Movatterモバイル変換


[0]ホーム

URL:


Skip to main content

Ask the publishers to restore access to 500,000+ books.

Internet Archive Audio

Images

Software

Texts

Video

Search the history of over __WB_PAGES_ARCHIVED__web pages on the Internet.

Search iconAn illustration of a magnifying glass.

Save Page Now

Capture a web page as it appears now for use as a trusted citation in the future.

Please enter a valid web address

Full text of "What's left of the left : Democrats and Social Democrats in challenging times"

See other formats


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive in  2020  with  funding  from Duke  University  Libraries https://archive.org/details/whatsleftofleftdOOunse What’s  Left  of  the  Left What's  Left  of  the  Left Democrats  and  Social  Democrats in  Challenging  Times Edited  by James  Cronin,  George  Ross,  and  James  Shoch Duke  University  Press Durham  and  London 2011 ©  2011  Duke  University  Press All  rights  reserved. Printed  in  the  United  States  of  America on  acid-free  paper  ® Typeset  in  Charis  by  Tseng  Information  Systems,  Inc. Library  of  Congress  Cataloging-in-Publication  Data appear  on  the  last  printed  page  of  this  book. Contents Acknowledgments  vii Introduction:  The  New  World  of  the  Center-Left  1 James  Cronin,  George  Ross,  and  James  Shock part  i:  Ideas,  Projects,  and  Electoral  Realities Social  Democracy’s  Past  and  Potential  Future  29 Sheri  Berman Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  50 The  Electoral  Dynamics  of  European Social  Democratic  Parties,  1950-2009 Gerassimos  Moschonas part  il:  Varieties  of  Social  Democracy  and  Liberalism Once  Again  a  Model:  89 Nordic  Social  Democracy  in  a  Globalized  World Jonas  Pontusson Embracing  Markets,  Bonding  with  America,  Trying  to  Do  Good: The  Ironies  of  New  Labour James  Cronin Reluctantly  Center-Left?  141 The  French  Case Arthur  Goldhammer  and  George  Ross The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition:  162 Prospects  and  Problems Ruy  Teixeira Party  Politics  and  the  American  Welfare  State  188 Christopher  Howard Grappling  with  Globalization:  210 The  Democratic  Party’s  Struggles  over International  Market  Integration James  Shock part  ill:  New  Risks,  New  Challenges,  New  Possibilities European  Center-Left  Parties  and  New  Social  Risks:  241 Facing  Up  to  New  Policy  Challenges Jane  Jenson Immigration  and  the  European  Left  265 Sofia  A.  Perez The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left:  290 A  Political  Family  under  Construction Jean-Michel  De  Waele  and  Sorina  Soare European  Center-Lefts  and  the  Mazes  of  European  Integration George  Ross Conclusion:  Progressive  Politics  in  Tough  Times  343 James  Cronin,  George  Ross,  and  James  Shock Bibliography  363 About  the  Contributors  395 Index  399 319 Acknowledgments The  editors  of  this  book  have  a  long  and  interconnected  history,  and  the  book itself  has  been  long  in  the  making.  Having  participated  in  the  upheavals  of the  1960s  and  spent  the  next  two  decades  on  the  socialist  left  in  different parts  of  the  country,  the  three  of  us  met  in  the  late  1980s  on  the  Boston  collec¬ tive  of  the  journal  Socialist  Review.  Although  our  faith  in  the  socialist  project subsequently  ebbed,  we  remained  both  committed  to  progressive  politics  and fast  friends. As  our  political  views  evolved,  our  friendship  endured  and  was  nurtured over  the  next  fifteen  years  through  regular  outings  to  action  movies  of  uneven quality  that  our  vastly  more  discriminating  wives  refused  to  see.  When  one of  us  departed  for  California  in  2003,  we  looked  over  the  next  several  years for  ways  to  keep  in  touch  beyond  the  occasional  e-mail  and  visit.  It  was  then that  the  fourth  member  of  our  movie  group,  Lou  Ferleger,  suggested  to  Jim Cronin  that  with  our  collective  expertise  on  European  and  American  politics, the  three  of  us  should  collaborate  on  a  book.  With  the  center-left  parties  that we  all  studied  and  agonized  over  in  difficult  straits,  Jim  proposed  an  edited volume  on  the  parties  on  both  continents.  The  other  two  of  us  jumped  at  the chance  to  work  together  on  a  project  close  to  all  our  hearts. We  pulled  together  a  stellar  cast  of  contributors  who  wrote  draft  chapters that  were  presented  and  discussed  at  a  stimulating  conference  at  the  Center for  European  Studies  at  Harvard  in  May  2008.  A  conference  in  spring  2009 to  celebrate  George  Ross’s  retirement  at  the  Brandeis  Center  for  German  and European  Studies  was  also  used  to  present  work  based  on  some  of  the  chap¬ ters  in  this  book.  After  several  rounds  of  revision  by  our  authors  and  two lively,  scotch-fueled  editorial  meetings  near  Lake  Tahoe  and  on  Cape  Cod,  we produced  the  book  before  you. In  pulling  this  volume  together,  we  have  of  course  accumulated  many debts.  First  and  foremost,  we  wish  to  thank  our  authors,  who  we  think  have contributed  chapters  of  exceptional  quality.  We  also  appreciate  the  help  of Valerie  Milholland  and  Miriam  Angress  at  Duke  University  Press  in  shepherd¬ ing  this  book  through  the  editorial  process. viii  Acknowledgments Lou  Ferleger  deserves  another  mention,  both  for  suggesting  this  volume and  for  being  our  great  friend  through  all  these  years.  Thanks  too  to  Peter Hall  and  Patricia  Craig  at  the  Center  for  European  Studies  and  to  Sabine  von Mering,  Karen  Hansen,  and  Judy  Hanley  at  the  Brandeis  Center  for  German and  European  Studies  and  Department  of  Sociology  for  supporting  and  host¬ ing  our  two  meetings.  Thanks  as  well  to  Joanne  Barkan,  Andrea  Campbell, Joel  Krieger,  Michel  Lowy,  Richard  Valelly,  Eleni  Varikas,  and  Kathrin  Zippel for  joining  us  and  commenting  on  the  chapters  presented  at  the  Harvard  con¬ ference.  We  also  want  to  thank  James  Clifton  for  his  excellent  work  on  the references. Last  but  by  no  means  least,  we  want  to  thank  our  wives  — Laura  Frader, Jane  Jenson,  and  Barbara  Baran  — exemplary  scholars  and  professionals  all, for  contributions  to  this  book  and  to  our  lives,  too  numerous  to  mention.  We love  you  all  and  appreciate  your  tolerance. Introduction The  New  World  of  the  Center-Left James  Cronin,  George  Ross,  and  James  Shock Left  History  and  Its  Crossroads The  idea  of  the  “left”  has  varied  greatly  since  its  first  appearances  on  the benches  of  France’s  revolutionary  assemblies.  Born  of  rebellion  against  per¬ ceived  injustices  in  capitalist  development,  the  left  has  had  to  adapt  con¬ stantly,  often  painfully,  to  the  dynamics  of  capitalism  and  the  changing  di¬ mensions  of  capitalist  societies.  The  subject  of  this  book  is  how  parties  and movements  of  the  center-left  have  responded  to  the  vast  shifts  that  have  oc¬ curred  in  worlds  around  them  since  the  1970s.  But  before  turning  to  this,  it  is worth  reviewing  some  of  the  left’s  experiences  with  crossroads  in  the  past.1 Faced  with  early  industrialization,  different  lefts  had  tense  discussions about  whether  the  socialist  movement  should  work  through  the  state  or  work from  the  ground  up  through  social  movements  like  trade  unions.  Would  social democracy  come  from  high-level  political  action,  or  action  at  the  very  base  of society?  These  discussions  led  to  divisions  between  anarchists  and  socialists, memorialized  in  Marx’s  vivid  anti-anarchist  polemics.  In  some  places,  like  the United  States,  divisions  between  advocates  of  politics  and  advocates  of  trade unionism  reproduced  these  earlier  arguments  in  different  forms.  These  early disputes  have  continued  to  help  shape  the  trajectories  of  many,  if  not  most, labor  and  socialist  lefts  since  then. In  the  early  twentieth  century,  after  it  had  become  clear  that  industrial capitalism  had  more  staying  power  than  earlier  lefts  had  anticipated,  there came  new  and  bitter  splits  between  revolutionaries  and  social  democrats  — Kautsky  versus  Bernstein  being  but  one  example.  For  social  democrats,  if capitalism  was  not  about  to  implode,  leftists  had  to  settle  in  for  the  long  haul by  building  and  deepening  a  democracy  which  would  eventually  empower the  people  to  demand  changes  to  humanize  harsh  market  societies.  Revolu¬ tionaries  concluded,  quite  differently,  that  if  capitalism  had  unexpected  stay- 2  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch ing  power,  quasi-military  vanguards  of  professional  revolutionaries  should transcend  it  by  putchist  force.  The  vanguardists,  inspired  by  the  success  of the  October  revolution  in  Russia,  advocated  disciplined  party  centralization to  seize  power  and  the  building  of  socialism  from  above  by  technocrats  of revolution  acting  in  the  name  of  the  “masses.”  The  legacies  of  this  division permeated  and  often  poisoned  the  left’s  twentieth  century. Earlier  left  theorists  had  also  assumed  that  the  left  would  naturally  be internationalist.  “Workers  of  the  world  unite,  you  have  nothing  to  lose  but your  chains”  was  one  famous  statement  of  this  thesis.  But  in  1914,  when  real, existing  socialists  marched  eagerly  into  the  trenches  in  national  uniforms  to massacre  one  another,  there  came  a  shocking  correction.  The  lesson  was  that from  then  on  lefts  would  be  national.2 Postwar  Crossroads  and  Golden  Ages The  lefts  that  we  are  about  to  analyze  emerged  from  another  crossroads  that began  after  the  Great  Depression  and  the  Second  World  War.  In  Western Europe  countries  rushed  to  emulate  the  mass  production  consumer  capital¬ ism  pioneered  in  the  United  States,  while  the  United  States  deepened  its  own version.  Lefts  in  these  nations  were  deeply  touched  by  the  general  issues raised  by  this  new  society  and  economy,  which  often  came  simultaneously with  new  democratization,  particularly  in  the  societies  where  fascism  and authoritarianism  had  won  in  the  interwar  period.  The  puzzle  of  this  period, now  seen  by  many  nostalgically  as  a  golden  age,  was  whether  left  parties  and movements  would  seek  to  transform  capitalism  into  a  new  form  of  socialism or  rather  “settle”  for  the  new  compromises  between  capital  and  labor  that postwar  welfare  states,  Keynesianism,  and  new  economic  growth  seemed  to allow. Answers  varied,  and  the  world  of  postwar  lefts  became  an  exotic  mosaic. Where  lefts  were  divided  between  social  democrats  and  communists,  as  in Latin  Europe,  they  had  difficulty  winning  power,  and  even  extensive  welfare states  and  protective  employment  relations  systems  were  often  promoted  by others.  British  Labour  occasionally  won  power,  but  had  problems  conciliat¬ ing  Labourism  with  economic  dynamism.  The  Swedes,  the  great  success  story, were  never  particularly  Keynesian,  but  they  built  an  egalitarian  middle-class system  which  created  stakeholders  for  social  democracy  and  also  had  mecha¬ nisms  to  compete  in  the  international  economy.  The  Germans  succeeded, again  without  much  Keynesianism,  when  strong  unions  and  innovative  pri¬ vate  sector  exporters  cooperated  on  wage  restraint  and  flexibility,  carefully supervised  by  a  very  demanding  central  bank.  Americans,  with  fewer  social- Introduction  3 ists  and  weaker  socialist  dreams,  continued  their  waning  New  Deal  trajectory, falling  well  behind  their  European  counterparts. The  left’s  key  claims  in  this  golden  age  are  familiar.  Capitalism  was  deeply flawed,  unable  to  manage  the  risks  that  it  created,  prone  to  waste  and  peri¬ odic  crises,  and  an  incubator  of  inequality.  Capitalist  markets  left  to  them¬ selves  paid  little  attention  to  human  needs,  often  corrupted  political  life,  and were  imperfect  in  the  terms  of  economics  textbooks.  Left  politics  had  strong remedies  to  propose,  mainly  through  action  by  the  national  state.  Keynesian¬ ism  might  help  states  shape  their  macroeconomic  policies  by  managing  de¬ mand  to  limit  the  chaos,  even  out  ups  and  downs,  achieve  full  employment, and  target  particular  groups  through  welfare  state  programs  and  industrial policies.  The  world  of  the  golden  age  was  industrial,  and  in  it  workers  counted most  because  they  created  value  and  had  the  most  significant  needs.  They were,  or  would  be,  well  organized  into  trade  unions,  they  would  support  left visions  of  change,  and  they  voted  for  progressive  political  parties. Lefts  after  the  Golden  Age? Four  decades  later  this  left  world  and  its  slogans  have  disappeared.  Indeed one  rarely  hears  the  term  “left”  these  days:  instead,  electable  left  parties  of the  world  are  almost  always  labeled  “center-left.”  Center-lefts  now  include a  variety  of  political  forces,  among  them  social  liberals,  social  democrats, democratic  socialists,  progressives,  greens,  and  human  rights  campaigners. They  accept  markets  and  a  mixed  economy,  but  favor  limited  state  interven¬ tion,  are  “moderate”  in  most  ways,  and  are  somewhat  “libertarian.”  Perhaps the  most  important  thing,  however,  is  that  this  new  center-left  accepts  the multiple  constraints  of  economic  internationalization.  With  the  limited  ex¬ ception  of  the  brief  period  at  the  onset  of  the  current  crisis,  it  has  abandoned Keynesianism  in  favor  of  “sound”  budgetary  practices  involving  low  deficits, low  debts,  and  restrained  spending.  The  dream  of  full  employment  has  been replaced  by  an  emphasis  on  achieving  price  stability  and  promoting  national competitiveness  in  the  broader  world.  Commitments  to  redistribution  have been  attenuated,  and  center-lefts  have  learned  to  live  with  greater  income inequality.  Postwar  ideas  about  social  policies  and  employment  relations  sys¬ tems  to  provide  lifetime  security  have  been  leavened  by  notions  about  choice and  “flexibility.”  The  center-left  remains  reformist,  but  with  a  changed  reper¬ tory  that  now  includes  environmentalism,  civil  and  human  rights,  and  indi¬ vidual  cultural  liberties  on  top  of  older  concerns  like  economic  security  and cross-class  redistribution.  The  idea  of  transcending  capitalism  and  creating “socialism”  has  completely  disappeared. 4  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch Center-lefts  now  live  in  a  changed  environment  and  work  with  changed political  technologies.  There  are  fewer  workers,  and  unions  are  weaker.  Mass- based  political  parties  are  in  decline.  Politics,  even  on  the  left,  has  been  pro¬ fessionalized,  and  sophisticated  specialists  now  track  potential  voters  and issues  into  every  nook  and  cranny  of  ever  more  complicated,  individualized societies.  Money  also  talks  louder,  along  with  wealthy  lobbies,  in  a  world where  extensive  and  expensive  media  attention  counts  hugely.  Last  but  not least,  the  transition  from  left  to  center-left  has  made  for  political  orphans who  often  do  not  recognize  their  concerns  in  what  center-lefts  are  propos¬ ing.  Some  of  these  would  earlier  have  been  in  what  were  once  called  “mass organizations.”  Others,  in  “new  social  movements,”  issue-focused  NGOs,  or lobbies,  would  earlier  have  looked  to  left  parties  for  inclusion  of  their  issues in  party  programs  and  outlooks.  They  are  now  much  more  likely  to  take  their appeals  directly  to  engaged  audiences  and  to  policymakers,  often  through  the Internet.  From  the  point  of  view  of  center-left  parties,  these  orphans  can  be politically  volatile  and  unpredictable.  Some,  like  anti-globalization  activists, see  themselves  as  the  “left  of  the  left”  whose  protests  will  keep  the  center- left  “honest.”  Others  will  stick  to  their  own  issues  even  if  it  hurts  the  center- left’s  electoral  chances.  Still  others  venture  into  a  fluid  world  of  populism  to oppose  freer  trade  and  immigration,  or  even  join  mobilizations  over  “values” or  “threatened  identities.” It  would  be  wrong  to  conclude  that  the  coming  of  center-lefts  marks  the dead  end  of  the  left’s  long  march,  however.  Labour  and  social-democratic parties  and,  in  the  United  States  the  Democratic  Party,  have  remodeled  their outlooks,  organizations,  and  relationships  with  constituents  in  response  to very  large,  often  global,  changes.  The  political  space  within  which  they  oper¬ ate  has  changed  greatly.  But  neoliberalism,  which  vaunts  markets  as  the  ap¬ propriate  place  for  all  social  decision  making,  has  not  succeeded  in  banishing all  effective  opposition.  Left-right  competition  is  still  the  most  prominent  fea¬ ture  of  our  politics  (Noel  and  Therien  2008);  center-lefts  still  advocate  seri¬ ous  reformist  programs,  and  they  still  win  support  and  elections. This  book  seeks  to  explore  the  center-left’s  new  political  space  and  the  con¬ tent  that  fills  it  in  different  places.  What  is  the  demand  out  there  for  center- left  reformism?  What  are  the  hopes  of  the  center-left  and  the  projects  that  it proposes  in  response?  The  chapters  that  follow  will  explore  these  issues  his¬ torically  and  comparatively  through  a  range  of  case  studies  covering  various nations,  including  the  United  States.  They  will  consider  why  and  how  the  old world  of  the  left  has  given  way,  what  the  new  world  of  the  center-left  looks like,  and  how  promising  its  future  may  be.  