Movatterモバイル変換


[0]ホーム

URL:


Skip to main content
Springer Nature Link
Log in

An economic theory of economic analysis: the case of the School of Salamanca

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The School of Salamanca often is identified as the first economic tradition in the history of the “dismal science”. Its members anticipated principles later developed by the likes of Adam Smith and Carl Menger. This paper provides an economic theory of the production of economic analysis by the Doctors of Salamanca, beginning from the observation that producers of economic analysis respond to incentives the same way producers of meat, beer, or bread do. Historically, the demand for economic analysis arises from two sources: governments and interest groups. I argue that the changes in international trade associated with the emergence of new transatlantic markets in the sixteenth century led to an increase in the demand for economic analysis by Spanish merchants and that the contribution of the School of Salamanca was grounded in the predictable supply response to those fresh incentives.

This is a preview of subscription content,log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Log in via an institution

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
¥17,985 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price includes VAT (Japan)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Chapter© 2019

Notes

  1. “The principles of all sciences are taught in Salamanca.” Little did they know that they also taught the principles of sciences yet to be discovered—economics.

  2. See Tollison (1986) for an excellent overview of the role played by economic incentives in the discovery of key economic ideas and the creative process more broadly.

  3. See Backhaus and Wagner (1987) on the role of the cameralists in producing economic arguments during the middle of the sixteenth to the nineteenth centuries for princes who demanded them largely because the costs of mobility increasingly had fallen (making it difficult to tax their subjects as heavily as before).

  4. “The great difference between scholastic and contemporary economics is one of scope and methodology: the Doctors approached economics from a legal point of view” (de Roover1995, p. 185). Throughout the paper, I will refer to the Spanish Scholastics using the broad, traditional term “Doctors” because their training and scholarship encompassed both theological and juridical (Roman and canon) disciplines.

  5. In his words: “[W]e are well received in the measure that we preach what the society wishes to hear. Perhaps all preachers achieve popularity by this route” (Stigler1981, p. 159).

  6. “It is within their systems of moral theology and law that economics gained definite if not separate existence, and it is they who come nearer than does any other group to having been the ‘founders’ of scientific economics” (Schumpeter1954, p. 97).

  7. In cases where the political authorities did intervene, some Doctors leveraged their economic analysis to make economic arguments for providing recompense to the injured parties. As Leonardus Lessius (1554–1623) taught:

    Take the following example. Without reason, a magistrate excludes some sellers from the market. The price of your goods rocket. The magistrate is obliged to indemnify the citizens for the damage they suffered as a result of this price increase because, contrary to the duties of his office, he caused the prices to climb so high. You, on the other hand, are not obliged to make compensation; under these circumstances your goods were simply worth the price for which you sold them (Lessius [1605] 2007, p. 25).

  8. Phillip II exercised monarchical self-control by defaulting on his loans only in 1557, 1560, 1575, and 1596. Solutions to royal financial pressures were found by increasing taxes on the merchants and capturing a larger share of ecclesial tithes and property.

  9. Charles V sought to reprimand him (although Vitoria later would be asked back as an advisor): “[T]he emperor did react in 1539 with a letter to the principal of the Convent of San Esteban, where both Vitoria and Soto were residing, to prevent their teaching and to destroy their manuscripts” (Koskenniemi2011, p. 10).

  10. “Monetary theorists are born in all ages and they were not lacking in sixteenth-century Spain, which was indeed the happiest of playgrounds for theologians whose tastes lay in what would now be called economics” (Grice-Hutchinson1952, p. 18); “a preoccupation with the ethics of pricing … is precisely one of the strongest motives a man can possibly have for analyzing actual market mechanisms" (Schumpeter1954, p. 57); “[b]ecause of their preoccupation with ethics, the Doctors were also more interested in what ought to be than in what actually was” (de Roover1955, p. 185).

  11. de Roover (1955, p. 180) highlights how their teachings were advantageously consistent: “One of the most striking characteristics of scholastic economics was universalism: regardless of origin and nationality, the Doctors are in fundamental agreement on method and principles”.

  12. The Doctors at Paris refused to recognize exchange (that is, currency exchange across time and distance) as legitimate. Interestingly, Vitoria was studying in Paris at the time and authored many of the responses. His students would later go on to argue for the legitimacy of these very exchanges (e.g., Tomás de Mercado).

