitude and maintain the same ecosystem. The study we need to see goes like this. Take a typical scholarly society, or a commercial publisher, and look at how it spends its journal revenue. Then cut that revenue by 90% and ask what goes away? Then estimate the academic, economic and social disbenefits of that loss of revenue. Do this for a variety of cases then project the results to the entire journal ecosystem.
Perhaps the authors do not consider the loss of jobs to be an adverse economic impact, although public policy analysis does. The deeper question is what value those labors provide, that is then lost? When I see such studies I will begin to believe that a balance has been struck in the OA discourse.
On the green side there have probably been few subscription losses to date simply because the repository system is a disjointed mess. But surely you do not deny that if everything were freely available then no one would subscribe. Immediate deposit per se is self defeating. It can only be used to force the journals into the APC model.
Embargoed access is far more difficult to assess. I have made a beginning here:
https://scholarlykitchen.sspnet.org/2014/01/07/estimating-the-adverse-economic-impact-of-imposed-embargoes/.
My basic point is that if there are going to be journals then someone has to pay for them. If we pay less we will get less. But note that there is another OA constituency that says that we do not need journals. They advocate simple author posting and post-posting review via comments. I hope your authors do not consider this no journal scenario to be "sustaining the current journal ecosystem," which no longer exists.
As I have said repeatedly, your authors are glossing over the vast differences between the various OA models being proposed and the disbenefits each model entails.
So just to pick a point, you say "The comment that APCs will be unable to sustain the current journal ecosystem is also not supported by current evidence."
That is not what I said.
My point is that there are several obvious reasons why APCsmight not sustain the current journal ecosystem, not that theywill not, as your authors claim. (We are talking about possibilities here, not making predictions. At least I am not and I hope you are not.)
The first reason is that switching the journal ecosystem to APCs requires massive systematic changes by millions of people and thousands of institutions. This is unlikely to occur, to say the least. Other scenarios are at least equally possible and these need to be considered. One cannot just say that since the money is there now nothing is going to change, which is essentially what these macroeconomic studies are saying. That is not how the world works.
But the second reason is far stronger. There is a large OA constituency that advocates the transition to a low APC model. Something on the order of a few hundred dollars an article, or less, compared to the thousands of dollars per article funding the present ecosystem.
Clearly it is impossible to cut revenue by an order of magnitude and maintain the same ecosystem. The study we need to see goes like this. Take a typical scholarly society, or a commercial publisher, and look at how it spends its journal revenue. Then cut that revenue by 90% and ask what goes away? Then estimate the academic, economic and social disbenefits of that loss of revenue. Do this for a variety of cases then project the results to the entire journal ecosystem.
Perhaps the authors do not consider the loss of jobs to be an adverse economic impact, although public policy analysis does. The deeper question is what value those labors provide, that is then lost? When I see such studies I will begin to believe that a balance has been struck in the OA discourse.
On the green side there have probably been few subscription losses to date simply because the repository system is a disjointed mess. But surely you do not deny that if everything were freely available then no one would subscribe. Immediate deposit per se is self defeating. It can only be used to force the journals into the APC model.
Embargoed access is far more difficult to assess. I have made a beginning here:
https://scholarlykitchen.sspnet.org/2014/01/07/estimating-the-adverse-economic-impact-of-imposed-embargoes/.
My basic point is that if there are going to be journals then someone has to pay for them. If we pay less we will get less. But note that there is another OA constituency that says that we do not need journals. They advocate simple author posting and post-posting review via comments. I hope your authors do not consider this no journal scenario to be "sustaining the current journal ecosystem," which no longer exists.
As I have said repeatedly, your authors are glossing over the vast differences between the various OA models being proposed and the disbenefits each model entails.
Many thanks for taking the time to provide an extended comment, we, the collective authors, appreciate it. Below, we provide our response to the points raised.
- The link to the
...Continue readingDear David,Many thanks for taking the time to provide an extended comment, we, the collective authors, appreciate it. Below, we provide our response to the points raised.
We thank you for your thoughtful and constructive comment, and we will make sure to amend the text appropriately to accommodate your points.