What  we  will  see  is  a  patchwork  of different  center-lefts,  some  with  serious  problems,  others  just  barely  coping, Introduction  5 and  still  others  doing  very  well.  We  insist  that  new  political  spaces  for  the center-left  have  emerged  everywhere,  however,  and  our  interest  is  in  illumi¬ nating  how  different  parties  have  acted  to  fill  them  and  to  take  advantage  of the  opportunities  they  offer. From  Left  to  Center-Left:  Three  “Crises” Sometime  in  the  1970s  the  long  postwar  boom  came  to  an  end  for  western democracies,  beginning  a  long  crisis  that  challenged  the  certainties  of  the world  in  which  the  left  had  lived  for  a  quarter-century  after  1945.  Inflation, built  into  postwar  settlements  in  many  western  democracies,  had  already been  slowly  rising  in  the  1960s.  Successful  Fordist  reindustrialization  in  West¬ ern  Europe  and  Japan  had  slowly  diminished  America’s  competitive  advan¬ tages.  The  American  decision  in  1971  to  abandon  the  commitment  to  gold enshrined  in  the  Bretton  Woods  agreement  began  a  lengthy  process  of  re¬ adjustment.  This  process  was  then  massively  complicated  by  the  oil  shocks  of 1973  and  1979,  which  fused  rising  unemployment  and  uncontrollable  infla¬ tion  in  a  “stagflation”  that  in  theory  could  not  happen. The  slump  that  followed  ended  the  Keynesian  era  and  its  consensual assumptions  about  running  the  economy,  including  the  compatibility  of  a large  state  sector,  high  public  expenditure,  and  prosperity.  For  left  and  social democratic  parties  throughout  the  industrial  world,  including  the  Democratic Party  in  the  United  States,  Keynesianism  had  for  a  time  made  it  possible  to maintain  that  market-constraining  social  and  economic  policies  — large  wel¬ fare  states,  protective  labor  laws,  high  redistributive  taxation,  and  an  activist, regulatory  state— were  good  for  the  economy  and  society  and  in  the  national interest.3 With  Keynesianism  challenged,  this  understanding  of  the  public  good  was no  longer  compelling.  This  was  particularly  true  when  ascendant  neoliber¬ alism  argued  for  reversing  Keynesian  priorities,  asserting  that  large  govern¬ ment,  centralized  planning,  high  taxes,  and  social  spending  were  antitheti¬ cal  to  growth  and  should  be  considered  obstacles  to  prosperity.  The  most visible  reversal  came  in  the  realm  of  macroeconomic  policy.  The  notion  that smart  demand  management  could  fine-tune  otherwise  unruly  markets  and produce  consistent  growth  was  largely  abandoned.  What  replaced  it  was  a turn  to  what  some  have  labeled  a  “market  fundamentalism,”  which  largely conquered  public  servants,  politicians,  economists,  and  the  news  media. Monetarism  and  fiscal  retrenchment  quickly  became  the  norm,  and  empha¬ sis  shifted  to  “supply-side”  policies  and  efforts  to  produce  competitiveness through  higher  productivity,  greater  flexibility,  and  constant  innovation. 6  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch Neoliberalism  promoted  a  vastly  different  view  of  the  state  and  its  roles. Where  American  liberals  and  social  democrats  elsewhere  had  seen  the  state as  an  essential  and  largely  benign  instrument,  the  new  advocates  of  the  mar¬ ket  saw  it  as  detrimental  and  sought  to  restrict  its  scope  and  impact.  This meant,  in  the  first  instance,  ceasing  to  see  the  state  as  the  solution  to  social and  economic  problems  and  abandoning  commitments  to  full  employment— probably  the  most  important  legacy  of  the  1930s.  The  more  extreme  formula¬ tions  of  neoliberalism  insisted  on  the  need  to  permanently  reduce  taxes,  pri¬ vatize  nationalized  industries,  and  pursue  deregulation,  thus  depriving  the state  of  the  means  to  steer  the  economy.  Beyond  that,  the  state  itself  should be  restructured  so  as  to  use  market  mechanisms  to  deliver  services  and  mar¬ ket  criteria  to  assess  its  performance.  Wherever  possible,  the  state  should  not provide  services  directly  but  rather  contract  or  partner  with  private  compa¬ nies  to  do  so. This  shift  posed  a  huge  challenge  to  the  center-left:  would  it  also  make the  turn  toward  the  market  or  would  it  resist?  The  answer  was  a  long  time  in coming,  for  it  required  the  experiences  of  policy  failure  and  electoral  defeat to  produce  a  major  rethinking.  It  was  the  sorry  fate  of  many  of  the  social- democratic,  labor,  and  democratic  parties  to  be  in  power  during  the  1970s and  early  1980s  and  to  suffer  the  frustrating  consequences  of  changing  en¬ vironments  around  them.  In  Britain  the  Labour  governments  led  by  Harold Wilson  and  then  James  Callaghan  responded  to  the  oil  shocks  by  adopting income  policies  that  the  party’s  core  supporters  came  to  reject  in  a  defiant wave  of  strikes,  leading  to  the  election  of  Margaret  Thatcher  and  nearly  two decades  of  neoliberal  Conservative  rule.  In  the  United  States  Jimmy  Carter, facing  stagflation  and  foreign  policy  crises,  was  equally  ineffective  and  also prepared  a  turn  to  the  right  in  1980.  In  France,  the  Mitterrand  government, elected  in  1981  and  committed  to  strong  Keynesian  and  statist  reforms,  had to  retreat  rapidly  on  almost  every  front.  Center-left  parties  in  general,  includ¬ ing  those  that  built  the  “Nordic  model,”  had  difficulty  adapting  economic  and social  policies  to  the  problems  of  the  new  era,  problems  with  which  voters were  overwhelmingly  concerned. A  second  crisis,  more  political  than  economic,  was  soon  to  follow,  involv¬ ing  the  collapse  of  socialism  in  Eastern  Europe  in  1989  and  the  disappearance in  1991  of  the  Soviet  Union.4  These  huge  events  further  narrowed  the  dis¬ cursive  and  programmatic  political  space  within  which  the  center-left  could operate,  putting  paid  to  what  remained  of  any  nineteenth-century  vision  of replacing  capitalism  with  a  wholly  different  system.  There  was  great  irony  in this,  because  parties  of  the  democratic  left  had  long  been  at  pains  to  distance themselves  from  communism  and  “actually  existing  socialism.”  But  in  fact, Introduction  7 while  western  democratic  socialists  had  vehemently  deplored  the  illiberal, antidemocratic  practices  of  communism,  they  had  nonetheless  held  many abstract  beliefs  and  predispositions  in  common  with  their  communist  rivals. Although  the  intensity  of  the  most  utopian  of  these  passions  had  slowly  at¬ tenuated  in  most  of  the  left  since  1945,  what  happened  between  1989  and 1991  nonetheless  forced  a  reckoning  with  the  socialist  past  and  its  thinking about  the  world.  The  dream  of  transcending  capitalism  disappeared,  making a  political  life  bounded  by  capitalism  and  markets  look  permanent.  This  shift dictated  a  more  restricted  definition  of  what  was  politically  possible  and desirable.  It  is  important  to  add  that  the  end  of  the  cold  war  and  the  Soviet experiment  occurred  when  campaigns  for  hard-line  neoliberalism  — the  po¬ litical  consequence  of  the  economic  crisis  that  opened  in  the  1970s— were reaching  their  apogee.  The  western  victory  over  “already  existing  socialism” was  thus  a  huge  gift  to  market  fundamentalists. Globalization  is  our  third  critical  event,  or  process,  and  its  effects  on  the center-left  have  already  been  very  powerful.  Beginning  in  the  1990s  fast- moving  trends  that  expanded  world  trade,  opened  product  and  financial  mar¬ kets,  and  heightened  international  capital  mobility  combined  to  place  new limits  on  how  national  states  could  manage  their  economies,  protect  workers and  their  environments,  and  pursue  fiscal  policies,  including  those  that  pro¬ vided  social  services.  The  crisis  of  the  1970s  and  computer  technologies  had opened  the  door  to  financial  globalization,  which  came  on  strong  in  the  1990s with  the  growth  of  multinational  companies,  tentacular  investment  banks, mutual  and  hedge  funds,  futures,  swaps,  derivatives,  and  rapidly  flowing  hot money.  Over  the  same  period  successive  GATT  rounds  had  lowered  tariffs and  opened  trade,  culminating  in  1995  in  the  new  World  Trade  Organization. The  Bretton  Woods  institutions— the  World  Bank  and  the  IMF  — had  also  done their  part  by  energetically  imposing  the  “Washington  consensus”  on  coun¬ tries  that  resisted  the  new  orthodoxies.  In  Europe  the  move  toward  more  open markets  had  also  been  pushed  forward  gradually  by  European  integration, but  it  took  the  single  market  program  and  Economic  and  Monetary  Union (EMU)  after  1985  to  institutionalize  fully  open  markets  and  the  new  para¬ digms  of  price  stability  and  budget  balancing.  Less  encompassing  regionaliz¬ ing  efforts  in  North  America  had  similar  results.  Economic  and  policy  borders became  more  permeable,  affecting  sovereignty  and  narrowing  what  national governments  could  do. The  limits  created  by  globalization  were  also  in  part  discursive  and  ideo¬ logical.  Motivated  by  either  sincere  belief  or  perceived  political  imperatives, politicians  and  intellectuals  of  the  left  and  the  right  now  ruled  out  all  sorts  of policy  options  because  of  the  supposed  dictates  of  the  global  economy.  The 8  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch reality  beneath  the  rhetoric  was  nevertheless  sobering  enough.  The  global economy  and  new  technologies  clearly  made  it  easier  to  move  capital  and jobs  to  places  with  fewer  rules  and  lower  labor  costs.  They  also  allowed  em¬ ployers  and,  more  broadly,  investors  to  threaten  such  moves  and  thus  en¬ hance  their  political  leverage  to  insist  that  states  adopt  their  preferred  fiscal, monetary,  and  regulatory  policies.  The  impact  of  globalization  was  made  still more  real  as  it  became  itself  more  truly  global.  While  the  United  States  and Europe  might  have  begun  the  processes  that  created  a  more  open  world  mar¬ ket  and  to  that  extent  laid  the  ground  rules  for  its  operation,  other  nations joined  in  and  thus  acquired  an  interest  in  keeping  it  open  and  functioning. Specifically,  China,  India,  Russia,  Brazil,  and  other  “emerging”  economies entered  global  manufacturing  with  a  vengeance,  marching  forward  on  the back  of  huge  comparative  advantages  in  labor  costs  and  growing  economi¬ cally  at  rates  not  seen  since  the  nineteenth  century.  Energy  producers  like Russia,  the  leading  Arab  oil  exporters,  Venezuela,  Nigeria,  and  South  Africa were  no  less  invested  in  the  world  market,  whatever  the  ideological  complex¬ ion  or  rhetoric  of  their  regimes.  The  effect  was  to  reinforce  the  trend  toward international  economic  interdependence  and  to  underline  the  dictates  of globalization. Taken  together,  these  three  shocks  remade  the  world  in  which  center-left parties  and  movements  operate.  It  is  only  a  slight  exaggeration  to  say  that the  contemporary  center-left  is  itself  a  product  of  this  new  world  and  the constraints  and  opportunities  that  it  presents.  In  this  transformed  world,  the alternative  to  actually  existing  capitalism  is  not  socialism,  but  a  better  and more  just  capitalism.  Scholars  and  activists  now  study  not  transitions  to  so¬ cialism  but  the  “varieties  of  capitalism”  or  the  virtues  and  vices  of  distinc¬ tive  “worlds  of  welfare”  and  state  provision  (Hall  and  Soskice  2001;  Esping- Andersen  1990;  Schroder  2008).5  This  is  not  a  time  bereft  of  possibilities,  but it  is  a  moment  when  possibilities  need  to  be  located  within  the  global  econ¬ omy  rather  than  outside  or  in  opposition  to  it.  This  is,  most  important,  a  mo¬ ment  when  to  be  effective  the  center-left  must  be  creative  and  find  opportu¬ nities  in  new  policies  and  strategies. From  Left  to  Center-Left:  Large  Social  Changes The  effects  of  the  passing  of  the  Keynesian  era,  the  collapse  of  socialism  in Eastern  Europe  and  then  the  Soviet  Union,  and  the  coming  of  a  more  in¬ tense  era  of  global  economic  competition  were  felt  at  the  levels  of  both  ide¬ ology  and  policy.  It  was  hard  to  know  what  to  believe,  what  to  hope  for,  and Introduction  9 what  actually  to  do.  But  the  center-left  confronted  yet  another  set  of  prob¬ lems  about  electability.  To  be  successful  in  the  new  era  it  had  also  to  come  to grips  with  a  fourth  major  challenge:  the  shifting  social  bases  of  its  political appeal.  The  left’s  utopias,  legends,  programs,  and  practices  had  historically been  grounded  in  the  social  movement  of  the  industrial  working  class,  espe¬ cially  its  most  organized  sectors  and  occupations.  This  fact,  true  even  if  elec¬ toral  success  also  typically  required  support  from  the  middle  and  professional classes,  had  been  built  upon  long  and  storied  historical  struggles.  The  rich lore  that  surrounded  the  Paris  Commune,  the  Haymarket,  the  struggle  for  the eight-hour  workday,  the  October  Revolution,  the  British  General  Strike,  the French  strikes  of  1936,  the  struggle  against  fascism,  the  French  May  and  Ital¬ ian  Hot  autumn  of  the  1960s,  to  list  but  a  few  headline  moments,  nourished the  politics  of  generations. In  recent  decades,  however,  these  stories,  traditions,  and  utopias  have  be¬ come  far  less  meaningful.  The  social  bases  of  “progressive  politics”  have  dra¬ matically  shifted,  mainly  because  of  the  transition  to  what  has  been  variously termed  a  “post-industrial,”  “service,”  or  “knowledge-based”  economy.  Start¬ ing  in  the  1920s,  if  not  earlier,  services  began  to  grow  faster  than  industry  in developed  economies  (Clark  1940).  The  trend  accelerated  with  the  informa¬ tion  and  communications  revolution  that  began  in  the  1970s.  The  introduc¬ tion  of  labor-saving  technologies,  including  computer-based  technologies, together  with  rising  consumer  affluence  and  demand  for  new  goods  and  ser¬ vices  substantially  transformed  the  nature  of  the  workforce. The  first  consequence  is  that  the  industrial  working  class  has  literally shrunk.  In  1950  agriculture  had  accounted  for  28.3%,  industry  for  34%,  and services  for  37.7%  of  employment  in  developed  countries.  By  1971,  with  Ford- ist  mass  production  at  its  peak,  the  figures  were  12.7%,  37.9%,  and  49.4%.  By 1998  they  were  4.8%,  27.0%,  and  67.4%.  While  the  added  value  of  manufactur¬ ing  to  GDP  hovered  at  around  35%  of  the  total  throughout  this  period,  deindus¬ trialization  proceeded  apace  and  the  number  of  industrial  workers,  relative  to other  wage  earners,  steadily  declined  (Feinstein  1999).  Much  of  the  manufac¬ turing  not  already  relocated  to  developing  countries  is  now  capital-  and  skills- intensive,  and  the  workers  who  remain  are  better  educated  and  trained,  live better  and  differently,  partake  in  mass  consumption  and  culture,  and  are  no longer  encapsulated  in  the  working-class  subcultures  that  informed  the  my¬ thologies  of  the  left’s  pasts.  Many  are  also  women,  now  somewhat  better  off when  compared  to  men  even  if  not  yet  equal,  and  in  most  countries  male breadwinner  status  and  pay  scales  are  in  retreat.  Rising  living  standards  have also  blurred  the  line  between  workers  and  the  lower  middle  class,  while  ser- io  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch vice  work  is  often  hard  to  categorize  as  either  blue-  or  white-collar,  manual or  non-manual.  The  demographic  underpinnings  for  what  Eric  Hobsbawm (1978)  once  labeled  the  “forward  march  of  labour”  have  thus  dissipated. Similar  things  can  be  said  of  the  organizational  structures  that  sustained older  left  projects.  In  some  countries  — mainly  smaller  ones  — union  mem¬ bership  remains  practically  obligatory  (because  of  what  is  called  the  Ghent system)  and  therefore  at  high  levels.  Since  the  1980s,  however,  union  mem¬ bership  in  the  EU-15,  the  heartland  of  traditional  social  democratic  politics, has  declined  by  roughly  20%.  And  where  trade  unionism  has  not  been  quasi- obligatory,  unions  have  had  a  particularly  rough  ride.  In  France  union  mem¬ bership  has  halved  since  1970  and  is  now  at  8%  of  the  workforce  (around  3% in  the  private  sector);  in  Germany  it  is  22%  and  falling;  in  the  United  King¬ dom  it  is  down  one-third,  to  roughly  30%;  and  in  the  United  States  it  is  down to  12.5%.  In  most  of  Europe  declines  may  be  mitigated  somewhat  by  legal  ex¬ tensions  of  collective  agreements  to  non-unionized  workers.  Even  there,  how¬ ever,  over  time  the  membership  drop  is  likely  to  undermine  these  extensions and  the  overall  meaningfulness  of  collective  bargaining.  And  in  more  liberal industrial  environments,  where  contract  extensions  don’t  exist,  the  situation  is much  worse  (Visser  2006).  In  the  United  States  13.8%  of  workers  are  covered by  contracts,  as  are  30%  in  the  United  Kingdom.  Moreover,  most  union  orga¬ nizations,  however  powerful,  have  themselves  changed.  