  13. That conclusion is consistent with DeLong and Shleifer’s (1993) analysis of the negative impact that an absolutist prince, whom they explicitly typify as Philip II (1527–1598) of Spain, has on economic growth.

  14. See also Ekelund and Hébert (2010).

  15. To give an example of their influence: Domingo de Soto (1494–1560) represented King Charles V at the Council of Trent and also became the Emperor's confessor; Diego de Covarrubias y Leyva (1512–1577) was the President of the Council of Castile; Martin de Azpilcueta (1493–1586) was called to Rome in 1567, where he advised three successive popes (de Roover1955). Rothbard ([1995] 2006) explains the School’s influence on contemporary and future thinkers in greater detail.

  16. “Benson (1990, p. 60) writes: “The shifting of enforcement cost onto the government is consistent with the increasing political power and political activity of merchants. Indeed, the overall trend in economic regulation of the period was primarily motivated by merchant demands for monopoly rights”. In other words, merchants found it in their interest to outsource the production of commercial rules to the School of Salamanca.

  17. Here and henceforth, economic analysis is understood to be the scientific nature of economic inquiry (i.e., economic principles) that is conveyed in theory through the medium of a scholarly economic research paper, while economic arguments involve mobilizing economic analysis for a particular end, something similar to the aims of policy papers (or policy sections of papers).

  18. For example, Smith (1904, Book V, Ch. 1, Part III, Art. II) highlighted the principal-agent problem in the payment structure of professors at Glasgow University, where compensation was paid directly by students to professors, versus at Oxford where the university compensated the professors (1904). The result: “In the university of Oxford, the greater part of the publick professors have, for these many years, given up altogether even the pretence of teaching”.

  19. One could adopt the same argument to explain why economics generally is not taught until high school. The return to economic arguments grows as individuals expand their choice sets.

  20. See Mokyr (2002), especially his discussion of the effects of innovation on the household in the chapter “Knowledge, Health, and the Household.”.

  21. Likewise, expanded economic opportunities always come at a cost. Merchants frequently sought excuses to exploit the native peoples, which was the area in which the School imposed the strongest constraints on merchant behavior (see Bartolomé de Las Casas). Ironically, the treatment of native peoples too put the Doctors of the School at odds with the Crown, who followed incentives to cater to merchants in that regard (see the debates and legacy of Spain’s New Laws of 1542).

  22. For further information regarding the history of theConsulado, see Smith’s (1940) bookThe Spanish Guild Merchant. Greif et al. (1994) advance an argument for the efficiency of merchant guilds in governing the relationship between rulers and alien merchants.

  23. de Mercado (1569, p. 26) explicitly dedicates his handbook to theConsulado, showing merchants the way to pursue earthly wealth “so as not to lose the eternal wealth in dealing with the temporal one”. He adds a guarantee: “Hence, the Merchants’ Guild of Seville may be assured of this doctrine, and rejoice in having their contracts solved by this famous university … to have a plain solution to the contracts that are most celebrated in these kingdoms and in the Indies” (de Mercado [1569] 2017, p. 26).

  24. Essentially a case of re-regulation at a more encompassing level. Thomas and Leeson (2012) provide an analysis of the interplay between productive and unproductive entrepnueruial activity by examining the case of Bavaria’s brewing industry in the fourteenth to sisteenth centuries.

  25. “The penalties of confiscation of property and perpetual exile for the importation of unregistered treasure were applicable to the prior and consuls, if convicted of abetting the evasion of registration. Since the guild often interceded on behalf of those prosecuted for possession of unregistered bullion, securing pardons or a mitigation of the penalties, and, finally, had a hand in the abolition of compulsory registration, plainly theConsulado failed to share fully the mercantilist preoccupation of the state to prevent the drain of specie to foreign parts” (Smith1940, p. 101).

  26. It is well-known that the merchants had no qualms about using credit arrangements to charge and receive interest payments as well. Church regulations did not hamper finance in any significant way; rather, it made some financial instruments (such as foreign currency exchange) relatively more attractive given their ability to conceal interest charges (de Roover1951).

  27. In a later book, Grice-Hutchinson (1978, p. 120) does give an economic answer to the question of why Protestant scholars did not engage explicitly with late Scholastic economic thought (while clearly having read and drawn from their analysis): "we must remember that not only was [Pufendorf] a convinced Lutheran himself but that he also depended on the favor of Protestant princes".