References
Berners-Lee, Tim, De Roure, Dave, Harnad, Stevan and Shadbolt, Nigel (2005) Journal publishing and author self-archiving: Peaceful Co-Existence and Fruitful Collaboration. Available at:http://eprints.soton.ac.uk/261160/
Bernius, Steffen, et al. "Exploring the effects of a transition to open access: Insights from a simulation study." Journal of the American Society for Information Science and Technology 64.4 (2013): 701-726.http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1002/asi.22772/epdf
Henneken, Edwin A. et al (2007) E-prints and journal articles in astronomy: a productive co-existence. Learned Publishing 20 (1), 16-22. Available at:http://arxiv.org/abs/cs/0609126
Houghton, John W., and Charles Oppenheim. "The economic implications of alternative publishing models." Prometheus 28.1 (2010): 41-54.http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/pdf/10.1080/08109021003676359
Jubb, Michael. "Heading for the open road: costs and benefits of transitions in scholarly communications." Liber Quarterly 21.1 (2011): 102-124
Schimmer R, Geschuhn KK, Vogler A: Disrupting the subscription journals’ business model for the necessary large-scale transformation to open access. 2014. Available at:http://pubman.mpdl.mpg.de/pubman/faces/viewItemOverviewPage.jsp?itemId=escidoc:2148961
Swan, Alma (2005) Open access self-archiving: an introduction. Truro: Key Perspectives Ltd. Available at:http://eprints.ecs.soton.ac.uk/11006/01/jiscsum.pdf
Many thanks for taking the time to provide an extended comment, we, the collective authors, appreciate it. Below, we provide our response to the points raised.
We thank you for your thoughtful and constructive comment, and we will make sure to amend the text appropriately to accommodate your points.
References
Berners-Lee, Tim, De Roure, Dave, Harnad, Stevan and Shadbolt, Nigel (2005) Journal publishing and author self-archiving: Peaceful Co-Existence and Fruitful Collaboration. Available at:http://eprints.soton.ac.uk/261160/
Bernius, Steffen, et al. "Exploring the effects of a transition to open access: Insights from a simulation study." Journal of the American Society for Information Science and Technology 64.4 (2013): 701-726.http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1002/asi.22772/epdf
Henneken, Edwin A. et al (2007) E-prints and journal articles in astronomy: a productive co-existence. Learned Publishing 20 (1), 16-22. Available at:http://arxiv.org/abs/cs/0609126
Houghton, John W., and Charles Oppenheim. "The economic implications of alternative publishing models." Prometheus 28.1 (2010): 41-54.http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/pdf/10.1080/08109021003676359
Jubb, Michael. "Heading for the open road: costs and benefits of transitions in scholarly communications." Liber Quarterly 21.1 (2011): 102-124
Schimmer R, Geschuhn KK, Vogler A: Disrupting the subscription journals’ business model for the necessary large-scale transformation to open access. 2014. Available at:http://pubman.mpdl.mpg.de/pubman/faces/viewItemOverviewPage.jsp?itemId=escidoc:2148961
Swan, Alma (2005) Open access self-archiving: an introduction. Truro: Key Perspectives Ltd. Available at:http://eprints.ecs.soton.ac.uk/11006/01/jiscsum.pdf
Green OA
The most extreme form of green OA is immediate deposit of the article in a repository. Here the obvious adverse impact is the loss of subscription revenue. The more widespread and discoverable this deposit practice becomes the more subscriptions will be canceled. Basic economics says that one cannot sell what is available for free.
Many OA advocates want subscriptions to end so they may not see this as an adverse impact, but it certainly is from a public policy point of view. The loss of revenue is the very definition of adverse economic impact.
The loss of revenue readily translates into adverse academic and societal impacts, especially when this loss is sustained by a scholarly society. Societies use subscription revenue to conduct various activities that benefit their members directly and society indirectly thereby.
In the extreme case, which might be common, loss of revenue might lead to the termination of the very journals that OA seeks to provide access to. Here the academic and societal disbenefit is loss of the journal, making OA self defeating.