Earlier  efforts  to  fuel broader  working-class  cultures  have  given  way  to  the  provision  of  highly  pro¬ fessionalized  and  bureaucratized  representational  services  for  members. Lefts  and  center-lefts  have  needed  middle-class  help  to  “march  forward,” and  this  in  turn  has  always  necessitated  complicated  strategic  calculations and  compromise  (Przeworski  1985;  Przeworski  and  Sprague  1986).  With  the relative  decline  of  the  organizations,  culture,  and  size  of  the  working  class, this  need  is  now  overwhelming.  Average  employment  in  services  in  the  EU- 15  area  in  2006  was  70%  of  the  labor  force,  compared  to  78%  in  the  United States  (OECD  2008a).  “Services”  are  not  an  undifferentiated  group,  however, and  involve  occupations  ranging  from  low-paid  precarious  work,  through  so¬ cial  service  workers  in  caring  and  teaching  work,  to  relatively  secure  pub¬ lic  sector  functionaries,  professors,  and  investment  bankers.  The  challenge of  formulating  appeals  to  capture  the  needs  and  aspirations  of  such  a  di¬ verse  population  is  daunting.  At  one  end  of  the  spectrum,  low-paid  personal and  distributional  service  workers  are  the  core  of  a  growing  “working  poor” whose  needs  for  dignity  and  “social  inclusion”  are  widely  recognized  but  not easily  addressed  by  the  existing  repertoire  of  center-left  policy  prescriptions. That  these  populations  often  consist  of  immigrants  or  ethnic  minorities  com¬ pounds  the  danger  of  an  emerging  social  dualism  between  market  insiders Introduction  n and  outsiders,  a  split  that  can  and  occasionally  has  become  political  and  is almost  always  detrimental  to  the  center-left. Attending  to  the  concerns  of  more  middle-class  and  professional  constitu¬ encies  is  more  complicated  still.  Political  science  literature  has  made  much of  the  emergence  of  “post-material  values”  among  educationally  credentialed new  middle  strata  (Inglehart  1990).  The  strategic  problem  is  that  center-lefts have  problems  conciliating  traditional  “material”  issue  outlooks  with  the more  “libertarian,”  individualist,  and  universalist  passions  of  new  middle- class  groups  (Kitschelt  1994).  Concerns  for  the  environment  or  for  human rights  or  the  rights  of  women  and  minorities  might  well  be  compatible  with the  traditional  goals  and  visions  of  the  left,  but  they  sometimes  seem  not  to be.  In  any  event,  engineering  the  ideological,  programmatic,  and  organiza¬ tional  changes  needed  to  reconcile  the  conflicting  demands  of  constituents who  have  “material”  needs  and  demands  with  others  who  have  “left  liber¬ tarian”  or  “quality  of  life”  concerns  is  now  a  baseline  for  center-left  success. Achieving  it  remains  a  struggle,  however. As  if  the  changing  social  bases  of  center-left  parties  were  not  enough  of a  challenge,  the  ways  of  doing  politics  have  changed  as  well.  In  the  United States  after  the  Second  World  War— earlier  than  in  Europe  — new  worlds  of political  campaigning  opened  up,  connected  to  the  decline  of  traditional party  organizations  and  their  constituent  groups,  especially  labor  unions, and  the  simultaneous  rise  of  modern  mass  communications,  particularly television  and  later  the  Internet.  As  costly  “air  wars,”  including  positive  and negative  TV  ads,  replaced  the  grassroots,  labor-intensive  “ground  wars”  of old,  political  consultants  of  various  kinds— strategists,  pollsters,  media  ex¬ perts,  and  fundraisers— assumed  control  of  political  campaigns  from  tradi¬ tional  party  leaders.  More  recently,  American  parties  have  adopted  sophisti¬ cated,  computer-assisted  “micro-targeting”  techniques,  through  which  vast amounts  of  consumer  data  are  analyzed  to  identify  likely  sympathizers.  Mes¬ sages  are  then  delivered  to  these  voters  by  direct  mail,  phone  calls,  and  in¬ creasingly,  with  the  rediscovery  of  the  value  of  face-to-face  contact,  in  person by  grassroots  volunteers. In  the  new  style  of  electoral  campaigning,  issues  have  remained  impor¬ tant  for  attentive  voters.  Advanced  polling  techniques  are  used  to  ascertain voters’  preferences  on  salient  issues,  while  “issue  ads”  and  other  media  tac¬ tics  are  used  to  “frame”  issues  in  language  favorable  to  particular  candidates, to  “prime”  voters  to  judge  candidates  on  the  basis  of  issues  that  a  particular party  “owns,”  and  in  some  cases  to  persuade  voters  to  change  their  prefer¬ ences.  In  complex  post-industrial  societies,  however,  the  rise  in  salience  of new  social,  cultural,  environmental,  and  other  non-economic  issues  along- 12  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch side  traditional  economic  ones  means  that  candidates  have  to  position themselves  on  multiple  issue  dimensions  to  win  the  support  of  some  groups without  alienating  others  that  have  conflicting  preferences.  To  avoid  such dilemmas,  politicians  often  take  vague  or  ambiguous  issue  positions.  Beyond this,  because  most  voters  are  relatively  inattentive  to  politics  and  have  little awareness  of  candidates’  issue  positions,  one  contemporary  trend,  greatly reinforced  by  the  growing  role  of  the  mass  media,  is  for  electoral  campaigns to  downplay  issues  and  instead  foreground  themes  that  demand  less  from viewers  and  listeners.  These  include  incumbents’  performances  and  candi¬ dates’  personal  characteristics  — their  integrity,  honesty,  experience,  leader¬ ship  ability,  religiosity,  patriotism,  affability,  race  or  gender,  physical  attrac¬ tiveness,  etc. These  new  media-centered  and  computer-aided  campaign  techniques  are very  costly  and  would  thus  seem  likely  to  disproportionately  benefit  conser¬ vative  parties  tied  to  powerful  business  interests  and  other  wealthy  donors. Parties  on  the  center-left  may  also  have  more  qualms  and  hesitations  about making  use  of  these  tactics  than  their  opponents.  But  the  very  newest  of  these campaign  techniques,  enabled  by  the  emergence  of  the  Internet,  may  actually be  of  greatest  value  to  parties  of  the  center-left.  For  example,  in  the  United States  Barack  Obama  — through  his  own  campaign  website,  social  network¬ ing  sites  like  Facebook,  MySpace,  and  Twitter,  YouTube  videos,  e-mail,  and text  messaging  — was  able  to  raise  vast  sums  of  money  from  small  donors  and mobilize  tens  of  thousands  of  grassroots  volunteers,  both  processes  contrib¬ uting  immensely  to  his  innovative  and  successful  presidential  campaign.  In the  French  presidential  campaign  in  2007  Segolene  Royal  used  analogous techniques  to  short-circuit  her  Socialist  rivals  and  win  her  party’s  nomina¬ tion,  even  though,  unlike  Obama,  she  did  not  win  the  general  election. All  this  is  not  to  suggest  that  the  new  forms  of  campaigning  are  of  deci¬ sive  importance  in  determining  election  outcomes.  The  so-called  fundamen¬ tals— the  balance  of  partisan  identification  in  the  electorate,  the  state  of  the economy  and  international  relations,  and  the  popularity  and  effectiveness of  the  executive  — retain  a  dominant  role.  But  especially  in  close  elections, campaigns  can  definitely  matter;  and  the  changed  character  of  political  cam¬ paigning  adds  yet  another  challenge  to  the  parties  of  the  center-left. Policy  Dilemmas Shifting  bases  of  political  allegiance,  combined  with  the  new  economic  con¬ straints  and  new  campaigning  techniques,  vastly  complicate  the  task  of putting  together  stable  and  long-term  center-left  coalitions.  They  also  make  it Introduction  13 harder  to  develop  policies  to  bring  and  hold  together  fragmented  and  hetero¬ geneous  constituencies  and  then  to  govern  effectively.  In  the  policy  realm, for  example,  center-left  parties— especially  in  Europe— must  adapt  to  new monetary  policies  that  emphasize  price  stability  and  deemphasize  counter¬ cyclical  spending,  constraints  limiting  their  ability  to  reward  old  and  new constituencies.  They  also  confront  difficult  issues  of  welfare  state  reform prompted  in  part  by  aging  populations  that  have  produced  skewed  pension dependency  ratios  and  rapidly  rising  healthcare  costs.  They  must  devise  pro¬ grams  in  response  to  new  social  needs— childcare  for  new  single-parent  and two-breadwinner  families  and  support  programs  for  the  working  poor,  for example.  Most  controversially,  they  are  expected  to  promote  flexible  labor markets  without  undermining  employment  security,  to  reform  institutions governing  industrial  relations,  and  to  promote  new  patterns  of  cooperation between  labor  and  capital.  An  equally  difficult  challenge  involves  reforming educational  systems  to  promote  lifelong  learning,  training,  and  retraining. Finally,  they  need  to  find  new  revenue  sources  without  damaging  national economies  engaged  in  global  competition.  These  strategic  dilemmas  have  cre¬ ated  new  political  minefields. There  is  another  side  to  this,  however.  The  new  conditions  also  open  up new  political  space  for  center-left  parties  and  political  entrepreneurs.  With older  certainties  gone,  there  is  much  greater  room  for  more  persuasive  and creative  center-left  politicking  than  earlier.  Navigating  the  contemporary maelstrom  of  changing  economies,  social  bases,  and  political  technologies  is obviously  difficult.  But  recent  setbacks  notwithstanding,  there  is  ample  evi¬ dence  that  parties  of  the  center-left  remain  capable  of  winning  elections.  The American  presidential  election  of  2008  provides  some  evidence,  but  other data  are  easy  to  find  in  contemporary  European  history.  The  changes  that  we have  listed  have  not  eliminated  the  political  space  for  strategies  and  policies beyond,  and  often  against,  the  neoliberal  paradigm.  In  a  number  of  countries humanized  “supply-side”  alternatives  to  Keynesian  demand  management have  produced  successes.  Productivity-enhancing  public  investment— in education  and  training,  infrastructure,  and  new  technologies  — has  been  ex¬ panded  without  abandoning  fiscal  restraint.  It  also  seems  possible,  given  the right  raw  materials,  to  make  labor  markets  more  flexible  and  liberalize  them without  turning  them  into  the  sites  of  wars  among  the  insecure.  This,  plus innovative  attention  to  equal  opportunities  and  public  services,  and  absent severe  macroeconomic  shocks,  can  generate  levels  of  growth,  employment, and  other  benefits  sufficient  to  produce  electoral  victories.  Policies  aimed  at and  premised  on  delivering  economic  growth  thus  remain  prominent.  They have  not  dominated  center-left  policymaking  quite  as  much  as  they  did  in 14  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch the  past,  however,  as  new  issues,  backed  by  new  constituencies,  have  be¬ come  more  prominent.  In  part  this  is  because  the  same  economic  processes that  have  led  to  fewer  manual  workers  have  also  produced  more  white-collar professionals  who  can  be  mobilized  by  the  center-left  on  social  and  cultural rather  than  economic  issues.  The  increase  in  women’s  employment  likewise contains  possibilities  as  well  as  challenges.  The  declining  significance  of  class more  broadly  creates  room  for  a  politics  that  broaches  questions  of  racial and  sexual  equality,  human  rights,  war  and  peace,  the  environment,  and  life¬ styles— questions  that  cut  across  electorates  differently  from  earlier  class cleavages.  Center-left  parties,  which  have  long  debated  the  electoral  signifi¬ cance  of  these  shifts,  by  now  have  come  to  understand  them  reasonably  well and  have  begun  to  successfully  incorporate  new  issues  into  their  electoral  ap¬ peals  and  programs.  On  old  and  new  issues,  with  old  and  new  constituencies, there  are  real  possibilities  for  the  center  left  even  in  a  different  world. There  Are  Center-Lefts  and  Center-Lefts  . . . All  center-lefts  have  had  to  confront  these  crises  and  changes,  but  it  would be  misleading  to  argue  that  there  is  one  center-left  everywhere  challenged  in the  same  way.  Histories  and  policy  legacies  vary  tremendously  from  country to  country  in  ways  that  may  either  facilitate  or  hinder  adaptive  responses  to new  conditions.  In  addition,  differences  among  national  constitutional,  insti¬ tutional,  and  political  systems  can  result  in  a  wide  range  of  policy  responses to  similar  economic  and  other  circumstances.  Specific  location  in  the  uneven development  of  the  unfolding  global  economy  is  also  important.  The  chap¬ ters  in  this  book  will  illustrate  these  different  variables  at  work  through  case studies. Different  narratives  about  recent  political  changes  tend  to  have  differ¬ ent  heroes.  Many  center-leftists  grant  pride  of  place  to  the  Nordic  countries. These  countries,  perhaps  uniquely,  have  been  able  simultaneously  to  adapt public  financial  practices  to  new  international  standards,  promote  public  in¬ vestment  and  flexible  internal  labor  markets  to  facilitate  rapid  innovation, and  sustain  generous  welfare  states.  Denmark  and  Sweden  have  been  particu¬ larly  good  at  active  labor  market  “flexicurity”  policies  that  liberalize  labor regulations  while  providing  support  to  wage  earners  looking  to  make  employ¬ ment  transitions  and  reskill.  There  are  specific  reasons  for  this.  The  Nordic countries,  each  different,  are  all  very  small  — the  population  of  Denmark  is about  the  same  as  that  of  greater  Boston,  for  example.  Their  size  has  long obliged  them  to  be  open  to  international  trade,  and  over  time  they  have  in¬ ternalized  the  lesson  that  success  on  international  markets  demands  high Introduction  15 levels  of  national  cross-class  cooperation.  Active  labor  market  policies  and monetary  policy  prudence  have  long  been  central  parts  of  the  package.  The Swedes  were  never  extravagantly  Keynesian,  for  example,  and  the  Danes  tied their  currency  to  the  D-Mark  early  in  the  1980s,  binding  themselves  to  the tough  monetarism  of  the  German  Bundesbank.  As  conditions  changed  around them,  therefore,  Denmark  and  Sweden  began  with  helpful  policy  legacies, although  even  being  so  endowed  none  of  the  Nordic  countries  has  avoided severe  moments  of  crisis  and  change.6  Moreover,  their  much-admired  labor market  flexibility,  monetary  soundness,  and  admirable  welfare  states  have not  always  helped  the  center-left.  In  Denmark  social  democrats  have  been relatively  weak  and  the  country  is  now  run  by  a  center-right  coalition.  Finn¬ ish  politics  has  almost  always  involved  centrist  governing  coalitions.  In  Swe¬ den  once-hegemonic  social  democrats  are  now  out  of  power  and,  if  they return,  will  only  do  so  as  part  of  a  complex  coalition.  The  Norwegians  are exceptional  in  this  discussion  because  they  have  had  oil  to  grease  their  eco¬ nomic  wheels. The  United  Kingdom  has  provided  a  very  different  northern  European success  story,  although  it  now  seems  over.  Here  good  recent  results  for  the center-left  are  in  large  part  the  product  of  radical  discontinuities  caused  by Thatcherite  neoliberalism.  The  Thatcher  years  undid  much  of  Old  Labour’s postwar  heritage  of  a  vast,  inefficient,  public  sector,  decentralized  collective bargaining  that  fed  chronic  inflation,  and  persistent  budgetary  difficulties. They  left  a  lean,  mean  liberal  environment,  and  until  its  defeat  in  2010,  New Labour  achieved  success  through  its  intelligent  acceptance  of  this  as  a  basis upon  which  to  build.  The  point  of  departure  for  its  Third  Way  was  thus  an  ex¬ treme  market  fundamentalism  that  cried  out  for  a  move  to  the  center  and  an effort  to  restore  public  services.  New  Labour  was  also  blessed  until  recently by  a  decade  of  steady  economic  growth,  which  it  helped  sustain  through prudent  public  financial  management.  New  Labour  thus  had  resources  for  a series  of  modest  innovations,  particularly  in  social  policy.  To  be  sure,  it  took policy  creativity  to  zero  in  on  what  to  do,  and  the  good  if  also  flawed  leader¬ ship  of  Tony  Blair  to  carry  it  out.  The  present  financial  crisis  profoundly  chal¬ lenges  the  New  Labour  formula,  however. The  EU’s  continental  political  economies,  in  contrast  to  the  Nordic  coun¬ tries  and  the  United  Kingdom,  have  been  more  troubled,  with  center-lefts deeply  implicated.  Excepting  brief  interludes,  France  has  had  low  growth  and high  employment  since  the  early  1990s.  The  French  left,  obliged  to  work  radi¬ cal  changes  in  financial  and  monetary  policies  in  the  1980s,  has  been  slow  at adapting  to  the  need  for  a  more  liberal  and  flexible  labor  market.  These  two processes  may  have  been  linked.  French  governments  of  the  center-left  and 16  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch sometimes  of  the  center-right,  afraid  of  electoral  reactions  to  labor  market reform,  reduced  the  size  of  the  workforce  at  taxpayers’  expense  in  ways  that may  have  made  economic  matters  worse.  One  consequence  has  been  high, and  not  terribly  productive,  levels  of  public  spending.  Moreover,  despite  in¬ cremental  but  serious  welfare  state  reforms,  there  has  been  growing  division between  insiders  and  outsiders.  The  center-left  has  had  huge  problems  devel¬ oping  attractive,  coherent  programs  and  has  lost  almost  all  major  elections since  1993. Germany  started  out  better  placed  than  France  for  the  new  world.  