  28. The earliest Doctors focused their analysis on the legal relationships between groups in the New World: “mere infidelity did not deprive the Indians of their rights—the contrary doctrine was, in fact, a Protestant heresy” (Koskenniemi2011, p. 8).

  29. For a taste of the magnitudes involved:

    Charles confiscated 1,500 ducats from the bishop of Cuenca as well as an additional 7,000 ducats of revenue from the diocese. The bishop of Guadix gave a loan of 300 ducats, the bishop of Almeria another 300 ducats, the bishop of Mallorca 1,500 ducats, the bishop of Badajoz a sum of 1,000 ducats, and the bishop of Osma a forced loan of 2,000 ducats. Charles as well confiscated from Segovia 6,000 ducats, from the bishopric of Burgos 10,000 ducats, the bishopric of Salamanca an additional 8900 ducats, and from the Toledan archdiocese 7,000 ducats. (Espinosa2006, p. 14)

    Not all prelates opposed those measures—in fact, many received new appointments in return for their financial support (Espinosa2006, p. 8). It was not to be the first nor the last time that Doctors of the School would take up positions against their fellow clergymen by explicitly warning the Crown against wars, inflation, and general excess.

  30. The political thought of the School distinguished itself from contemporaries by attempting to disentangle the state from the church; “One of Suárez’ major works—his 1613Defensio fidei—was written, building upon Bellarmine’s efforts to refute the claims of James I about the divine right and absolute power of kings” (Alves and Moreira2013, p. 103).

  31. Melé (1999), Rivas (1999), Alves and Moreira (2013) and Moreira and Alves (2013) provide thorough investigations into the business ethics approach taken by the Doctors.

  32. Milgrom et al. (1990) show how the larger system of seasonal fairs, private judges, and the Law Merchant reduced the transaction costs of long-distance trade between individual merchants.

  33. For more details on this point, see de Roover (1951, p. 501): “It would be a grievous mistake in historical interpretation to assume that the theories of the Doctors did not affect economic policy or influence legislation”.

  34. de Roover (1951) also cites numerous examples of medieval wills including restitution for usury and illegitimate gains.

  35. Diego de Covarrubias summarizes the theory in1556: “'The value of an article', he says, 'does not depend on its essential nature but on the estimation of men, even if that estimation be foolish. Thus, in the Indies wheat is dearer than in Spain because men esteem it more highly, though the nature of the wheat is the same in both places” (quoted by Grice-Hutchinson1952, p. 48).

  36. The conclusion that taxes can change behavior violates the norm of “tax neutrality” found in many public finance textbooks.

  37. The permanent principles of the Church's social doctrine constitute the very heart of Catholic social teaching. These are the principles of: the dignity of the human person, which has already been dealt with in the preceding chapter, and which is the foundation of all the other principles and content of the Church's social doctrine; the common goodsubsidiarity; and solidarity” (italics in original, Pontifical Council for Justice and Peace2004).

  38. Laures (1928) discusses taxation further in his excellent book,The Political Economy of Juan de Mariana.

  39. To give a sense of the magnitude of inflationary finance to which the Crown would resort, Velde and Weber ([1997] 2000, p. 6) report:

    The stampings of 1636, 1641 and 1654 each provided 5m ducats on average. From 1621 to 1626, minting of pure copper coinage earned 2m ducats per year. By way of comparison, total expenditures in 1598 and 1621 (both war years) were 12.3m and 12.7m ducats respectively, of which 6 to 7m ducats for defense. In 1608, a peacetime year, expenditures were 10.8m D of which 4.2m for defense. The sums raised in seigniorage were therefore considerable.

  40. Consider an excerpt from Cyprian’s homily in the second century: “The property of the wealthy holds them in chains … which shackle their courage and choke their faith and hamper their judgement and throttle their souls. They think of themselves as owners, whereas it is they rather who are owned: enslaved as they are to their own property, they are not the masters of their money but its slaves.”.

  41. Juan de Mariana even accuses his own order of Jesuits for extravagant living: “Certainly, it is natural for people to spend much more when they are supplied in common than when they have to obtain things on their own. The extent of our common expenses is unbelievable” (quoted by Chafuen2003, p. 35).

  42. San Bernardino of Sienna had taught: “If it is legal to lose, it must be legal to win” (quoted by Chafuen2003, p. 113).