Transition to APC gold OA
OA advocates often argue that loss of subscription revenue will not lead to a loss of journals because the journals will simply transition to an author pays (APC) business model. But this transition is difficult and expensive, so some journals may not make it. Moreover, those that do may not attract the APC revenue needed to continue.
In fact there is no a priori reason to think that a system of all APC journals will duplicate and sustain the present system of subscription journals. The present system is based on libraries buying journals for large numbers of researchers. The APC system is based on individuals paying to be published. These are fundamentally different economic models.
The all APC system might well turn out to be much smaller than the subscription system. If so then the disbenefits will flow from the loss of a significant number of journals. Both recognition and communication might be greatly reduced in an all APC world.
Moreover, even if this does not happen, the APC funds are taken from research funding, thereby reducing the amount of research. Also, those who cannot afford the APCs will not be able to publish, further reducing both communication and recognition.
There is also the very real danger that funders will force APCs down to an unsustainable level. Peer review could be forced out, thereby reducing quality, or journals terminated altogether, if APC limits are set too low.
In fact the use of mandates to get OA has the potential adverse effect of turning scholarly publishing into a regulatory regime. In particular, de facto government control of who gets to publish, and where, is fraught with danger. Most published research is funded by governments and lowering allowable APCs is politically attractive (as is shortening green embargo periods).
All of these potential adverse impacts of OA are well known. Some are obvious. If the Tennant et all article aims to be an balanced account of the impact of OA then it should include the recognition of these possible disbenefits, in at least as much detail as is given to the possible benefits. Either that or re-title their article to make clear that they are only considering the potential benefits of OA, not including the disbenefits.
Green OA
The most extreme form of green OA is immediate deposit of the article in a repository. Here the obvious adverse impact is the loss of subscription revenue. The more widespread and discoverable this deposit practice becomes the more subscriptions will be canceled. Basic economics says that one cannot sell what is available for free.
Many OA advocates want subscriptions to end so they may not see this as an adverse impact, but it certainly is from a public policy point of view. The loss of revenue is the very definition of adverse economic impact.
The loss of revenue readily translates into adverse academic and societal impacts, especially when this loss is sustained by a scholarly society. Societies use subscription revenue to conduct various activities that benefit their members directly and society indirectly thereby.
In the extreme case, which might be common, loss of revenue might lead to the termination of the very journals that OA seeks to provide access to. Here the academic and societal disbenefit is loss of the journal, making OA self defeating.
Transition to APC gold OA
OA advocates often argue that loss of subscription revenue will not lead to a loss of journals because the journals will simply transition to an author pays (APC) business model. But this transition is difficult and expensive, so some journals may not make it. Moreover, those that do may not attract the APC revenue needed to continue.
In fact there is no a priori reason to think that a system of all APC journals will duplicate and sustain the present system of subscription journals. The present system is based on libraries buying journals for large numbers of researchers. The APC system is based on individuals paying to be published. These are fundamentally different economic models.
The all APC system might well turn out to be much smaller than the subscription system. If so then the disbenefits will flow from the loss of a significant number of journals. Both recognition and communication might be greatly reduced in an all APC world.
Moreover, even if this does not happen, the APC funds are taken from research funding, thereby reducing the amount of research. Also, those who cannot afford the APCs will not be able to publish, further reducing both communication and recognition.
There is also the very real danger that funders will force APCs down to an unsustainable level. Peer review could be forced out, thereby reducing quality, or journals terminated altogether, if APC limits are set too low.
In fact the use of mandates to get OA has the potential adverse effect of turning scholarly publishing into a regulatory regime. In particular, de facto government control of who gets to publish, and where, is fraught with danger. Most published research is funded by governments and lowering allowable APCs is politically attractive (as is shortening green embargo periods).
All of these potential adverse impacts of OA are well known. Some are obvious. If the Tennant et all article aims to be an balanced account of the impact of OA then it should include the recognition of these possible disbenefits, in at least as much detail as is given to the possible benefits. Either that or re-title their article to make clear that they are only considering the potential benefits of OA, not including the disbenefits.