It  did not  need  to  abandon  Keynesianism,  because  the  long-standing  monetarist practices  of  its  Bundesbank  had  ruled  it  out  in  the  first  place.  Also,  Germany pursued  an  export-oriented  development  strategy  built  around  very  competi¬ tive  manufacturing  operations,  whose  success  had  trickled  down  to  finance a  generous  welfare  state.  Thus  while  virtually  everyone  else  faced  trauma  in the  1980s,  Germany  sailed  as  Modell  Deutschland.  But  the  end  of  the  cold  war and  globalization  proved  more  troublesome.  German  unification,  a  huge  po¬ litical  success,  was  promoted  in  economically  unsound  ways  and  led  to  huge and  chronic  internal  west-east  transfers  (upward  of  5%  of  GDP  annually),  a huge  jump  in  unemployment,  and  chronic  budgetary  problems.  Germany  re¬ mains  the  world’s  leading  exporter,  but  at  the  cost  of  increased  capital  invest¬ ment  and  labor  shedding.  Germany’s  exporting  companies  now  employ  fewer well-paid,  highly  skilled,  and  flexible  workers.  But  German  society  has  been more  and  more  troubled.  Recent  social  policy  reforms  have  helped,  but  the German  welfare  state  remains  expensive,  and  trickle-down  effects  from  suc¬ cessful  exporting  no  longer  reliably  float  broader  living  standards.  The  result has  been  insider-outsider  dualism.  The  German  center-left,  held  responsible by  parts  of  its  working  class  base  for  painful  welfare  state  reforms,  has  lost electoral  support  to  a  new  left  competitor,  die  Linke,  whose  stock  in  trade  is defensive  resistance  to  social  policy  change. In  southern  Europe  the  distinctive  character  of  political  regimes  has  af¬ fected  prospects  of  the  center-left.  In  Italy  the  left  long  meant  the  Italian Communist  Party  (PCI),  which  had  deep  working-class  roots,  solid  experience in  local  government,  and  a  leadership  less  craven  in  its  relations  with  Moscow than  its  counterparts  in  the  rest  of  Europe,  France  especially.  It  would  for  all these  reasons  become  Eurocommunism’s  best  hope  in  the  1970s.  But  the  PCI was  also  ghettoized,  and  its  dominance  of  the  working-class  vote  produced  for most  of  the  postwar  era  a  rallying  of  right-wing  and  centrist  political  forces around  the  Christian  Democratic  Party  (DC),  which  had  an  effective  lock  on central  government.  That  firm  grip  allowed  Italian  politics  to  remain  clien- telist  and  corrupt,  and  the  corruption  enveloped  nearly  everyone,  including Introduction  17 the  socialists  under  Bettino  Craxi.  The  end  of  the  cold  war  and  of  Christian Democratic  domination  had  the  effect  of  undermining  both  left  and  right:  the PCI  became  a  shadow  of  its  former  self;  the  DC  suffered  massive  defections and  was  replaced  by  smaller,  more  erratic,  and  often  right-wing  groupings; and  the  socialists  never  recovered  from  the  scandals  known  collectively  as Tangentopoli.  One  consequence  was  a  center-left  that  was  fragmented  and lacked  a  history,  vision,  and  program;  a  second  was  the  rise  of  the  clownish, populist,  but  electorally  successful  Silvio  Berlusconi;  the  third  was  a  policy stasis,  as  no  party  or  coalition  could  muster  the  will  or  the  means  to  reform the  welfare  state  and  economy.  Italy  as  a  society  has  thus  also  moved  toward the  dualism— the  insider-outsider  pattern  visible  elsewhere— but  with  more corruption  and,  it  must  be  admitted,  much  better  style. Spain,  Portugal,  and  Greece,  in  contrast,  all  lived  under  authoritarian  dic¬ tatorships  that  did  not  end  until  the  mid-1970s.  In  both  Spain  and  Greece  they ended  in  ways  that  helped  lefts  to  become  center-lefts  and  then  gave  them  an unusual  record  of  electoral  success.  In  part  this  was  because  in  both  countries rights  had  been  tainted  by  complicity  with  the  dictatorships.  The  center-lefts thus  had  access  to  power  which,  in  the  context  of  joining  the  EU  and  mod¬ ernizing  their  societies  and  economies,  gave  them  a  widely  shared  national mission  and,  with  success,  strong  new  credibility.  The  Portuguese  left  did  less well,  losing  its  post-dictatorship  advantage  through  excess  revolutionary  pos¬ turing  and  internal  divisions. The  new  lefts  of  Eastern  European  countries  provide  different  illustrations of  the  importance  of  historical  legacies.  Revulsion  with  the  communist  past ruled  out  the  emergence  of  strong  forms  of  traditional  social  democracy.  As they  democratized  and  built  market  societies,  these  countries  started  out  on  a more  liberal  path  than  their  Western  European  neighbors.  Ironically,  this  ten¬ dency  has  not  prevented  center-lefts,  often  formed  from  the  remnants  of  com¬ munist  parties,  from  winning  elections.  The  policies  that  they  then  carried  to power  have  been  very  different  from  those  in  the  West.  Two  decades  of  tran¬ sition  are  not  long  enough  to  discern  permanent  trends,  however,  and  the situation  remains  unsettled. Including  the  American  Democratic  Party  in  a  comparative  analysis  of center-left  parties  is  unorthodox,  since  unlike  Europe,  America  has  not  pro¬ duced  a  socialist  movement  tied  to  a  strong  union  movement.7  Yet  the  Demo¬ crats  may  have  become  center-left  before  anyone  else,  obliged  by  their  differ¬ ent  historical  trajectory  to  build  complex  alliances  with  social  groups  other than  the  working  class  and  to  deal  with  unusually  powerful  capitalists.  At  the same  time,  from  the  New  Deal  through  the  1960s  the  Democrats  followed many  of  the  policy  trajectories  of  their  European  brethren.  But  constrained 18  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch by  an  anti-statist  political  culture,  a  fragmented  federal  state,  and  a  weak labor  movement,  the  American  welfare  state  was  a  “residual”  one,  combin¬ ing  tax-subsidized,  employer-provided  retirement  and  healthcare  benefits  for workers  in  the  core,  mostly  unionized  sectors  of  the  economy,  government- sponsored  pension  and  healthcare  programs  for  the  elderly,  and  means-tested programs  for  the  poor.  Momentum  in  the  growth  of  an  already  limited  wel¬ fare  state  was  largely  stopped  in  the  early  1980s  by  a  deeply  rooted  and  long- lived  conservative  political  reaction  that  lasted  until  Barack  Obama’s  victory in  2008. Ironically,  owing  to  the  size  and  global  strength  of  its  economy,  the  United States  has  been  able  to  circumvent  some  of  the  crises  that  have  bedeviled European  countries.  The  United  States  spearheaded  the  international  shift away  from  Keynesianism,  but  the  administration  of  Ronald  Reagan,  while hawkish  about  the  practices  of  other  governments,  was  able  to  engineer  a quick  and  politically  beneficial  recovery  from  transitional  recession  by  run¬ ning  budget  deficits  that  could,  thanks  to  American  international  monetary and  financial  centrality,  be  financed  in  global  capital  markets  by  foreign  in¬ vestors  and  central  bankers.  It  was  only  during  the  Democratic,  center-left presidency  of  Bill  Clinton  that  the  United  States  turned  toward  obeying  stan¬ dard  rules  of  fiscal  responsibility;  these  were  swiftly  abandoned  by  President George  W.  Bush,  who  returned  to  the  use  of  internationally  financed  budget deficits  to  fund  sweeping,  politically  driven  tax  cuts  for  corporations  and  the upper  class.  Rule  violations  and  role  reversals  have  seemed  eminently  fea¬ sible  for  a  country  that  has  been  the  biggest  elephant  in  the  international  eco¬ nomic  zoo,  at  least  until  very  recently. The  negative  consequences  of  these  practices  and  of  the  harsh  conserva¬ tism  that  pushed  them  forward  are  in  part  why  even  as  Europe  continued  to liberalize,  the  Democratic  Party  in  the  United  States  began  to  move  toward  a more  active  government  economic  role.  With  the  bursting  of  the  technology and  housing  bubbles,  economic  growth  and  job  creation  in  the  United  States slowed,  while  globalization,  technological  change,  the  weakening  of  labor unions,  a  declining  minimum  wage,  and  regressive  Republican  tax  policy  con¬ tributed  to  stagnant  wages,  eroded  retirement  and  healthcare  benefits,  and increased  inequality.  In  response  to  all  these  developments,  as  well  as  to  the resulting  shift  of  American  public  opinion  to  the  left  since  the  mid-1990s, and  with  the  continued  availability  of  capital  in  global  markets,  Democratic policy  intellectuals  and  politicians  themselves  moved  a  bit  to  the  left.  Re¬ considering  the  economic  and  political  primacy  of  reduced  budget  deficits, Democratic  elites,  in  some  cases  drawing  on  the  example  of  the  European  ex¬ perience,  began  to  call  for  universal  healthcare,  increased  public  investment, Introduction  19 wage  insurance  for  workers  displaced  by  globalization,  and  progressive  tax reform. This  Democratic  shift  to  the  left  accelerated  briefly  in  the  wake  of  Obama’s victory  and  the  global  economic  crisis,  which  at  least  temporarily  relaxed  tra¬ ditional  constraints  on  an  expanded  government  role.  In  addition  to  rescuing failing  financial  institutions  and  auto  companies,  Obama  and  congressional Democrats,  in  the  face  of  vociferous  Republican  opposition,  passed  a  mas¬ sive  economic  stimulus  program  and  a  budget  resolution  — including  aid  to the  states  and  big  increases  in  public  investment  in  infrastructure  and  “green jobs”  — to  spark  an  economic  recovery  and  strengthen  the  foundations  for long-term  growth.  After  an  epic  battle,  Obama  and  his  allies  then  successfully restructured  the  nation’s  healthcare  system  and  later  enacted  an  important if  modest  financial  reform  bill.  However,  a  persistently  weak  economy  and mounting  public  concern  over  bailouts,  rising  spending  and  deficits,  and  “Big Government”  led  to  significant  Republican  gains  in  the  congressional  mid¬ term  elections  in  2010,  jeopardizing  the  durability  of  the  recent  shift  to  the left  in  United  States  politics. There  is  therefore  considerable  variety  in  the  economies  and  societies where  center-left  parties  operate  and  hope  to  make  gains.  There  are  also  very different  histories,  whose  legacies  may  not  quite  determine  the  future  but nevertheless  matter  greatly.  Still,  the  center-left  parties  work  within  strik¬ ingly  similar  electoral  maps  across  Europe  and  North  America,  confront  sur¬ prisingly  similar  social  and  economic  problems,  and  must  find  their  way within  a  common  world  economy.  We  believe  that  it  is  therefore  worth  ex¬ amining  their  situations  and  prospects  together. The  Book  and  Its  Goals The  book  explores  the  post-Keynesian,  globalized  political  world  in  which  the center-left  finds  itself  after  the  cold  war  and  assesses  its  consequences  and implications.  It  is  premised  on  a  belief  that  it  is  unhelpful  to  lament  the  recent narrowing  of  political  debate  and  to  regard  the  acceptance  of  new  constraints as  betrayal.  Instead,  it  will  probe  the  new  political  structures  faced  by  the center-left  with  an  eye  toward  realizing,  seizing,  and  expanding  the  political possibilities  that  they  offer.  We  shall  investigate  the  center-left’s  more  suc¬ cessful  initiatives  and  analyze  when  and  where  they  occurred,  which  condi¬ tions  facilitated  the  most  useful  political  responses,  which  barriers  blocked their  emergence  in  other  places,  and  how  they  were  subject  to  limitations even  where  they  were  politically  feasible.  Our  work  as  presented  here  will often  be  historical,  but  we  shall  try  consistently  to  look  forward.  It  will  be 20  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch broad  in  its  reach  but  necessarily  selective;  and  it  will  be  transatlantic,  but also  aware  of  the  very  real  differences  that  separate  the  European  experience from  that  of  the  United  States.8 The  first  chapter  focuses  on  the  unique  history  of  social  democracy  in Europe  and  its  roles  in  securing  democracy,  prosperity,  and  a  measure  of social  justice  and  social  protection  in  the  postwar  years.  It  also  makes  clear the  pitfalls,  detours,  and  false  starts  that  accompanied  what  the  author,  Sheri Berman,  considers  the  victory  of  social  democracy,  and  the  continuing  diffi¬ culties  that  social  democrats  have  had  in  understanding  their  own  achieve¬ ments,  sustaining  them  in  hard  times,  and  building  upon  them  in  the  most recent  era.  Gerassimos  Moschonas  follows  with  a  comparative  essay  on  the shifting  electoral  fortunes  and  social  bases  of  center-left  parties  over  the  past quarter-century.  The  story  he  tells  is  mixed  and  complicated,  like  Berman’s, in  which  achievements  and  setbacks  are  carefully  balanced  through  time  and space.  Less  mixed,  but  unsurprisingly  so,  is  the  record  of  center-left  parties in  eastern  and  central  Europe  surveyed  by  Jean-Michel  De  Waele  and  Sorina Soare.  In  that  unfortunate  region  the  legacy  of  “actually  existing  socialism” and  Soviet  domination  cast  doubt  on  the  legitimacy  of  anything  calling  itself socialist  or  social  democratic,  even  as  the  economic  and  social  wreckage  left behind  called  out  for  a  political  vision  offering  more  than  neoliberalism  and “shock  therapy.” Three  case  studies  follow:  on  Britain,  France,  and  Sweden.  Britain  and Sweden  illustrate  two  potentially  viable  paths  for  center-lefts.  France,  in  con¬ trast,  embodies  many  of  the  obstacles  to  taking  any  path.  James  Cronin  re¬ views  the  unhappy  history  out  of  which  New  Labour  emerged  and  argues that  this  history,  and  the  desire  to  transcend  it,  explain  a  great  deal  of  what New  Labour  has  been  about.  Viewed  in  that  historical  context,  New  Labour has  achieved  more  than  it  is  usually  credited  with  having  achieved.  It  may  or may  not  be  a  model  for  the  center-left,  but  despite  its  defeat  in  the  elections of  May  2010,  it  is  at  the  least  a  model  worth  studying.  Art  Goldhammer  and George  Ross  undertake  a  similar  analysis  of  the  lengthy  process  by  which  the French  center-left  reached  its  present  impasse.  They  see  a  record  of  incoher¬ ence  and  factionalism  that  has  prevented  French  socialists  from  capitalizing on  the  many  failures  of  their  opponents  and  from  undertaking  the  sorts  of policies  that  might  give  them  a  more  lasting  purchase  on  voters’  preferences. Jonas  Pontusson  tells  a  different  story  about  Sweden,  where,  he  explains,  a period  of  political  uncertainty  and  economic  distress  in  the  1980s  afforded social  democrats  the  opportunity  to  sort  out  what  was  central  in  their  vision and  program.  That  involved  a  reaffirmation  of  the  party’s  commitment  to work  rather  than  to  a  particular  job,  to  the  skills  and  training  and  social  sup- Introduction  21 ports  required  for  obtaining  and  keeping  work,  and  to  a  world  market  in which  workers  and  firms  would  find  their  just  rewards.  If  properly  under¬ stood  and  locally  tailored,  this  slimmed-down  and  updated  Swedish  model can,  Pontusson  insists,  inspire  the  center-left  in  countries  far  different  from Sweden  and  its  Scandinavian  cousins. What  form  of  center-left  politics  is  likely  or  even  possible  in  a  place  as  dif¬ ferent  as  the  United  States?  That  is  part  of  what  the  three  chapters  focused on  the  American  experience  seek  to  determine.  In  his  chapter  on  electoral dynamics,  Ruy  Teixeira  makes  the  argument  that  for  all  of  America’s  real  and imagined  “exceptionalism,”  and  notwithstanding  its  setback  in  the  congres¬ sional  midterm  elections  in  2010,  the  party  of  the  center-left  is  in  the  process of  becoming  politically  dominant.  Democrats  have  emerged  as  the  party  of professionals  in  the  “knowledge”  industries  and  the  service  sector  as  well  as of  women,  the  young,  and  ethnic  and  racial  minorities.  The  party  has  lost support  among  its  traditional  bases  in  the  white  working  class,  but  offsetting this  to  a  considerable  extent  is  that  those  workers  who  do  vote  Democratic, mainly  those  in  trade  unions,  turn  out  in  large  numbers  to  do  so.  Teixeira differs  sharply  from  those  who  argued  before  the  last  two  election  cycles that  the  unusual  strength  of  the  religious  right,  the  effects  of  Republican- controlled  redistricting,  and  the  enduring  attraction  of  tough  rhetoric  on  na¬ tional  security,  immigration,  and  divisive  social  issues  had  given  Republi¬ cans  a  permanent  edge.  Teixeira  concludes  his  highly  useful  corrective  by predicting  that  despite  the  current  decline  in  Obama’s  popularity  and  the Democrats’  substantial  midterm  losses  in  2010,  due  in  both  cases  mainly  to the  weak  economy,  the  subsequent  economic  turnaround  and  the  continued growth  of  the  Democrats’  demographic  coalition  will  likely  produce  a  reelec¬ tion  victory  for  Obama  in  2012  and  a  broader  Democratic  revival.  Time  will tell  if  Teixeira’s  relatively  optimistic  forecast  is  borne  out. Chris  Howard  breaks  with  the  conventional  wisdom  about  the  supposed retrenchment  of  American  social  policy,  describing  a  record  of  consistent  and not  insignificant  increases  in  what  would  normally  be  considered  govern¬ ment  social  expenditure.  