  43. Aquinas makes a careful distinction—that just because an act is immoral doesn’t mean that it should be illegal. Both Aquinas and the Doctors conclude that prostitution should be legal to avoid even greater harm, and they “do not sin in taking their salary.… [T]hey can even claim what was promised to them” (quoted by Chafuen2003, p. 116).

  44. Merchants invested their new wealth into the educations of their children, providing a new source of funding for the universities. Records show that one of the wealthiest Sevillian merchants, Juan de la Barrera, established a fund to provide annual scholarships to the University of Salamanca for seven poor boys (Pike1972, p. 117).

  45. Maryks (2010) documents how the (originally) non-discriminatory policies of the Jesuits allowed for a significant numberconversos—Jews who were forced to convert to Catholicism by the Alhambra decree in 1492 (and other past laws)—to join the Society. It is hardly a stretch to believe that the financial expertises of the formerly Jewish families had some effect on the well-rounded knowledge from which the Schoolmen approached business.

  46. Francisco de Vitoria was a primary correspondent of past and future merchants during his study at the University of Paris. His opinions can be distinguished from the others by the “severity of his doctrine”.

  47. They also called for educational reform: “Moncado advocated the use of the vernacular instead of Latin for teaching at universities. He furthermore regretted that the educational system did not analyse social and economic problems. According to him, education had to be relevant to reality and functionally oriented to the socio-economic and cultural development problems of the nation. As long ago as that!” (Baeck1988, p. 399) .

  48. de Roover (1955, p. 170) discusses the interplay between usury laws and merchant evasion, concluding that “in trying to constrain the market, the moralists were fighting a losing battle”.

  49. An excellent conclusion of this exercise is given in Tollison (1986, p. 921): “To defend a person’s behavior as being consistent with positive economic theory is to say very little indeed. Moral leadership requires to some degree that preachers practice what they preach”.

  50. González (2017) reports: “We know that Mercado’s work had an evident repercussion at the time, to the point that, in a very short span, two other, extended editions were published in Spain (Seville 1571 and Seville 1587) as well as an Italian translation (Brescia 1591)”.

  51. Finnis (1980, p. 36), who has certainly read more Aquinas than the present author, writes that for Thomas Aquinas "the way to discover what is morally right (virtue) and wrong (vice) is to ask not what is in accordance with human nature, but what is reasonable”.

  52. The mathematical historian Morris Kline (1987) has called attention to the influence of the Scholastics: “The last medieval teachers, the Scholastics in particular, provided not only the rational climate in which mathematics and modern science were born, but they also inspired in Renaissance thinkers the belief that nature was the creation of God, and that the paths of God could be understood. It was this fundamental article of faith what prevailed on and inspired scientists and mathematicians of the Renaissance” (quoted by Gómez Camacho et al.2017, p. 31).

  53. “In the first chapter we said that monies are not of the same value in all places, that theducado among us is worth elevenreales, in Rome thirteen, the real is worth thirty-four in Seville, and in Gran Canaria, thirty-eight. Now it is a question whether it is licit to change a hundredreales in Seville for a hundred in Gran Canary where they are not worth four hundred maravedíes” (de Mercado [1569] 2017, pp. 135–136).

  54. Importantly, I do not intend to claim that the main motivation of the Doctors, merchants, or Spanish Crown, for that matter, wasnot seeking truth. What I believe my paper demonstrates is that the actions of the Doctors, merchants, and Crownalso can be explained by their economic incentives.

  55. In the words of Tollison (1986, p. 911), “The economist is a rational, maximizing individual, subject to the predictions of economic science. In this sense there is no way that the economist cannot be influenced by the environment”.

References

  • Allen, D. (1995). Order in the church: A property rights approach.Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,27, 97–117.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alves, A. A., & Moreira, J. M. (2013). Business ethics in the School of Salamanca. In C. Luetge (Ed.),Handbook of the philosophical foundations of business ethics. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, G. M., Shughart II, W. F., & Tollison, R. D. (1985). Adam smith in the customhouse.Journal of Political Economy,93(4), 740–759.

    Google Scholar 

  • Backhaus, J., & Wagner, R. (1987). The cameralists: A public choice perspective.Public Choice,53, 3–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baeck, L. (1988). Spanish economic thought: the school of Salamanca and the arbitristas.History of Political Economy,20(3), 381–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bañez, D. (1594).De Iustitia et Iure Decisiones. Salamanca: Ioannem et Andream Renaut.