Many thanks for your comment. In the revised version of this article, we will pay extra attention to the language used, in particular with the headings to address potential ...Continue readingDear David,
Many thanks for your comment. In the revised version of this article, we will pay extra attention to the language used, in particular with the headings to address potential issues with objectivity. While we were careful to provide a balanced argument, and provide numerous references to support these, it is possible of course that we have missed some key studies or counter points. Based on your comments, we would greatly appreciate any insight or links to the proposed counter-arguments so that we can strengthen the discussion throughout the paper.
Best,
Jon
Many thanks for your comment. In the revised version of this article, we will pay extra attention to the language used, in particular with the headings to address potential issues with objectivity. While we were careful to provide a balanced argument, and provide numerous references to support these, it is possible of course that we have missed some key studies or counter points. Based on your comments, we would greatly appreciate any insight or links to the proposed counter-arguments so that we can strengthen the discussion throughout the paper.
Best,
Jon
"The motivation behind this could come from the currently available data that suggests that hybrid publishing ...Continue readingThis single sentence on hybrid models seems dismissive and the link seems not to work:
"The motivation behind this could come from the currently available data that suggests that hybrid publishing options offered by traditional publishers, while being of higher cost, provide a much lower overall quality publishing process (blog.wellcome.ac.uk/ 2016/03/23/wellcome-trust-and-coaf-openaccess- spend-2014-15/)."
The hybrid model is an obvious transition route to widespread no-embargo OA, probably the most feasible and possibly the only feasible route.
"The motivation behind this could come from the currently available data that suggests that hybrid publishing options offered by traditional publishers, while being of higher cost, provide a much lower overall quality publishing process (blog.wellcome.ac.uk/ 2016/03/23/wellcome-trust-and-coaf-openaccess- spend-2014-15/)."
The hybrid model is an obvious transition route to widespread no-embargo OA, probably the most feasible and possibly the only feasible route.
But it is most certainly not a review of the academic, economic and societal impacts of OA, because there is no discussion of the various potential adverse impacts. Every argument presented has well known counter arguments based on adverse impacts. None of these counter arguments are mentioned, except the fact that significant APCs will make it harder for researchers in developing countries to publish. Thus the review is almost completely one-sided.
Another problem is that both the benefits and disbenefits of OA are highly sensitive to the model used to get it. This is not discussed, so the false impression may be given that all of these benefits will flow from every model. In some cases the benefits may be slight. Where they are potentially large the disbenefits may well be larger.
As an independent issue analyst who has studied this issue for years I have no competing interest. See https://scholarlykitchen.sspnet.org/author/dwojick/.
But it is most certainly not a review of the academic, economic and societal impacts of OA, because there is no discussion of the various potential adverse impacts. Every argument presented has well known counter arguments based on adverse impacts. None of these counter arguments are mentioned, except the fact that significant APCs will make it harder for researchers in developing countries to publish. Thus the review is almost completely one-sided.
Another problem is that both the benefits and disbenefits of OA are highly sensitive to the model used to get it. This is not discussed, so the false impression may be given that all of these benefits will flow from every model. In some cases the benefits may be slight. Where they are potentially large the disbenefits may well be larger.
As an independent issue analyst who has studied this issue for years I have no competing interest. See https://scholarlykitchen.sspnet.org/author/dwojick/.
A few small improvements could be made:
- 2nd paragraph: "A core issue remains: universal or even marginal access to ~75% of articles is not directly possible unless one is in a privileged position to work at an institute which has subscription access to a portion of these articles." - might it be worth mentioning the unlikely alternative, which is that someone has the budget to pay to buy access to all articles they require on a per-article basis? If so, include the fact that not all journals have a per-article price, and of course that these prices add up very quickly so are unrealistic for all but occasional uses.
- Predatory publishers section: I agree with Ross Mounce that the sentence "Predatory publishers tend to charge low publication fees" could be misleadingly read as suggesting that this is a criterion on which publishers can be judged as predatory or not. Some clarification should be provided here. I also suggest expanding on "not all scholars and advocates agree with the criteria proposed by Jeffrey Beall" - can you provide a link or two to criticisms of his criteria and of his views on open access?