Spending  in  the  United  States  does  not  match  that in  other  developed  nations,  but  America  is  not  quite  the  laggard  it  is  often thought  to  be.  Howard  stresses  three  additional  and  critical  features  of  the American  welfare  state:  a  reliance  on  the  tax  system  to  transfer  funds  to  those in  need;  the  tendency  of  government  programs  to  miss  those  most  in  need and  to  focus  instead  on  those  with  real  but  less  pressing  needs;  and,  because the  United  States  economy  generates  very  unequal  incomes  and  distributes wealth  disproportionately  to  the  very  top,  the  failure  of  increases  in  social spending  to  do  much  to  redress  inequality.  Howard  further  shows  that  the 22  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch Democratic  Party  bears  considerable  responsibility  for  the  recent  growth  in social  spending,  although  the  enactment  of  social  programs  and  the  shift  in the  distribution  of  social  benefits  has  often  required  cooperation  from  Re¬ publicans.  Assessing  the  future  of  the  American  welfare  state  in  the  wake  of the  current  economic  crisis,  Howard  notes  the  many  positive  provisions  of the  recently  enacted  economic  stimulus  and  healthcare  reform  bills.  He  con¬ cludes  somewhat  pessimistically,  however,  that  for  a  number  of  economic  and political  reasons,  Obama  and  congressional  Democrats  are  unlikely  to  make more  than  a  dent  in  poverty  and  inequality. James  Shoch’s  chapter  on  globalization  begins  by  noting  that  European social  democrats  have  long  recognized  the  benefits  of  free  trade  while  both compensating  “losers”  with  various  social  policies  and  expanding  public  in¬ vestment  to  boost  national  competitiveness  and  save  and  create  jobs.  The Democratic  Party,  however,  once  committed  to  free  trade,  has  in  the  past  few decades  charted  a  different  course.  Democratic  presidents  representing  broad national  constituencies  have  continued  to  promote  trade  liberalization.  But congressional  Democrats,  under  strong  pressure  from  trade-battered  labor constituents  while  also  unable  or  unwilling  to  press  for  significant  compensa¬ tory  or  public  investment  programs  in  the  face  of  Republican  attacks  on  them as  “tax-and-spend”  liberals,  have  instead  opposed  and  in  some  cases  blocked recent  free  trade  initiatives.  Barack  Obama’s  victory  and  the  expansion  of the  Democrats’  congressional  majorities  in  2008  initially  appeared  to  signal a  new  era  of  increased  social  and  public  investment  spending  and  thus  also  a possible  eventual  decline  of  labor  and  Democratic  opposition  to  freer  trade. But  Democratic  midterm  losses  in  2010  and  likely  further  Senate  setbacks  in 2012,  Shoch  concludes,  have  seriously  diminished  these  prospects. Taken  together,  the  three  chapters  devoted  to  the  United  States  show  that the  center-left  in  America  faces  much  the  same  set  of  problems  as  elsewhere and,  especially  in  light  of  the  election  results  from  2008,  that  the  Democratic Party’s  potential  to  win  elections,  despite  its  current  slide  in  approval,  may be  at  least  equal  to  that  of  any  center-left  party  in  Europe.  The  American chapters  also  show,  however,  that  historically  center-left  policies  are  perhaps harder  to  develop,  implement,  and  maintain  in  America  than  in  Europe.  Still, policy  and  politics  go  together  everywhere,  and  some  of  the  most  pressing policy  concerns  will  pose  difficulties  for  center-left  parties  on  both  sides  of the  Atlantic.  The  last  three  chapters  in  the  book  demonstrate  this  very  clearly. Jane  Jenson  looks  closely  at  what  have  been  termed  “new  social  risks”  and the  policy  responses  they  have  provoked.  New  risks  come  in  part  from  the changing  demography  of  the  workforce,  as  more  women  work  and  family structures  shift,  and  from  the  changed  nature  of  work  itself,  which  is  now Introduction  23 less  secure,  more  variable  over  time,  and  more  highly  concentrated  in  sectors and  regions.  Specifically,  there  are  now  more  single  mothers  as  well  as  more women  working,  and  more  of  the  so-called  working  poor.  The  main  response to  this  set  of  changes  has  been  to  try  to  get  more  people  into  the  workforce  — labor  market  activation  is  the  term  for  this— or  to  make  work  pay  better, either  by  subsidizing  low-paid  work  or  by  supplementing  wages  with  social supports.  Jenson  demonstrates  that  these  problems  and  responses  are  shared across  different  countries  with  historically  rather  different  welfare  systems and  types  of  political  economy.  The  implication  is  that  systems  and  regimes and  parties  can  and  will  learn  from  each  other,  because  whatever  the  policy legacy,  the  problems  are  converging  in  a  more  and  more  global  economy. Sofia  Perez  makes  a  very  similar  argument  about  an  issue  that  is  equally important  for  the  center-left:  immigration.  All  over  Europe  there  are  more immigrants  than  before,  and  some  of  them,  especially  those  from  Africa, Asia,  and  the  Middle  East,  are  by  definition  more  different  from  Europeans than  earlier  immigrants  and  in  that  respect  less  easily  integrated  in  the  soci¬ eties  to  which  they  have  come.  The  effects  of  immigration  have  varied  be¬ tween  countries,  Perez  shows,  but  everywhere  it  matters  in  unprecedented ways  and,  one  might  add,  in  ways  that  have  affected  American  politics  for  a very  long  time.  The  center-left  has  problems  with  immigration,  since  part  of its  natural  base  (organized  labor)  may  find  immigrants  an  economic  threat, but  the  center-right  faces  similar  problems  (with  employers).  Both  factions try  to  avoid  these  problems  through  symbolic  political  positions  which  tend to  cancel  the  partisan  effects. The  penultimate  piece  in  our  collection  is  George  Ross’s  analysis  of  the  im¬ pact  of  the  European  Union  on  the  center-left.  When  the  EU  began  as  a  Com¬ mon  Market,  many  on  the  left  regarded  it  as  either  a  capitalist  plot  or  an  ir¬ relevancy  for  national  politics.  Then  from  the  mid-1980s,  when  the  EU  came to  exercise  new  and  extensive  power  over  its  member  states,  lefts  had  to  pay more  attention.  For  a  while  some  hoped  for  a  “social  Europe,”  but  recently  the EU  has  looked  more  like  a  force  for  globalization  and  market  liberalization. Ross  provides  a  tour  of  these  moves  and  what  each  has  meant  for  parties  of the  center-left  across  the  continent.  His  is  a  particularly  intimate  and,  at  base, disenchanted  view,  but  he  sees  possibilities  as  well  as  constraints  in  EU  insti¬ tutions  which  are  obliged  to  speak  in,  if  not  seek,  broad  consensus.  Ross’s  ac¬ count  of  the  EU  is  in  many  ways  an  account  of  the  present  state  of  the  world economy  and  of  the  institutions  and  assumptions  that  govern  it,  and  so  also of  their  impact  on  the  prospects  of  the  center-left  in  Europe  and  elsewhere.  It is  a  reminder  again  of  the  novel  mix  of  constraints  and  opportunities,  limits and  possibilities,  within  which  center-left  politics  now  operates,  and  which 24  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch must  be  mastered  if  it— or  rather  they,  for  the  constituents  of  the  center-left are  many  and  varied— are  to  prosper  and  fulfill  the  hopes  of  supporters. The  book  ends  not  with  a  summary  but  a  set  of  reflections  on  what  the center-left  and  its  components— be  they  socialists  or  social-democrats  or democratic  socialists  or  members  of  the  Labour  Party  or  just  plain  Demo¬ crats  in  the  United  States  — have  meant  in  the  past  and  how  the  world  they inhabit  today  requires  that  they  evolve  new  identities,  meanings,  and  means of  being  effective.  The  portrait  which  emerges  is  varied  and  nuanced.  Some center-lefts  are  better  placed  than  others  to  conciliate  the  demands  of  eco¬ nomic  management,  humane  policy  innovation,  and  popular  support.  Some live  in  institutional  environments  that  favor  success;  for  others  this  is  less true.  Some  have  been  able  to  sustain  support  among  a  large  number  of  voters, while  others  live  in  fragmented  political  landscapes  that  vastly  complicate the  tasks  they  need  to  undertake.  All  face  a  new  historical  crossroads,  cre¬ ated  by  the  collapse  of  the  global  financial  sector  that  spread  from  the  United States  outward  beginning  in  2008. It  is  too  soon  to  know  what  this  crisis  will  bring  for  center-lefts,  but  signifi¬ cant  change  is  likely.  Initial  responses  pointed  to  a  blunting  of  the  excessive faith  in  markets  that  had  colored  politics  everywhere  where  center-lefts  had operated  for  the  past  quarter-century,  a  return  to  government  and  politics in  the  making  of  key  economic  and  social  decisions,  enhanced  regulation  of markets,  and  perhaps  even  more  extensive  global  governance.  All  these  ini¬ tial  efforts  were  first  aid,  designed  to  save  North  America,  Europe,  and  the rest  of  the  world  from  the  catastrophic  collapse  of  the  global  financial  sector. They  did  not  necessarily  indicate  a  fundamental  shift,  and  in  any  case  history tells  us  that  major  economic  crises  have  not  immediately  helped  lefts.  The “Great  Recession”  lingers,  its  effects  still  spreading,  but  if  recent  electoral cycles  are  an  indication,  it  has  benefited  center-right  parties  for  the  most part.  This  is  predictable,  as  is  the  way  in  which  conservatives  have  sought to  turn  what  was  initially  a  crisis  of  capitalism,  for  which  capital  itself  was largely  blamed,  into  a  crisis  of  the  welfare  state  and  social  provision.  The big  question  not  yet  answered  is  whether,  as  has  often  happened  in  the  past, center-lefts  will  eventually  be  able  to  regroup,  gain  strength,  and  bring  new and  needed  reforms.  Crises  can  present  great  political  opportunities,  but  one can  never  be  sure  just  who  will  be  able  to  seize  these  opportunities.  Center- lefts  should  be  in  a  position  to  profit  if  they  are  able  to  recognize  that  this crisis  is  an  invitation  not  to  resurrect  the  past  but  rather  to  innovate  in  ways that  could  enhance  and  restore  economic  security  and  produce  sustainable new  development  and  greater  distributional  justice  and  opportunity  for  their supporters. Introduction  25 Notes 1.  The  editors  are  more  than  aware  of  their  debt  to  the  enormous  and  thoughtful literatures  on  which  they  build.  Some  of  that  is  reflected  in  the  references,  but  surely not  all. For  a  sampling  of  the  best  literature  and  extensive  references  see  Sassoon  2010  and Bartolini  2007. 2.  The  only  really  effective  left  internationalism  of  the  twentieth  century  turned out  to  be  imposed  and  enforced  on  communists  by  the  Soviet  Union. 3.  Whether  the  experience  of  the  1970s  truly  disproved  Keynesian  notions  and policy  prescriptions  remains  controversial.  So  too  are  the  questions  of  how  and  when Keynesian  ideas  were  adopted  and  implemented  in  various  countries.  Even  in  Britain, where  Keynes  himself  was  intimately  involved  in  policymaking  from  the  1920s  until his  death  in  1945,  it  can  be  argued  that  Keynesianism  triumphed  as  a  means  to  fight inflation  during  the  Second  World  War  rather  than  as  a  means  to  counter  depression and  stimulate  the  economy.  See  Hall  ed.  1989. 4.  The  narrowing  is  especially  evident  among  those  who  seek  to  resist  it.  See,  for example,  the  review  by  Therborn  (2007)  of  the  ideas  and  projects  of  those  who  place themselves  to  the  left  of  the  center-left. 5.  A  number  of  authors,  most  notably  Iversen  and  Stephens  (2008),  have  sought to  combine  the  “varieties  of  capitalism”  and  “welfare  state  regimes”  frameworks  in  a notion  of  “welfare  production  regimes.”  See  also  Schroder  2008. 6.  Denmark’s  crisis,  like  that  in  the  Netherlands,  came  earlier  in  the  1980s.  The Swedes  had  several  years  of  inflation,  high  unemployment,  and  financial  instability  in 1990  which  led  them  to  join  the  EU.  Finland  had  a  massive  crisis  with  higher  unem¬ ployment  than  anyone  in  the  EU  15  after  the  end  of  the  cold  war  in  the  1990s.  The  Nor¬ wegians  had  oil.  See  Dolvik  2008  and,  on  the  Netherlands,  Visser  and  Hemerijk  1997. 7.  The  question  of  whether  to  study  the  United  States  alongside  other  advanced industrial  societies  is  often  debated  but  seldom  resolved.  Does  “American  exceptional- ism”  render  comparison  meaningless,  or  is  the  United  States  similar  enough  to  justify comparison?  See  among  many  others  Lipset  and  Marks  2000,  Kopstein  and  Steinmo eds.  2008,  and  Baldwin  2009. 8.  As  noted  above,  this  volume  builds  upon  the  efforts  of  many  other  scholars. There  are  a  number  of  admirably  broad  studies  on  the  center-left,  most  of  which  un¬ fortunately  end  chronologically  at  roughly  the  point  where  our  volume  will  begin. These  works  also  focus  almost  exclusively  on  Europe.  One  classic  example  is  Scharpf 1987,  which  treats  only  the  end  of  the  Keynesian  postwar  boom  years.  Other  large- scale  and  important  studies— including  Bartolini  2007,  Sassoon  2010,  Eley  2002,  and Pierson  2001a— bring  their  stories  to  a  close  at  roughly  similar  points.  Kitschelt  1994 is  an  impressive  analysis  whose  focus  is  primarily  on  parties  and  voting  rather  than policy,  and  its  database  may  now  be  somewhat  out  of  date.  Moschonas  2002  comes close  chronologically  to  what  we  propose,  even  if  it  remains  European  in  its  focus, but  Moschonas’s  presence  among  our  contributors  indicates  that  he  has  a  great  deal 26  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch more  to  say.  Another  impressive  and  more  current  study,  focused  on  the  experience  of parties  in  power  in  six  countries,  is  Merkel,  Petring,  Henkes,  and  Egle  2008.  On  recent developments  in  social  democracy,  including  the  turn  toward  “third  way”  reforms,  see Bailey  2009a  and  Huo  2009.  In  more  of  a  political  theory  vein  see  Meyer  with  Hinch- man  2007.  More  prescriptively  see  Giddens  1998. In  addition  to  these  general  works  there  are  a  number  of  very  good  studies  of  the prospects  of  social  democracy  for  sustaining  electoral  coalitions  or  achieving  success in  key  policy  areas:  generating  growth,  managing  industrial  relations,  and  maintain¬ ing  welfare  states  in  the  face  of  the  new  constraints.  For  good  examples  on  parties  and politics  see  Berman  2006  and  two  important  earlier  studies:  Piven  ed.  1992  and  Ander¬ son  and  Camiller  1994.  There  is  also  an  extensive  pertinent  literature  on  policy  areas. On  economic  policy  per  se  see  Boix  1998,  Glyn  2001,  and  Blyth  2002.  On  social  policy and  the  welfare  state  there  is  a  huge  literature.  See  for  example  the  classic  work  by Esping-Andersen  (1990),  as  well  as  Garrett  1998,  Hicks  2000,  Pierson  2001b,  Stephens and  Stephens  2001,  Swank  2002,  Esping-Andersen,  Gallie,  Hemerijk,  and  Myles  2002, Rieger  and  Leibfried  2003,  Bonoli  and  Powell  eds.  2004,  Ferrera,  Hemerijk,  and Rhodes  eds.  2006,  Giddens,  Diamond,  and  Liddle  eds.  2006,  Pierson  2007,  Svallfors and  Taylor-Gooby  2007,  Rueda  2008,  and  Hausermann  2010. Part  I Ideas,  Projects,  and  Electoral  Realities Social  Democracy’s  Past and  Potential  Future Sheri  Berman The  aim  of  this  book  is  to  figure  out  “what’s  left  of  the  left,”  that  is,  what  the left  or  center-left  stands  for  and  should  aspire  to  accomplish  in  our  current globalized  world.  Globalization  is  seen  as  particularly  problematic  for  the  left because  it  has  thrown  into  question  many  of  the  left’s  traditional  policies  and principles.  Many  insist,  for  example,  that  the  increasing  mobility  and  inter¬ nationalization  of  capital  have  permanently  shifted  the  balance  of  power  in society  in  capital’s  favor.  As  the  exit  options  of  capital  grow,  so  does  the  bar¬ gaining  power  of  employers  vis-a-vis  labor,  thereby  complicating  efforts  to regulate  and  control  business  decisions  and  development.  Similarly,  increas¬ ing  international  competition  is  said  to  make  things  like  generous  welfare states  and  high  tax  rates  an  impediment  to  efficiency  and  therefore  luxuries that  states  can  no  longer  afford.  But  perhaps  more  important  than  global¬ ization’s  impact  on  policies  traditionally  associated  with  the  left  is  its  direct challenge  to  many  of  the  postwar  left’s  key  ideological  principles.  Among the  most  striking  features  of  contemporary  globalization  debates  is  the  wide¬ spread  belief  in  the  primacy  of  economics.  In  the  world  envisioned  by  neo¬ liberals,  markets  would  be  allowed  as  great  a  degree  of  freedom  and  as  wide a  scope  as  possible  and  states  would  be  knocked  from  the  “commanding heights”  that  they  occupied  during  the  postwar  era  (Yergin  and  Stanislaw 1998).  Given  the  historic  connection  between  social  democracy  and  the  use of  the  state  to  provide  services,  facilitate  growth,  and  generally  tame  the  mar¬ ket  and  temper  its  effects,  the  logic  of  this  position  is  that  at  the  beginning of  the  twenty-first  century  there  is  not  much  “left  of  the  left”  at  all.  