    Google Scholar 

  • Batchelder, R. W., & Sanchez, N. (2013). The economienda and the optimizing imperialist: an interpretation of Spanish imperialism in the Americas.Public Choice,156(1–2), 45–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1981).A treatise on the family. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time.The Economic Journal,75(299), 493–517.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. (1989). The spontaneous evolution of commercial law.Southern Economic Journal,55(3), 644–661.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. (1990).The enterprise of the Law. San Fransisco: Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bork, R. H. (1967). The goals of antitrust policy.The American Economic Review,57(2), 242–253.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chafuen, A. (1986).Christians for freedom: Late-scholastic economics. San Fransisco: Ignatius Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chafuen, A. (2003).Faith and liberty: The economic thought of the late scholastics. Lanham: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Covarrubias, D. (1556).Variarum ex pontificio, regio et caesareo jure resolutionum libri III. New York: Philippum Pincium.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Mariana, J. [1609] 2002. A Treatise on the Alteration of Money (P. Brannan, Trans.).Journal of Markets & Morality (Instituto de estudios fiscales), 5(2).

  • de Mercado, T. [1569] 2017.Deals and contracts of merchants and traders. Salamanca: Ediciones Universidad de Salamanca.

  • de Roover, R. D. (1951). Monopoly theory prior to Adam Smith: A revision.The Quarterly Journal of Economics,65(4), 492–524.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Roover, R. (1955). Scholastic economics: Survival and lasting influence from the sixteenth century to Adam Smith.Quarterly Journal of Economics,69(2), 161–190.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Roover, R. D. (1958). The concept of the just price: Theory and economic policy.The Journal of Economic History,18(4), 418–434.

    Google Scholar 

  • DeLong, J. B., & Shleifer, A. (1993). Princes and merchants: European city growth before the industrial revolution.Journal of Law and Economics,36(2), 671–702.

    Google Scholar 

  • Director, A. (1964). The parity of the economic marketplace.Journal of Law and Economics,7, 1–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund, R., & Hébert, R. (2010). Interest groups, public choice, and the economics of religion.Public Choice,142(3–4), 429–436.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund, R. B., Hébert, R. F., & Tollison, R. D. (2002). An economic analysis of the protestant reformation.Journal of Political Economy,110(3), 646–671.

    Google Scholar 

  • Espinosa, A. (2006). The Spanish reformation: Institutional reform, taxation, and the secularization of ecclesiastical properties under Charles V.The Sixteenth Century Journal,37(1), 3–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finnis, J. (1980).Natural law and natural rights. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gómez Camacho, F., Bernal, A., Becedas González, M., Cuadrado Payeras, L., Ramón Keele, E., López, S., & Cuadrado Payeres, L. (2017).Three essays on the times and work of Tomás de Mercado. Salamanca (España): Ediciones Universidad de Salamanca.

    Google Scholar 

  • González, M. B. (2017). Tomás de Mercado and the deals and contracts of merchants and traders. In A.-M. Bernal, M. B. González, & F. G. Camacho (Eds.),Three essays on the times and work of Tomás de Mercado. Salamanca: Ediciones Universidad de Salamanca.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A., Milgrom, P., & Weingast, B. (1994). Coordination, commitment, and enforcement: The case of the merchant guild.Journal of Political Economy,102(4), 745–776.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grice-Hutchinson, M. (1952).The School of Salamanca. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grice-Hutchinson, M. (1978).Early economic thought in Spain, 1177–1740. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, E. J. (1934).American treasure and the price revolution in Spain, 1501–1650. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, E. J. (1938). Revisions in economic history: VIII. The decline of Spain.The Economic History Review,8(2), 168–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hernandez, R. (1991). The internationalization of Francisco de Vitoria and Domingo de Soto.Fordham International Law Journal,15, 1031.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger, C. P. (1998). Economic and financial crises and transformations in sixteenth-century Europe. In International Finance Section of the Deparment of Economics at Princeton (Ed.),Essays in international finance. Princeton: International Finance Section, Deparment of Economics, Princeton University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kline, M. (1987).Mathematics in western culture. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koskenniemi, M. (2011). Empire and international law: The real Spanish contribution.University of Toronto Law Journal,61(1), 1–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laures, J. (1928).The political economy of Juan de Mariana. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. (2005). Endogenizing fractionalization.Journal of Institutional Economics,1(1), 75–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. (2006). Cooperation and conflict: Evidence on self-enforcing arrangements and heterogeneous groups.American Journal of Economics and Sociology,65(4), 891–907.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. (2013). Vermin trials.The Journal of Law and Economics,56(3), 811–836.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P., & Coyne, C. (2012). Conflict-inhibiting norms. In M. Garfinkel & S. Skaperdas (Eds.),Oxford handbook of the economics of peace and conflict. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P., & Russ, J. (2018). Witch trials.The Economic Journal,128(613), 2066–2105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lessius, L. [1605] 2007. On buying and selling. Edited by Wim Decock.Journal of Markets and Morality, 10(2), 433–516.