- Figure 1: I found the "Ratio of the cumulative sum" hard to grasp - is there perhaps a more straightforward way of illustrating this point? Or could it be explained more clearly?
The following are small suggestions for improving wording:A few small improvements could be made:
- 2nd paragraph: "A core issue remains: universal or even marginal access to ~75% of articles is not directly possible unless one is in a privileged position to work at an institute which has subscription access to a portion of these articles." - might it be worth mentioning the unlikely alternative, which is that someone has the budget to pay to buy access to all articles they require on a per-article basis? If so, include the fact that not all journals have a per-article price, and of course that these prices add up very quickly so are unrealistic for all but occasional uses.
- Predatory publishers section: I agree with Ross Mounce that the sentence "Predatory publishers tend to charge low publication fees" could be misleadingly read as suggesting that this is a criterion on which publishers can be judged as predatory or not. Some clarification should be provided here. I also suggest expanding on "not all scholars and advocates agree with the criteria proposed by Jeffrey Beall" - can you provide a link or two to criticisms of his criteria and of his views on open access?
- Figure 1: I found the "Ratio of the cumulative sum" hard to grasp - is there perhaps a more straightforward way of illustrating this point? Or could it be explained more clearly?
The following are small suggestions for improving wording:Many thanks for these thoughtful and constructive comments. They will be given full consideration, and integrated into the next version of this manuscript pending the organised peer ...Continue readingDear Ross and Philip,
Many thanks for these thoughtful and constructive comments. They will be given full consideration, and integrated into the next version of this manuscript pending the organised peer review process.
Best,
Jon
Many thanks for these thoughtful and constructive comments. They will be given full consideration, and integrated into the next version of this manuscript pending the organised peer review process.
Best,
Jon
In the academic case for OA, I think ...Continue readingThanks for this great overview of open access. I am already finding many of the arguments and references useful in my own work.
In the academic case for OA, I think the case for ordinary academic reuse is understated, particularly in comparison to the extensive description of TDM benefits (which is great). For CC-licensed OA, the everyday decisions about reuse of material in a class, or usage of a figure or passage in a thesis or dissertation are greatly simplified. Arguably this kind of permission-free reuse will benefit more academics than TDM.
In Table 1, for 2012 you mention PeerJ's membership model, but they also offer an APC if the authors choose. I realize you are focusing on innovative models, but it may be misleading to suggest this is the only way they receive payment.
In the section on text and data mining, I am not sure that your reference to "a robust and developing public domain" is completely correct, since "public domain" has a specific legal meaning- perhaps rephrase as "a robust and developing scholarly ecosystem" or something like that. Also in this sentence, isn't it open licensing rather than shifting copyright to stay with author that makes TDM possible?
I have serious reservations about the mention of work made for hire in this section. In the U.S. at least, proposing this would result in a tremendous amount of criticism from faculty groups such as the American Association of University Professors (AAUP) who claim that copyright retention is part of academic freedom (see their statement in this regard here:http://www.aaup.org/report/statement-copyright). This would also be a problem for faculty who make creative works such as novels, films, artwork, etc. In addition, the argument here is contradicted in the paragraphs above, where you cite that 71% of the research community favors author-retained copyright. It's hard to imagine researchers favoring university-held rather than journal-held copyright. Perhaps faculty could voluntarily grant non-exclusive rights, as for green OA policies, but that is not the same as work for hire.
In the discussion of Freedom of Information requests, you could also cite Bergstrom et al. (2014), Evaluating big deal journal bundles,https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1403006111. In the next paragraph regarding pay-to-publish, it may be worth surfacing how authors pay APCs (Solomon & Bjork 2011,http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/asi.21660 see table 4) and the extent to which waivers are available (Lawson 2015,http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/publications3030155).
I also echo Ross Mounce's comment - someone has suggested “deceptive publishing” instead.
Minor issues:
- Suggest specifying "U.S." before National Institutes of Health
- question mark after “potential citation rates”
- Open Journal Systems (OJS)https://pkp.sfu.ca/ojs/ (not Journals System)
- in the conclusion, "number of policies” (not number policies)
Thanks again, great jobIn the academic case for OA, I think the case for ordinary academic reuse is understated, particularly in comparison to the extensive description of TDM benefits (which is great). For CC-licensed OA, the everyday decisions about reuse of material in a class, or usage of a figure or passage in a thesis or dissertation are greatly simplified. Arguably this kind of permission-free reuse will benefit more academics than TDM.