In  fact, a  number  of  commentators  have  announced  that  “socialism  is  dead”  and,  as Ralf  Dahrendorf  pointedly  insisted,  “none  of  its  variants  can  be  revived.”  It is  now  time,  according  to  Anthony  Giddens,  to  begin  the  process  of  “burying socialism.”1 30  Berman This  chapter  argues  that  such  pessimism  and  the  reading  of  history  that underlies  it  are  not  merely  premature  but  wrong.  Indeed,  the  very  condi¬ tions  that  have  led  so  many  observers  to  proclaim  the  left’s  demise  provide an  excellent  context  for  its  reexamination  and  perhaps  even  rejuvenation. This  is  because  for  all  its  purported  novelty,  the  issue  at  the  heart  of  contem¬ porary  globalization  debates— whether  states  can  and  should  dominate  mar¬ ket  forces  or  must  bow  before  them  — is  in  fact  very  old.  Social  democracy, the  most  successful  version  of  leftist  thinking  and  politics  during  the  twenti¬ eth  century,  emerged  from  similar  debates  within  the  international  socialist movement  a  century  ago.  It  is  only  because  these  debates  have  been  forgotten or  misunderstood  — at  least  until  the  onset  of  the  global  financial  and  eco¬ nomic  crisis  of  2008  — that  contemporary  discussions  of  left  and  contempo¬ rary  political  alternatives  are  so  superficial  and  intellectually  impoverished, and  why  it  is  so  important  to  refresh  the  democratic  left’s  collective  memory about  its  past.  This  chapter  will  endeavor  to  do  just  that,  providing  a  brief summary  of  the  emergence  and  rationale  of  social  democracy.  It  will  then use  this  history  to  provide  a  foundation  upon  which  to  begin  thinking  about possible  paths  forward  for  the  democratic  left  today. The  Origins  of  Social  Democracy Social  democracy’s  intellectual  origins  lie  in  a  debate  that  began  within  the international  socialist  movement  at  the  end  of  the  nineteenth  century.  Like now,  this  was  a  period  of  rapid  globalization.  Spurred  on  by  new  technolo¬ gies  in  communications  and  transportation,  capitalism  had  developed  re¬ newed  vigor  and  was  rapidly  spreading  its  tentacles  across  the  globe.  These changes  made  many  question  the  “orthodox”  version  of  Marxism  that  had established  itself  as  the  official  ideology  of  much  of  the  international  socialist movement  by  this  time.2  The  most  distinctive  features  of  this  doctrine  (which was  largely  codified  by  Marx’s  collaborator  and  leading  apostle,  Friedrich Engels,  and  popularized  by  the  “pope  of  socialism,”  Karl  Kautsky)  were  his¬ torical  materialism  and  class  struggle,  according  to  which  history  was  pro¬ pelled  forward  not  by  changes  in  human  consciousness  or  behavior  but  rather by  economic  development  and  the  resulting  shifts  in  social  relationships.  As Engels  put  it,  “The  materialist  conception  of  history  starts  from  the  propo¬ sition  that .  .  .  the  final  causes  of  all  social  changes  and  political  revolutions are  to  be  sought,  not  in  men’s  brains,  not  in  man’s  better  insight  into  eternal truth  and  justice,  but  in  changes  in  the  modes  of  production  and  exchange. They  are  to  be  sought,  not  in  the  philosophy  but  in  the  economics  of  each  par¬ ticular  epoch”  (Engels  1962,  365-66).  As  one  observer  noted,  what  histori- Social  Democracy's  Past  and  Potential  Future  31 cal  materialism  offered  was  an  “obstetric”  view  of  history:  since  capitalism had  within  it  the  seeds  of  the  future  socialist  society,  socialists  had  only  to wait  for  economic  development  to  push  the  system’s  internal  contradictions to  the  point  where  the  emergence  of  the  new  order  would  require  little  more than  some  midwifery  (Cohen  1999).  And  in  this  drama  the  role  of  midwife was  played  by  class  struggle  and  in  particular  by  the  proletariat.  In  Kautsky’s words,  “economic  evolution  inevitably  brings  on  conditions  that  will  compel the  exploited  classes  to  rise  against  this  system  of  private  ownership”  (Kaut- sky  1910,  90-91).  With  each  passing  day,  ever  larger  would  grow  the  group of  “propertyless  workers  for  whom  the  existing  system  [would  become]  un¬ bearable;  who  have  nothing  to  lose  by  its  downfall  but  everything  to  gain” (Kautsky  1910, 119). By  the  end  of  the  nineteenth  century,  however,  it  was  becoming  increas¬ ingly  clear  that  many  orthodox  Marxist  predictions  were  not  coming  true. The  proletariat  was  not  experiencing  a  steady  “immiserization,”  small  farm¬ ing  and  businesses  were  not  disappearing,  economic  growth  was  continu¬ ing,  and  general  economic  collapse  seemed  increasingly  far  off.  Just  as  Marx¬ ism’s  failings  as  a  guide  to  history  and  economic  development  were  becoming clear,  moreover,  criticism  arose  within  the  international  socialist  movement regarding  its  inadequacy  as  a  guide  to  constructive  political  action.  Parties acting  in  Marx’s  name  had  become  important  political  players  in  a  number of  European  countries  by  the  end  of  the  nineteenth  century,  but  orthodox Marxism  could  not  furnish  them  with  a  strategy  for  using  their  power  to achieve  any  practical  goals.  Orthodox  Marxist  thought  had  little  to  say  about the  role  of  political  organizations  in  general,  since  it  considered  economic forces  rather  than  political  activism  to  be  the  prime  mover  of  history. Around  the  beginning  of  the  twentieth  century,  therefore,  many  on  the left  faced  a  troubling  dilemma:  capitalism  was  flourishing,  but  the  economic injustices  and  social  fragmentation  that  had  motivated  the  Marxist  project in  the  first  place  remained.  Orthodox  Marxism  offered  only  a  counsel  of  pas¬ sivity— of  waiting  for  the  contradictions  within  capitalism  to  bring  the  sys¬ tem  down,  which  seemed  both  highly  unlikely  and  increasingly  unpalatable. Orthodox  Marxism’s  passive  economism  also  did  little  to  meet  the  psycho¬ political  needs  of  mass  populations  under  economic  and  social  stress.  As noted  above,  the  last  years  of  the  nineteenth  century,  like  those  at  the  end  of the  twentieth  and  the  beginning  of  the  twenty-first,  were  marked  by  a  wave of  globalization  and  rapid,  disorienting  change.  This  caused  immense  unease in  European  societies,  and  critics,  not  just  on  the  left  but  increasingly  now on  the  nationalist  right,  railed  against  the  glorification  of  self-interest  and rampant  individualism,  the  erosion  of  traditional  values  and  communities, 32  Berman and  the  rise  of  social  dislocation,  atomization,  and  fragmentation  that  capi¬ talism  brought  in  its  wake  (Hughes  1977).  Orthodox  Marxism  had  little  to offer  those  interested  in  actively  responding  to  capitalism’s  downsides  (rather than  merely  waiting  for  its  collapse)  and  little  sympathy  or  understanding  for growing  nationalist  sentiment.  It  was  against  this  backdrop  and  in  response to  these  frustrations  that  revisionism  emerged. As  the  nineteenth  century  drew  to  its  close,  several  socialists  realized  that if  their  desired  political  outcome  was  not  going  to  come  about  because  it  was inevitable  (as  Marx,  Engels,  and  many  of  their  influential  followers  believed), then  it  would  have  to  be  achieved  as  a  result  of  human  action.  Some,  such  as Lenin,  felt  that  it  could  be  imposed,  and  set  out  to  spur  history  along  through the  politico-military  efforts  of  a  revolutionary  vanguard.  Others,  not  willing to  accept  the  violence  or  elitism  of  such  a  course,  chose  to  revamp  the  social¬ ist  program  so  as  to  attract  the  support  of  a  majority  of  society.  They  felt  that if  the  triumph  of  socialism  was  not  going  to  be  inevitable,  it  could  be  made desirable  and  emerge  through  the  active,  collective  efforts  of  human  beings motivated  by  a  belief  in  a  better,  higher  good. These  democratic  revisionists  rejected  the  pseudo-scientific  and  material¬ ist  justifications  of  socialism  proffered  by  orthodox  Marxists  and  called  for  a rediscovery  of  socialism’s  moral  roots,  for  an  emphasis  on  the  ideals  and  spirit underpinning  the  original  Marxist  project.  (As  some  contemporary  observers noted,  they  wanted  to  exchange  Hegel  for  Kant.)  Although  their  thoughts  and actions  often  emerged  independently  and  differed  according  to  local  context, democratic  revisionists  shared  an  emphasis  on  the  desirability  rather  than the  necessity  of  socialism,  on  morality  and  ethics  as  opposed  to  science  and materialism,  and  on  human  will  and  cross-class  cooperation  rather  than  ir¬ resistible  economic  forces  and  inevitable  class  conflict.  The  most  influential member  of  this  group  was  Eduard  Bernstein,  an  important  figure  in  both  the international  socialist  movement  and  its  most  powerful  party,  the  Sozialde- mokratische  Partei  Deutschlands  (SPD). Bernstein  attacked  the  two  main  pillars  of  orthodox  Marxism  — historical materialism  and  class  struggle  — and  argued  for  an  alternative  based  on  the primacy  of  politics  and  cross-class  cooperation.  His  observations  about  capi¬ talism  led  him  to  believe  that  it  was  not  heading  toward  its  collapse  but  rather was  becoming  increasingly  complex  and  adaptable.  Thus  instead  of  waiting until  capitalism’s  demise  for  socialism  to  emerge,  he  favored  trying  to  ac¬ tively  reform  the  existing  system.  In  his  view  the  prospects  for  socialism  de¬ pended  “not  on  the  decrease  but  on  the  increase  of .  .  .  wealth,”  and  on  the ability  of  socialists  to  come  up  with  “positive  suggestions  for  reform”  capable of  spurring  fundamental  change  (Bernstein  1898). Social  Democracy's  Past  and  Potential  Future  33 Bernstein’s  loss  of  belief  in  the  inevitability  of  socialism  led  him  to  appre¬ ciate  the  potential  for  political  action.  In  his  view,  orthodox  Marxists’  faith in  historical  materialism  had  bred  a  dangerous  political  passivity  that  would cost  them  the  enthusiasm  of  the  masses.  He  felt  that  the  doctrine  of  inevitable class  struggle  shared  the  same  fatal  flaws,  being  both  historically  inaccurate and  politically  debilitating.  There  was  actually  a  natural  community  of  inter¬ est  between  workers  and  the  vast  majority  of  society  that  suffered  from  the injustices  of  the  capitalist  system,  he  argued,  and  socialists  should  regard dissatisfied  elements  of  the  middle  classes  and  peasantry  as  potential  allies ready  to  be  converted  to  the  cause. Bernstein’s  arguments  were  echoed  by  a  small  but  growing  number  of  re¬ visionist  socialists  across  Europe,  who  shared  an  emphasis  on  a  political  path to  socialism  rather  than  its  necessity,  and  on  cross-class  cooperation  rather than  class  conflict.  During  the  last  years  of  the  nineteenth  century  and  the first  years  of  the  twentieth,  revisionism  progressed  in  fits  and  starts,  within and  across  several  countries,  and  although  Bernstein  and  his  fellow  revision¬ ists  insisted  that  they  were  merely  “revising”  or  “updating”  Marxism,  their fiercest  critics— the  defenders  of  orthodoxy— saw  clearly  what  the  revision¬ ists  themselves  were  loath  to  admit:  that  they  were  arguing  for  a  replace¬ ment  of  Marxism  with  something  entirely  different.  By  abandoning  histori¬ cal  materialism  and  class  struggle,  they  were  in  fact  rejecting  Marxism  as thoroughly  as  Marx  had  rejected  liberalism  a  half-century  earlier.  But  the revisionists  were  not  yet  ready  to  fully  accept  the  implications  of  their  views and  make  a  clean  break  with  orthodoxy.  The  result  was  growing  tension  and confusion,  which  left  the  international  socialist  movement,  like  many  of  its constituent  parties,  a  house  divided  against  itself.  The  First  World  War  and  its aftermath  brought  the  house  down. The  vast  changes  unleashed  by  the  Great  War  led  many  on  the  left  to  ex¬ plicitly  reject  class  struggle  and  historical  materialism  and  to  openly  em¬ brace  their  antitheses— cross-class  cooperation  and  the  primacy  of  politics. The  doctrine  of  class  struggle  suffered  a  critical  blow  with  the  outbreak  of  the war.  Socialist  parties  across  the  continent  abandoned  their  suspicion  of  bour¬ geois  parties  and  institutions  and  threw  their  support  behind  the  states  they had  hitherto  pledged  to  destroy.  The  doctrine  came  under  even  more  pressure in  the  postwar  era,  as  the  democratic  wave  that  spread  across  much  of  Europe confronted  socialists  with  unprecedented  opportunities  for  participation  in bourgeois  governments.  Given  a  chance  to  help  form  or  even  lead  democratic administrations,  many  were  forced  to  recognize  the  uncomfortable  truth  that workers  alone  could  never  deliver  an  electoral  majority  and  that  cooperation with  non-proletarians  was  the  price  of  political  power.  The  war  also  revealed 34  Berman the  immense  mobilizing  power  of  nationalism  and  bred  a  generation  that valued  community,  solidarity,  and  struggle.  Populist  right-wing  movements across  the  continent  were  riding  these  trends,  and  many  socialists  worried that  clinging  to  orthodox  Marxism’s  emphasis  on  class  conflict  and  proletar¬ ian  exclusivity  would  prevent  them  from  responding  to  the  needs  of  ordinary citizens  and  thus  cause  them  to  lose  ground  to  competitors. The  second  pillar  of  orthodox  Marxism,  historical  materialism,  was  also dealt  a  critical  blow  by  the  war  and  its  aftermath.  The  pivotal  position  occu¬ pied  by  socialist  parties  in  many  newly  democratized  countries  after  the Great  War  made  it  increasingly  difficult  to  avoid  the  question  of  how  political power  could  contribute  to  socialist  transformation,  and  the  subsequent  onset of  the  Great  Depression  made  submission  to  economic  forces  tantamount  to political  suicide.  Protests  against  liberalism  and  capitalism  had  been  growing since  the  end  of  the  nineteenth  century,  but  war  and  depression  gave  these protests  a  mass  base  and  renewed  momentum,  with  the  legions  of  the  dis¬ affected  ready  to  be  claimed  by  any  political  movement  promising  to  tame markets.  Orthodoxy’s  emphasis  on  letting  economic  forces  be  the  drivers  of history  meant  that  here  too  it  ceded  ground  to  activist  groups  on  the  right. As  socialist  parties  stumbled  and  fell  in  country  after  country,  a  growing number  of  socialists  became  convinced  that  a  whole  new  vision  was  neces¬ sary  for  their  movement— one  that  would  supplant  rather  than  tinker  with orthodoxy.  So  they  turned  to  the  themes  set  out  by  revisionism’s  pioneers a  generation  earlier:  the  value  of  cross-class  cooperation  and  the  primacy of  politics.  In  the  context  of  the  interwar  years  and  the  Great  Depression this  meant  first  and  foremost  using  political  forces  to  control  economic  ones. Where  orthodox  Marxists  and  classical  liberals  preached  passivity  in  the  face of  economic  catastrophe,  the  new,  truly  “social  democratic”  leftists  fought  for programs  that  would  use  the  power  of  the  state  to  tame  the  capitalist  system. Neither  hoping  for  capitalism’s  demise  nor  worshipping  the  market  uncriti¬ cally,  they  argued  that  the  market’s  anarchic  and  destructive  powers  could and  should  be  fettered  at  the  same  time  that  its  ability  to  produce  unprece¬ dented  material  bounty  was  exploited.  They  thus  came  to  champion  a  real “third  way”  between  laissez-faire  liberalism  and  Soviet  communism.  These themes  found  their  advocates  within  all  socialist  parties.  In  Belgium,  Hol¬ land,  and  France,  for  example,  Hendrik  De  Man  and  his  Plan  du  travail  found energetic  champions.  De  Man  argued  for  an  activist  strategy  to  combat  eco¬ nomic  depression,  an  evolutionary  transformation  of  capitalism,  and  a  focus on  the  control  rather  than  the  ownership  of  capital.  Activists  in  other  parts of  Europe  echoed  these  themes:  in  Germany  and  Austria  reformers  advo¬ cated  government  intervention  in  the  economy  and  pseudo-Keynesian  stimu- Social  Democracy's  Past  and  Potential  Future  35 lus  programs;  and  in  Sweden  the  Swedish  social  democratic  party,  the  SAP, initiated  the  single  most  ambitious  attempt  to  reshape  capitalism  from  within (Berman  2006). Regardless  of  the  specific  policies  they  advocated,  one  thing  that  joined  all budding  interwar  social  democrats  was  a  rejection  of  the  passivity  and  eco¬ nomic  determinism  of  orthodox  Marxism  and  a  belief  in  the  need  to  use  state power  to  tame  capitalism.  In  order  to  do  this,  however— and  finally  relegate historical  materialism  to  the  dustbin  of  history— they  had  to  win  majority support  for  their  programs  and  fight  back  the  advances  of  the  growing  nation¬ alist  right.  Hence  during  the  interwar  years  many  returned  to  the  themes  of cross-class  cooperation  that  Bernstein  and  other  revisionists  had  preached a  generation  earlier.  In  an  era  of  dislocation  and  disorientation,  these  social democrats  realized  that  appeals  to  the  “people,”  the  “community,”  and  the common  good  were  much  more  attractive  than  the  class  struggle  perspective of  orthodox  Marxism  or  the  individualism  of  classic  liberals.  