  • Lovett, A. W. (1980). The Castilian bankruptcy of 1575.The Historical Journal,23(4), 899–911.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maryks, R. A. (2010).The Jesuit order as a Synagogue of Jews. Leiden: Koninklijke Brill NV.

    Google Scholar 

  • Melé, D. (1999). Early business ethics in Spain: The Salamanca School (1526–1614).Journal of Business Ethics,22(3), 175–189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., North, D., & Weingast, B. (1990). The role of institutions in the revival of trade: The law merchant, private judges and the champagne fairs.Economics and Politics,2(1), 1–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2002).The gifts of Athena: Historical origins of the knowledge economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moreira, J. M., & Alves, A. A. (2013). Business ethics in the School of Salamanca. In C. Luetge (Ed.),Handbook of the philosophical foundations of business ethics (pp. 207–225). Aveiro: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Navarrete, P. F. (1619). Conservación de Monarquias. InBiblioteca de Autores Españoles, Rivadeneyra (vol. 25). Madrid: Editions Atlas, 1947.

  • Phillips, C. R. (1983). Spanish merchants and the wool trade in the sixteenth century.The Sixteenth Century Journal,14(3), 259–282.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pike, R. (1972).Aristocrats and traders: Sevillian society in the sixteenth century. Cornell: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pontifical Council for Justice and Peace. (2004). Compendium of the social doctrine of the church: Chapter four.catholicculture.org.https://www.catholicculture.org/culture/library/view.cfm?id=7214&repos=1&subrepos=0&searchid=1875960. Accessed 2018.

  • Posner, R. A. (1979). The Chicago school of antitrust analysis.University of Pennsylvania Law Review,127, 92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Priest, G. (1977). The common law process and the selection of efficient rules.Journal of Legal Studies,6(1), 65–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rivas, L. G. (1999). Business ethics and the history of economics in Spain ‘The School of Salamanca: A bibliography’.Journal of Business Ethics,22(3), 191–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. N. [1995](2006).Classical economics. Volume II of an austrian perspective on the history of economic thought. Auburn, Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1954).History of economic analysis. New York: Oxford University Press Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W., & Tollison, R. (1985). The positive economics of antitrust policy: A survey article.Internatinal Review of Law and Economics,5(1), 39–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1904). Of the expences of the sovereign or commonwealth. In Cannan, E. (Ed.),An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. London: Methuen & Co., Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, R. S. (1940).The Spanish guild merchant. Durham: Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1981). Economics or ethics?The Tanner lectures on human values,2, 143–191.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1982). The economists and the problem of monopoly.Occasional Papers L. Sch. U. Chi.,19, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1992). Law or economics?The Journal of Law and Economics,35(2), 455–468.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, D., & Leeson, P. (2012). The brewer, the baker, and the monopoly maker.Journal of Entrepreneurship and Public Policy,1(1), 84–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tollison, R. (1986). Economists as the subject of economic inquiry.Southern Economic Journal,52(4), 909–922.

    Google Scholar 

  • Velde, F. R., & Weber, W. E. [1997] 2000.Fiat money in 17th century castile. Minneapolis: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and University of Minnesota.

  • Vigo, A. D. (1997). Cambistas, mercaderes y banqueros en el siglor de oro español.BAC Madrid,578, 12–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vilar, P. (1969). Oro y Moneda en la Historia 1450–1920, InA History of Gold and Money 1450–1920 (trans. J. White). London: NLB.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

  1. George Mason University, Fairfax, USA

    Clara Jace

Authors
  1. Clara Jace

    You can also search for this author inPubMed Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence toClara Jace.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jace, C. An economic theory of economic analysis: the case of the School of Salamanca.Public Choice181, 375–397 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00662-y

Download citation

Keywords

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
¥17,985 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price includes VAT (Japan)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Advertisement


[8]ページ先頭

©2009-2025 Movatter.jp