In Table 1, for 2012 you mention PeerJ's membership model, but they also offer an APC if the authors choose. I realize you are focusing on innovative models, but it may be misleading to suggest this is the only way they receive payment.
In the section on text and data mining, I am not sure that your reference to "a robust and developing public domain" is completely correct, since "public domain" has a specific legal meaning- perhaps rephrase as "a robust and developing scholarly ecosystem" or something like that. Also in this sentence, isn't it open licensing rather than shifting copyright to stay with author that makes TDM possible?
I have serious reservations about the mention of work made for hire in this section. In the U.S. at least, proposing this would result in a tremendous amount of criticism from faculty groups such as the American Association of University Professors (AAUP) who claim that copyright retention is part of academic freedom (see their statement in this regard here:http://www.aaup.org/report/statement-copyright). This would also be a problem for faculty who make creative works such as novels, films, artwork, etc. In addition, the argument here is contradicted in the paragraphs above, where you cite that 71% of the research community favors author-retained copyright. It's hard to imagine researchers favoring university-held rather than journal-held copyright. Perhaps faculty could voluntarily grant non-exclusive rights, as for green OA policies, but that is not the same as work for hire.
In the discussion of Freedom of Information requests, you could also cite Bergstrom et al. (2014), Evaluating big deal journal bundles,https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1403006111. In the next paragraph regarding pay-to-publish, it may be worth surfacing how authors pay APCs (Solomon & Bjork 2011,http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/asi.21660 see table 4) and the extent to which waivers are available (Lawson 2015,http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/publications3030155).
I also echo Ross Mounce's comment - someone has suggested “deceptive publishing” instead.
Minor issues:
- Suggest specifying "U.S." before National Institutes of Health
- question mark after “potential citation rates”
- Open Journal Systems (OJS)https://pkp.sfu.ca/ojs/ (not Journals System)
- in the conclusion, "number of policies” (not number policies)
Thanks again, great jobThis is merely an attempt at constructive criticism of a particular ...Continue readingThis is in no way a review of the entire manuscript, I don't have time for that at the moment.
This is merely an attempt at constructive criticism of a particular section, namely 'The case for publishers'.
Reading the manuscript as it currently is, one might come away from this section thinking that the average published research paper costs $3500–$4000 publish. I do not believe this to be true. For instance, at the Journal of Machine Learning Research (JMLR) it costs between $6.50 and $10 per paper - it is a notably efficient journal with technically competent submitting authors that submit manuscripts in formats that are more immediately publishable (e.g. LaTeX), thus Shieber (2012) absolutely must be cited in any discussion of the cost of publishing. Likewise, another estimate is given by Ubiquity Press: 300 is all they need to sustainable publish manuscripts submitted in less convenient formats (such as MS Word documents), so please do cite: http://www.ubiquitypress.com/site/publish/ too. Scale and 'selectivity' (the arbitrary rejection of signifcant percentage of papers that some journals like impose) are also very important factors in the cost of a particular journal's cost per paper. The high cost at Nature is largely down to the cost of rejecting all those papers, not the cost of the papers they actually end up accepting!
You may also want to mention the end-to-end XML based publishing system called ARPHA (Mietchen et al., 2015) as used by the open access publisher Pensoft and a similar(-ish?) system licensed by River Valley. Adoption of these more efficient, integrated publishing workflows will inevitably bring down the real costs of publishing - it's a madly inefficient workflow at most biology journals at the moment with completely different systems for authoring, peer-review and making the final version / typesetting / proofs.
Mike Taylor also has useful information on the real cost of typesetting here: https://svpow.com/2015/06/11/how-much-does-typesetting-cost/
I'm hugely surprised you don't seem to mention the effect of open access journals on decreasing publication delays. That's also a major value-add for most (all?) stakeholders. Daniel Himmelstein's (2015) excellent data & blog post showing that newer open access journals like eLife and PeerJ are decreasing the average time between submission and publication - faster publication. Furthermore, journals like F1000Research and Research Ideas and Outcomes (http://riojournal.com/) and preprint servers are eliminating the delay before submitted manuscripts are made public to zero days.