Therefore  they often  embraced  communitarian,  corporatist,  and  even  nationalist  appeals and  urged  their  parties  to  make  the  transition  from  workers’  to  “people’s” parties. It  was  only  in  Scandinavia  and  in  Sweden  in  particular  that  a  unified  party embraced  this  new  approach  wholeheartedly.  This  is  why  one  must  turn  to the  Swedish  case  to  observe  the  full  dimensions,  and  potential,  of  the  so¬ cial  democratic  experiment  at  this  time.  During  the  interwar  years  the  SAP began  to  develop  a  comprehensive  economic  program  designed  to  harness the  powers  of  the  market  and  reshape  the  Swedish  polity.  In  selling  this  pro¬ gram  to  the  electorate,  especially  during  the  depression,  the  SAP  stressed  its activism  and  commitment  to  the  common  good.  For  example,  during  the  elec¬ tion  campaign  of  1932  a  leading  party  paper  proclaimed:  “Humanity  carries its  destiny  in  its  own  hands. . . .  Where  the  bourgeoisie  preach  laxity  and  sub¬ mission  to  .  .  .  fate,  we  appeal  to  people’s  desire  for  creativity  .  .  .  conscious that  we  both  can  and  will  succeed  in  shaping  a  social  system  in  which  the fruits  of  labor  will  go  to  the  benefit  of  those  who  are  willing  to  . . .  participate in  the  common  task”  ( Social-Demokraten ,  15  September  1932). The  SAP’s  leader  Per  Albin  Hansson,  meanwhile,  was  popularizing  his theme  of  Sweden  as  the  “folkhemm”  or  “people’s  home.”  He  declared,  “The basis  of  the  home  is  community  and  togetherness”  and  stressed  that  social democracy  strove  to  “break  down  the  barriers  that  .  .  .  separate  citizens” (Hansson  1982  [1928]).  The  result  was  that  while  in  countries  such  as  Ger¬ many  and  Italy  the  populist  right  assumed  the  mantle  of  communal  solidarity and  put  together  devastatingly  effective  cross-class  coalitions,  in  Sweden  it was  the  social  democrats  who  became  seen  as  the  champions  of  the  “little 36  Berman people,”  the  party  that  was  “one  with  the  nation”  and  was  taking  critical  steps toward  becoming  a  true  “people’s  party.”  These  positions  helped  the  SAP  to form  a  majority  government  through  an  alliance  with  the  peasantry,  and  reap political  rewards  from  the  economic  recovery  that  eventually  occurred. By  the  mid-i930s  the  democratic  strand  of  revisionism  had  therefore  blos¬ somed  into  a  powerful  and  creative  political  movement  all  its  own.  Ortho¬ dox  Marxism’s  historical  materialism  and  class  struggle  were  jettisoned  for  a belief  in  the  primacy  of  politics  and  cross-class  cooperation,  and  these  prin¬ ciples  were  translated  into  a  distinctive  and  viable  policy  agenda  based  on  a “people’s  party”  approach  together  with  a  commitment  to  using  the  state  to control  markets.  Together  this  added  up  to  social  democracy.  It  was  only  in Sweden,  however,  that  social  democrats  were  able  to  take  charge  of  a  politi¬ cal  party,  and  so  it  was  only  there  that  the  social  democratic  agenda  was  fully implemented  during  the  interwar  period. The  Postwar  Era If  during  the  interwar  years  social  democrats  generally  lost  the  battle  for  the soul  of  the  left,  except  in  Scandinavia  and  particularly  in  Sweden,  the  story changed  after  the  Second  World  War  as  many  of  the  social  democrats’  ideas and  policies  ultimately  triumphed,  on  the  left  and  across  much  of  the  politi¬ cal  spectrum.  The  political  chaos  and  social  dislocation  of  the  1930s  were held  to  have  been  caused  by  the  Great  Depression,  which  in  turn  was  held to  have  been  caused  by  unregulated  markets  — and  so  actors  from  across  the European  political  spectrum  agreed  on  the  inadvisability  of  taking  that  path again.  And  so  as  Europe  struggled  to  rebuild  economically  while  trying  to head  off  the  political  and  social  instability  that  had  led  to  ruin  in  the  past, there  was  widespread  agreement  that  unchecked  capitalism  could  threaten goals  in  all  three  spheres.  After  1945,  therefore,  Western  European  nations started  to  construct  a  new  order,  one  that  could  ensure  economic  growth while  at  the  same  time  protecting  societies  from  capitalism’s  destructive  con¬ sequences  (Marglin  and  Schor  1991;  Armstrong,  Glyn,  and  Harrison  1991). As  John  Ruggie  has  put  it,  postwar  policymakers  “seized  upon  the  state  in the  attempt  to  reimpose  broader  and  more  direct  social  control  over  market forces,”  redefining  the  “legitimate  social  purposes  in  pursuit  of  which  state power  was  expected  to  be  employed  in  the  domestic  economy”  (Ruggie  1982, 386).  No  longer  would  states  be  limited  to  ensuring  that  markets  could  grow and  flourish;  no  longer  were  economic  interests  to  be  given  the  widest  pos¬ sible  leeway.  Instead,  after  1945  the  state  became  generally  understood  as  the guardian  of  society  rather  than  the  economy,  and  economic  imperatives  were Social  Democracy's  Past  and  Potential  Future  37 often  forced  to  take  a  back  seat  to  social  ones.  Throughout  Western  Europe states  explicitly  committed  themselves  to  managing  markets  and  protecting society  from  its  most  destructive  effects. Across  Europe,  in  short,  the  postwar  order  represented  something  quite unusual.  Crosland  pointed  out  that  it  was  “different  in  kind  from  classical capitalism  ...  in  almost  every  respect  that  one  can  think  of”  (Crosland  1967, 34),  while  Andrew  Shonfield  questioned  whether  “the  economic  order  under which  we  now  live  and  the  social  structure  that  goes  with  it  are  so  differ¬ ent  from  what  preceded  them  that  it  [has  become]  misleading  ...  to  use  the word  ‘capitalism’  to  describe  them”  (Shonfield  1969,  3).  But  of  course  capital¬ ism  did  remain— even  though  it  was  a  very  different  capitialism  than  before. After  1945  the  market  system  was  tempered  and  limited  by  political  power, and  the  state  was  explicitly  committed  to  protecting  society  from  the  market’s worst  consequences.  Scholars  have  long  recognized  that  this  new  order  rep¬ resented  both  a  decisive  break  with  the  past  and  a  repudiation  of  the  radical left’s  hopes  for  an  end  to  capitalism  (Maier  1981;  Offe  1983).  What  they  have often  failed  to  appreciate  is  just  how  much  it  was  a  repudiation  of  traditional liberalism  as  well.  The  core  principle  of  the  new  system— that  political  forces should  control  economic  ones— was  a  reversal  of  both  classical  liberalism’s theory  and  its  long-standing  practice.  The  most  common  term  used  to  de¬ scribe  the  postwar  system— Ruggie’s  “embedded  liberalism”  (Ruggie  1982)  — is  thus  a  misnomer.  If  liberalism  can  be  stretched  to  encompass  an  order  that saw  unchecked  markets  as  dangerous,  that  had  public  interests  trump  private prerogatives,  and  that  granted  states  the  right  to  intervene  in  the  economy and  society  to  protect  a  “common”  or  “public”  interest,  then  the  term  is  so elastic  as  to  be  nearly  useless.  In  fact,  rather  than  a  modified,  updated  form  of liberalism,  what  spread  like  wildfire  after  the  war  was  really  something  quite different:  social  democracy. Although  the  postwar  order  represented  a  clear  triumph  for  social  demo¬ cratic  principles,  and  marked  the  first  time  that  Western  Europe  was  able to  combine  economic  growth,  well-functioning  democracy,  and  social  sta¬ bility,  social  democracy’s  victory  was  not  complete.  Many  on  the  right  ac¬ cepted  the  new  system  out  of  necessity  alone:  once  their  fear  of  economic and  social  chaos  (and  the  radical  left)  faded,  their  commitment  to  the  new order  also  faded.  But  more  interestingly,  many  on  the  left  failed  to  understand or  wholeheartedly  accept  the  social  democratic  compromise.  Although  after 1945  almost  all  democratic  socialist  parties  eventually  turned  themselves  into champions  of  policies  that  helped  temper  and  redirect  market  forces,  this practical  reorientation  was  not  always  matched  by  an  equivalent  ideological one.  Many  democratic  leftists  may  have  embraced  social  democratic  words 38  Berman but  still  didn’t  hear  the  music,  and  they  continued  to  proclaim  their  dedica¬ tion  to  classic,  pre-war  ideological  goals  such  as  transcending  capitalism  en¬ tirely  and  avoiding  too-close  relationships  with  non-proletarian  groups. The  classic  unfolding  of  this  drama  occurred  in  Germany.  Despite  a  radi¬ cally  changed  environment,  after  the  war  the  German  social  democratic party,  SPD,  offered  Germans  a  rehashed  version  of  its  pre-war  program  and appeal.3  The  theoretical  and  historical  sections  of  the  party’s  program  spoke in  traditional  Marxist  tones  not  dramatically  different  from  those  invoked  at Erfurt  more  than  half  a  century  earlier.  Kurt  Schumacher,  who  dominated the  leadership  until  his  death  in  1952,  proclaimed:  “The  crucial  point  [of  the SPD’s  contemporary  agenda]  is  the  abolition  of  capitalist  exploitation  and  the transfer  of  the  means  of  production  from  the  control  of  the  big  proprietors  to social  ownership,  the  management  of  the  economy  as  a  whole  in  accordance not  with  the  interests  of  private  profit  but  with  the  principles  of  economically necessary  planning.  The  muddle  of  the  capitalist  private-economy  . . .  cannot be  tolerated.  Planning  and  control  are  not  socialism;  they  are  only  prerequi¬ sites  for  it.  The  crucial  step  is  to  be  seen  in  drastic  socialisation”  (Schumacher 1986  [1945],  274). In  addition  to  offering  a  bleak,  intransigent  view  of  capitalism’s  possibili¬ ties  and  calling  for  widespread  nationalization,  the  SPD  more  or  less  returned to  its  traditional  emphasis  on  workers  and  suspicion  of  other  parties.  Under Schumacher  “the  party  slid  all  too  easily  into  the  oppositional  stance  of  the Weimar  days,  supremely  confident  that  it  could  spurn  co-operation  with bourgeois  parties  and  win  power  effortlessly  through  the  logic  of  history” (Carr  1987,  194).  But  if  Schumacher  and  his  cronies  were  comfortable  with such  a  position,  others  in  the  party,  and  especially  its  younger  echelons,  were not.  As  the  SPD’s  membership  declined  in  the  1950s,  it  became  painfully  clear that  without  a  change  it  was  heading  for  permanent  minority  status.  Mean¬ while,  the  contrast  between  an  increasingly  dictatorial  regime  in  the  East and  the  Federal  Republic’s  prospering  economy  helped  many  to  realize  that a  fully  socialized  economy  was  inimical  to  both  democracy  and  growth  (Carr 1987, 196).  As  a  result,  in  1955  Schumacher’s  successor  Erich  Ollenhauer  set up  a  commission  to  reevaluate  the  party’s  direction  and  appeal. The  outcome  was  a  full  reconsideration  of  the  SPD’s  course  in  German politics,  the  famed  Bad  Godesberg  program.  Essentially  this  committed  the SPD  to  the  twin  aims  of  a  modern  social-democratic  program:  a  people’s  party strategy  and  a  commitment  to  reform  capitalism  rather  than  destroy  it.  In particular,  Bad  Godesberg  proclaimed  that  the  party  “no  longer  considered nationalization  the  major  principle  of  a  socialist  economy  but  only  one  of several  (and  then  only  the  last)  means  of  controlling  economic  concentra- Social  Democracy's  Past  and  Potential  Future  39 tion  and  power”  (Braunthal  1994, 18).  In  the  program’s  well-known  phrase,  it committed  the  SPD  to  promoting  “as  much  competition  as  possible,  as  much planning  as  necessary.”  Bad  Godesberg  also  attempted  to  reach  beyond  the working  class  by  making  clear  the  party’s  desire  for  better  relations  with  the churches  and  its  commitment  to  defending  the  country  and  supporting  its military.  Finally,  the  Bad  Godesberg  program  marked  the  triumph  of  social democracy  through  its  clear,  if  implicit,  severing  of  socialism  from  Marxism: Democratic  socialism,  which  in  Europe  is  rooted  in  Christian  ethics, humanism  and  classical  philosophy,  does  not  proclaim  ultimate truths— not  because  of  any  lack  of  understanding  for  or  indifference  to philosophical  or  religious  truths,  but  out  of  respect  for  the  individual’s choice  in  these  matters  of  conscience  in  which  neither  the  state  nor  any political  party  should  be  allowed  to  interfere. The  Social  Democratic  party  is  the  party  of  freedom  of  thought.  It  is  a community  of  men  holding  different  beliefs  and  ideas.  Their  agreement is  based  on  the  moral  principles  and  political  aims  they  have  in  com¬ mon.  The  Social  Democratic  party  strives  for  a  way  of  life  in  accordance with  these  principles.  Socialism  is  a  constant  task— to  fight  for  freedom and  justice,  to  preserve  them  and  to  live  up  to  them.  (Miller  and  Pott- hoff,  1986,  275) Bad  Godesberg  marked  a  clear  shift  in  the  SPD’s  stated  identity  and  goals. Yet  if  somewhere  Bernstein  was  smiling  about  his  ultimate  triumph  over Kautsky,  he  might  also  have  been  a  bit  troubled,  because  the  shift  was  at least  as  much  pragmatic  as  it  was  principled,  motivated  by  a  desire  to  break out  of  a  political  ghetto  rather  than  a  decision  to  chart  a  bold  course  for  the future.  In  a  country  where  national  socialism  was  a  recent  memory  and  “real, existing”  socialism  was  being  built  next  door,  the  wish  to  avoid  ideology  and grand  projects  is  perhaps  easy  to  understand.  And  it  was  made  possible  by  the leadership  transition  to  Ollenhauer,  “a  solid,  loyal  party  functionary,  a  man dedicated  to  oiling  the  wheels  of  a  smoothly  running  bureaucratic  machine [who]  was  as  far  removed  from  the  consuming  political  passions  that  fired Kurt  Schumacher  as  anyone  in  the  SPD  could  be”  (Parness  1991,  60).  But  if the  SPD’s  de-ideologizing  made  it  more  palatable  and  less  scary  to  voters— and  it  did  indeed  eventually  lead  to  an  expansion  of  the  party’s  support  and its  participation  in  government  — it  also  had  its  drawbacks.  In  particular,  it “rendered  [the  SPD]  unserviceable  as  a  nexus  for  creating  and  reproducing utopian  aspirations”  (Gorski  and  Markovits  1993,  44),  alienating  from  the party  those  dissatisfied  with  the  status  quo  and  looking  to  transform  it  into something  better. 40  Berman By  the  1960s  the  SPD’s  reorientation  had  thus  opened  a  political  space  to the  party’s  left,  a  trend  furthered  by  its  increasing  intolerance  of  intraparty disputes  and  its  own  activists,  and  the  fall-out  from  its  “Grand  Coalition” with  the  CDU.  When  the  pragmatic  and  centrist  Helmut  Schmidt  became chancellor  after  Willy  Brandt  resigned  in  1974,  the  SPD’s  postwar  transfor¬ mation  was  complete.  Competent  and  determined  but  lacking  transformative goals  and  an  ideological  temperament,  Schmidt  focused  on  proving  that  his government,  and  the  SPD  more  generally,  were  the  most  capable  caretakers of  Germany’s  domestic  economy  and  international  standing.  Schmidt  com¬ mitted  himself  to  maintaining  and  improving  the  living  standards  of  Ger¬ many’s  citizens  and  committed  the  country  to  accepting  NATO  missiles  on European  soil.  Although  successful  on  their  own  terms,  these  stances  further alienated  the  left,  and  by  tying  the  party’s  fortunes  ever  closer  to  the  coun¬ try’s  economy  they  made  the  SPD  vulnerable  to  the  economic  downturn  that began  in  the  1970s. In  short,  by  the  1970s  the  SPD  had  become  so  fully  integrated  into  the  sys¬ tem,  and  so  inflexible  and  ideologically  exhausted,  that  the  partial  discredit¬ ing  of  its  leadership  by  economic  turmoil  dealt  it  a  blow  from  which  it  has  yet to  recover.  Over  the  next  generation  the  party  hemorrhaged  members  and  in¬ creasingly  became  a  home  for  the  elderly  and  beneficiaries  of  the  status  quo. It  lost  the  support  of  the  young  and  the  radical  (many  of  whom  turned  left  to the  Greens),  as  well  as  many  of  the  poor,  unemployed,  and  alienated  (some  of whom  have  lately  turned  to  right  and  left-wing  populism  and  some  to  the  left, die  Linke).  Lacking  anything  distinctive  to  offer,  the  hollowed-out  SPD  now finds  itself  electorally  vulnerable,  subject  to  internal  dissension,  and  increas¬ ingly  unable  to  generate  either  enthusiasm  or  commitment  from  anybody. In  Italy  and  France  the  left’s  trajectories  were  not  entirely  dissimilar,  al¬ though  it  took  even  longer  for  socialists  in  both  countries  to  make  their  peace with  reality.  In  Italy  the  socialists  “jettisoned  what  remained  of  [their]  Marx¬ ist  heritage”  only  in  the  1970s  (De  Grand  1989,  161-62).  When  the  Partito Socialista  Italiano  (PSl)  reestablished  itself  after  the  war  it  quickly  returned, like  the  SPD,  to  many  of  the  same  patterns  and  practices  that  had  doomed  it to  irrelevance  in  the  1920s.  Its  initial  postwar  leader,  Pietro  Nenni,  sought  to ally,  and  even  merge,  with  the  Communists  (the  PCI),  and  believed  that  the party’s  foremost  goal  should  be  the  immediate  formation  of  a  “socialist  Re¬ public.”  