Finally, I'd advise extreme caution in adopting (willingly?) Beall's phrase "predatory publishers". You seem to indicate that if a journal charges a low APC it may be a predatory publisher? Would a solo author article at PeerJ then thus make PeerJ a "predatory publisher"?
If you still do insist on including a section on Beall's views (although why? whhyyyyyyy?), please do point out by citation/quotation that he is a controversial figure who thinks (his own words) that "The OA movement is an anti-corporatist movement that wants to deny the freedom of the press to companies it disagrees with".
Beall 2013. The Open-Access Movement is Not Really about Open Access. Triple C
Shieber 2012. An efficient journal https://blogs.harvard.edu/pamphlet/2012/03/06/an-efficient-journal/
Mietchen D, Mounce R, Penev L (2015)Publishing the research process. Research Ideas and Outcomes 1: e7547. doi: 10.3897/rio.1.e7547
This is merely an attempt at constructive criticism of a particular section, namely 'The case for publishers'.
Reading the manuscript as it currently is, one might come away from this section thinking that the average published research paper costs $3500–$4000 publish. I do not believe this to be true. For instance, at the Journal of Machine Learning Research (JMLR) it costs between $6.50 and $10 per paper - it is a notably efficient journal with technically competent submitting authors that submit manuscripts in formats that are more immediately publishable (e.g. LaTeX), thus Shieber (2012) absolutely must be cited in any discussion of the cost of publishing. Likewise, another estimate is given by Ubiquity Press: 300 is all they need to sustainable publish manuscripts submitted in less convenient formats (such as MS Word documents), so please do cite: http://www.ubiquitypress.com/site/publish/ too. Scale and 'selectivity' (the arbitrary rejection of signifcant percentage of papers that some journals like impose) are also very important factors in the cost of a particular journal's cost per paper. The high cost at Nature is largely down to the cost of rejecting all those papers, not the cost of the papers they actually end up accepting!
You may also want to mention the end-to-end XML based publishing system called ARPHA (Mietchen et al., 2015) as used by the open access publisher Pensoft and a similar(-ish?) system licensed by River Valley. Adoption of these more efficient, integrated publishing workflows will inevitably bring down the real costs of publishing - it's a madly inefficient workflow at most biology journals at the moment with completely different systems for authoring, peer-review and making the final version / typesetting / proofs.
Mike Taylor also has useful information on the real cost of typesetting here: https://svpow.com/2015/06/11/how-much-does-typesetting-cost/
I'm hugely surprised you don't seem to mention the effect of open access journals on decreasing publication delays. That's also a major value-add for most (all?) stakeholders. Daniel Himmelstein's (2015) excellent data & blog post showing that newer open access journals like eLife and PeerJ are decreasing the average time between submission and publication - faster publication. Furthermore, journals like F1000Research and Research Ideas and Outcomes (http://riojournal.com/) and preprint servers are eliminating the delay before submitted manuscripts are made public to zero days.
Finally, I'd advise extreme caution in adopting (willingly?) Beall's phrase "predatory publishers". You seem to indicate that if a journal charges a low APC it may be a predatory publisher? Would a solo author article at PeerJ then thus make PeerJ a "predatory publisher"?
If you still do insist on including a section on Beall's views (although why? whhyyyyyyy?), please do point out by citation/quotation that he is a controversial figure who thinks (his own words) that "The OA movement is an anti-corporatist movement that wants to deny the freedom of the press to companies it disagrees with".
Beall 2013. The Open-Access Movement is Not Really about Open Access. Triple C
Shieber 2012. An efficient journal https://blogs.harvard.edu/pamphlet/2012/03/06/an-efficient-journal/
Mietchen D, Mounce R, Penev L (2015)Publishing the research process. Research Ideas and Outcomes 1: e7547. doi: 10.3897/rio.1.e7547