His  stances  alienated  the  party’s  more  moderate  and  social  demo¬ cratic  elements,  leaving  the  PSl  weakened  by  infighting. By  1947  Nenni’s  opponents  had  split  off,  leaving  him  free  to  dally  with  the Communists  and  reorganize  the  party  along  Leninist  lines,  thereby  turning  it into  probably  the  “most  radical  and,  in  a  Marxist  sense,  fundamentalist,  of  all Social  Democracy's  Past  and  Potential  Future  41 European  socialist  movements”  (Laqueur  1970, 155).  Despite  or  probably  be¬ cause  of  this,  the  PCI  soon  overwhelmed  the  hapless  PSI,  becoming  the  main party  of  the  left  and  wresting  away  control  of  many  of  the  affiliated  organiza¬ tions  of  the  labor  movement  (Di  Scala  1998,  280).  This  left  the  Italian  center up  for  grabs,  a  situation  of  which  the  Christian  Democrats  took  full  advantage to  become  Italy’s  dominant  party. After  many  years  of  political  irrelevance  the  PSI  was  finally  turned  around by  Bettino  Craxi,  who  transformed  it  into  a  moderate  reformist  center-left party  by  the  1970s.  At  least  initially  this  strategy  paid  off,  and  Craxi  became the  first  socialist  prime  minister  of  Italy  in  1983.  Yet  the  party  proved  unable to  build  on  this  success  and  construct  a  distinctive  and  dynamic  movement with  broad  appeal.  It  was  “too  late  to  wrench  the  PCI’s  strong  grip  from  the masses”  (Colarizi  1996,  151),  and  in  any  case  the  PSI  now  lacked  the  type  of clear  ideological  profile  that  might  attract  committed  followers  and  engen¬ der  real  enthusiasm.  Making  matters  worse,  Craxi  suffered  from  the  same weaknesses  as  other  Italian  politicians,  and  in  the  1990s  he  was  convicted  of accepting  bribes  and  kickbacks.  With  a  discredited  leader  and  no  particular raison  d’etre,  Italian  socialism  found  its  renewal  short-lived. French  socialism  offers  yet  another  dreary  version  of  the  same  theme. After  the  war  the  Section  Frangaise  de  l’Internationale  Ouvriere  (SFIO)  aban¬ doned  many  of  its  traditional  policy  stances,  and  most  importantly  ended  its long-standing  internal  battles  over  whether  to  accept  a  position  as  a  junior partner  in  a  governing  coalition.  Nevertheless,  despite  such  changes  the  party was  unable  to  make  a  full  break  with  its  past  or  drop  its  Marxist  rhetoric.  Its most  prominent  member,  Leon  Blum,  vociferously  urged  a  change  of  course and  pushed  for  a  socialism  based  on  evolutionary  rather  than  revolutionary change,  one  committed  to  appealing  to  “people  in  every  walk  of  life”  rather than  one  steeped  in  class  warfare  and  worker  exclusivity  (Graham  1994,  271- 76;  Halperin  1946).  Yet  his  pleas  were  rejected,  and  at  its  first  postwar  con¬ gress  in  August  1945  the  SFIO  proclaimed:  “The  Socialist  party  is  by  its  nature a  revolutionary  party.  It  aims  at  replacing  capitalist  private  property  by  a society  in  which  natural  resources  and  the  means  of  production  are  socially owned  and  classes  have  been  abolished.  Such  a  revolutionary  transforma¬ tion,  though  in  the  interest  of  all  mankind,  is  to  be  achieved  only  by  the  work¬ ing  class.  .  .  .  The  Socialist  party  is  a  party  of  class  struggle  founded  on  the organized  working  class”  (Braunthal  1967,  24). During  the  following  years  the  orthodox  faction  of  the  party  continued  to gain  in  strength.  At  the  party’s  congress  in  1946,  for  example,  this  wing,  under the  leadership  of  Guy  Mollet  (who  soon  became  the  party’s  general  secre¬ tary),  attacked  Blum’s  “watering  down”  of  the  party’s  principles  and  “all  at- 42  Berman tempts  at  revisionism,  notably  those  which  are  inspired  by  a  false  humanism whose  true  significance  is  to  mask  fundamental  realities  — that  is,  the  class struggle”  (Colton  1966),  459. Unsurprisingly,  as  a  result  the  party’s  membership  declined  from  354,000 in  1946  to  60,000  in  i960,  while  its  share  of  the  vote  dropped  from  23%  in 1945  to  12.6%  in  1962.  Its  bastions  of  support  ended  up  being  not  the  working classes,  the  young,  or  the  more  dynamic  sectors  of  the  economy  but  rather middle-aged  civil  servants  and  professionals  along  with  those  who  stood to  lose  from  rapid  social  and  economic  change  (such  as  textile  workers  and small  farmers).  As  in  Germany  and  Italy,  meanwhile,  one  consequence  of  the SFlO’s  rhetorical  radicalism  was  that  it  provided  an  opening  for  the  center- right— here  in  the  form  of  Gaullism  —  to  capture  those  groups  alienated  by the  left  and  form  a  true  cross-class  coalition  on  the  other  side  of  the  aisle, thereby  becoming  the  dominant  force  in  French  political  life. The  SFIO  remained  stuck  in  a  rut  through  the  1960s;  yet  continual  elec¬ toral  defeats,  culminating  in  routs  in  1968  and  1969,  finally  led  to  change. Mollet  retired  in  1969  and  a  new,  more  pragmatic  organization,  the  Parti Socialiste  (PS),  arose  in  1971.  It  insisted  on  maintaining  a  clear  left-wing  pro¬ file,  at  least  in  part  so  that  it  could  form  an  alliance  with  the  Communists. The  two  forces  eventually  agreed  on  a  unity  program,  the  Programme  Com- mun,  which  committed  the  Communists  to  democracy  and  pluralism  and  the socialists  to  economic  radicalism,  including  large-scale  nationalizations.  This combined  front  came  to  power  in  1981  during  an  economic  downturn  by  con¬ vincing  voters  that  it  had  the  most  promising  and  innovative  solutions  to France’s  problems. Unfortunately  the  socialists’  economic  program  did  not  work  out  as  hoped, and  the  long-awaited  socialist  government  soon  found  itself  overseeing  an economy  in  turmoil.  Forced  to  act  but  with  little  else  to  fall  back  on,  the socialists  ended  up  making  a  dramatic  volte-face:  by  1982  the  PS  had  moved from  advocating  one  of  the  most  radical  economic  programs  of  any  socialist party  in  Europe  to  implementing  deflationary  measures  and  dramatically  cut¬ ting  public  spending.  By  the  end  of  the  twentieth  century  the  French  social¬ ists,  like  their  German  and  Italian  counterparts,  had  shown  themselves  able to  win  elections  but  could  no  longer  explain  to  themselves  or  others  why  any¬ one  should  care. Not  all  socialist  parties  suffered  the  same  fate.  As  might  be  expected,  the Swedes  did  well  — largely  because  they,  unlike  most  socialist  parties  elsewhere, understood  and  believed  in  what  they  were  doing.  The  SAP  was  able  to  prosper at  the  polls  and  maintain  its  distinctiveness  by  recognizing  that  the  two  tasks were  in  fact  complementary:  the  party’s  ability  to  integrate  individual  policy Social  Democracy's  Past  and  Potential  Future  43 initiatives  into  a  larger  social  democratic  whole  ensured  that  it  remained  more vibrant  and  successful  than  most  of  its  counterparts  in  the  rest  of  Europe. To  be  sure,  the  Swedish  social  democrats  started  off  the  postwar  era  in  a better  position  than  parties  on  the  left  elsewhere.  They  could  build  on  their own  governing  record  rather  than  struggle  to  reestablish  their  very  existence as  a  party,  and  their  country  emerged  in  better  shape  from  the  war  than  did most  others.  But  even  more  than  luck  and  a  head  start,  their  success  was  due to  their  having  fully  internalized  the  core  elements  of  social  democratic  ideol¬ ogy  and  devoted  themselves  to  developing  creative  policies  for  putting  them into  practice. Politically  the  SAP  worked  during  the  postwar  years  to  strengthen  its  hold over  a  broad  cross-section  of  the  Swedish  electorate.  Continuing  the  strategy that  it  had  embraced  during  the  interwar  years,  the  party  directed  its  appeals not  to  workers  alone  but  to  the  Swedish  “people”  (folk)  in  general.  In  doing so  it  exploited  its  wartime  leadership  role,  loudly  proclaiming  its  commit¬ ment  to  social  solidarity  and  the  national  interest.  There  was  no  conflict  be¬ tween  these  positions  and  social  democracy,  the  party  insisted,  because  social democracy  properly  understood  was  all  about  advancing  collective  interests rather  than  those  of  a  particular  group  or  class.  SAP  appeals  were  saturated with  references  to  “solidarity,”  “cooperation,”  and  “togetherness.”  This  was especially  true  in  discussions  of  plans  for  an  expanded  welfare  state,  which was  presented  as  part  of  the  SAP’s  strategy  for  creating  “the  strong  society” (starka  samhallet)  and  protecting  the  public  from  the  uncertainties  and  in¬ securities  inherent  in  modern  capitalism.  Meanwhile  the  SAP  also  continued along  its  pre-war  path  of  using  state  intervention  to  manage  the  economy and  sever  the  link  between  individuals’  market  position  and  their  broader  life chances  (Stephens  1986;  Svensson  2002;  Pontusson  this  volume).  What  made these  efforts  so  distinctive  was  not  only  the  sizable  amount  of  intervention and  decommodification  they  involved,  but  also  the  way  they  were  presented as  part  of  a  larger,  transformative  project.  The  Rehn-Meidner  model,  for  ex¬ ample,  was  sold  not  merely  as  a  practical  package  of  wage  regulations  but as  a  case  study  in  the  party’s  strategy  of  increasing  “social  control”  over  the economy  without  resorting  to  full-scale  nationalization  (Meidner  1993,  211). The  Swedish  welfare  state  was  understood  in  a  similar  way.  Its  comprehen¬ siveness  and  universalism  helped  “manufacture  broad  class  (even  cross-class) solidarity  and  social  democratic  consensus,”  while  at  the  same  time  margin¬ alizing  “the  market  as  the  principal  agent  of  distribution  and  the  chief  deter¬ minant  of  peoples’  life  chances”  (Esping-Andersen  1985,  245).  The  party  con¬ sciously  used  social  policy  to  expand  its  hold  over  the  electorate  and  develop a  sense  of  common  interests  across  classes. 44  Berman Recognizing  the  growing  importance  of  white-collar  workers,  for  example, the  SAP  explicitly  designed  social  policies  that  would  appeal  to  them  and tie  their  interests  to  those  of  other  workers.  This  was  particularly  clear  in the  fight  over  supplemental  pensions  at  the  end  of  the  1950s,  when  the  SAP “stressed  the  common  interests  of  manual  and  white-collar  workers  [in  these pensions]  and  the  struggle  for  the[m]  as  of  vital  interest  for  all  wage-earners” (Svensson  1994,  272).  As  with  increased  economic  management,  moreover, welfare  state  enhancements  were  presented  as  valuable  not  only  on  their  own terms  but  as  steps  toward  a  better  future.  The  party  insisted  that  the  welfare state  itself  represented  a  form  of  socialism,  since  under  it  “the  total  income  of the  people  was  regarded  as  a  common  resource  and  a  portion  of  it  was  trans¬ ferred  to  those  with  inadequate  incomes”  (Sainsbury  1990,  66). All  these  strategies  proved  quite  successful,  and  in  the  years  after  the war  the  SAP  was  able  to  remain  firmly  anchored  in  the  working  class  while strengthening  its  support  well  beyond  it.  Still  by  far  the  largest  party  in  the Swedish  political  system,  it  used  its  dominance  to  shift  the  country’s  center of  political  gravity  to  the  left,  and  built  the  greatest  record  of  political  hege¬ mony  of  any  party  in  a  democratic  country  during  the  twentieth  century. Even  so,  the  party  did  not  escape  unscathed  from  some  of  the  problems that  set  back  its  counterparts  elsewhere.  Like  them,  in  the  1970s  it  was  forced to  reevaluate  some  of  its  traditional  tactics  and  even  strategies  (Blyth  2002). It  went  through  a  period  in  the  late  1980s  when  it  appeared  to  be  drifting intellectually  and  politically  (Blyth  2002).  But  because  it  had  strong  reserves of  political,  ideological,  and  intellectual  capital  to  draw  on,  and  had  reshaped the  political  and  social  structure  of  Swedish  society  so  extensively,  in  the end  the  party  was  able  to  weather  the  storm  better  than  others.  It  bounced back  politically,  recaptured  power  in  the  1980s,  and  although  currently  out  of office,  remains  the  dominant  party  in  the  Swedish  political  system  (although it  is  not  as  hegemonic  as  before).  It  has  maintained  its  ability  to  appeal  to voters  across  much  of  the  political  spectrum  and  managed  to  coopt  many  new “postmaterialist”  issues  such  as  environmentalism  and  women’s  rights.  And economically  it  recovered  from  the  fiasco  surrounding  wage  earners’  funds  by essentially  promising  the  electorate  that  it  would  maintain  traditional  social democratic  policies  while  updating  them  as  appropriate  to  deal  with  con¬ temporary  challenges— something  at  which  it  has  been  relatively  successful, overseeing  impressive  economic  growth  in  recent  years  during  its  time  in office,  while  still  maintaining  high  levels  of  social  spending  and  a  commit¬ ment  to  egalitarianism  and  social  solidarity. Perhaps  the  SAP’s  greatest  success  has  been  to  preserve  a  sense  of  social democratic  distinctiveness  in  Sweden  (Castles  1978).  Despite  all  the  changes Social  Democracy's  Past  and  Potential  Future  45 that  have  occurred  in  both  the  domestic  and  international  economy  over  re¬ cent  decades  and  the  current  existence  of  a  bourgeois  government,  the  vast majority  of  Swedes  acknowledge  and  accept  the  SAP’s  basic  ideas  about  the virtues  of  social  solidarity,  egalitarianism,  and  political  control  over  the  econ¬ omy.  Rather  than  question  whether  these  social  democratic  concepts  are worthwhile,  political  debate  in  Sweden  has  tended  to  be  about  whether  the socialists  or  the  bourgeois  parties  are  best  able  to  implement  them  together with  steady  growth. UNDERSTANDING  SOCIAL  DEMOCRACY’S  original  rationale  and  gaining  a renewed  appreciation  for  its  role  in  twentieth-century  political  development is  reason  enough  to  reconsider  the  movement’s  history.  It  turns  out  that  there are  other  pressing  reasons  to  do  so  as  well,  since  many  of  the  hard-earned insights  of  earlier  ideological  battles  have  been  forgotten  in  recent  years,  as a  shallow  version  of  neoliberalism  has  come  to  exert  an  almost  Gramscian hegemony  over  mainstream  public  debate. Globalization,  it  is  often  said,  marks  a  new  era.  The  spread  of  markets across  the  globe,  and  the  deepening  and  quickening  of  economic  intercon¬ nections  accompanying  it,  is  creating  a  fundamentally  new  environment  for leaders  and  publics,  imposing  burdens  while  constraining  choices.  You  can either  opt  out  of  the  system  and  languish,  or  put  on  what  Thomas  Friedman has  called  neoliberalism’s  “Golden  Straitjacket”  — at  which  point  “two  things tend  to  happen:  your  economy  grows  and  your  politics  shrinks”  (Friedman 1999,  87). Globalization’s  onward  march  has  produced  a  backlash  too,  of  course,  and anti-globalization  protests  have  become  a  regular  feature  of  contemporary life.  Yet  if  contemporary  neoliberals  of  the  right  and  center  dismiss  concerns about  globalization’s  individual  and  social  costs,  large  sectors  of  the  left  ex¬ hibit  the  opposite  tendency  and  dismiss  the  huge  gains  that  the  global  spread of  capitalism  has  brought,  particularly  to  the  poor  in  the  developing  world. These  debates  resemble  nothing  so  much  as  those  that  took  place  a  century ago,  out  of  which  the  social  democratic  worldview  first  emerged  (Berman 2006). Democratic  revisionists  such  as  Bernstein  saw  that  capitalism  was  not  col¬ lapsing  and  seemed  likely  to  be  around  for  at  least  the  medium  term.  They decided  accordingly  to  try  to  reform  and  reshape  it  rather  than  destroy  it. Democratic  revisionists  also  recognized  the  need  to  counter  the  immense mobilizing  power  of  nationalism  and  offer  something  to  the  vast  majority  of people  suffering  from  the  injustices  and  dislocations  of  capitalism.  Their  suc¬ cessors  a  generation  later  built  upon  this  foundation,  arguing  that  the  time 46  Berman had  come  to  put  aside  calls  for  capitalism’s  collapse  and  instead  focus  on managing  and  directing  markets.  By  the  1930s  social  democrats  recognized that  markets  and  capitalism  were  not  only  here  to  stay  but  were  an  invaluable tool  for  producing  growth  and  wealth.  At  the  same  time,  they  never  wavered in  their  insistence  that  while  markets  made  great  servants,  they  also  made terrible  masters.  Capitalism  might  be  necessary  to  ensure  an  ever-increasing economic  pie,  but  it  had  to  be  carefully  regulated  by  states  so  that  its  negative social  and  political  consequences  could  be  kept  in  check.  During  the  1930s social  democrats  came  to  see  as  never  before  how  widespread  and  powerful was  the  longing  for  some  sort  of  communal  identity  and  social  solidarity,  and that  if  they  did  not  come  up  with  some  convincing  response  to  this  longing, other  more  nefarious  movements  would  do  so  in  their  place. Whether  or  not  the  participants  recognize  it,  in  other  words,  today’s  battles over  globalization  are  best  viewed  as  simply  the  latest  chapter  in  an  ongoing debate  over  how  to  reconcile  capitalism  with  democracy  and  social  stability. Now  as  before,  liberals  who  venerate  markets  uncritically  and  old-style  left¬ ists  who  are  unwilling  to  recognize  any  good  in  them  have  little  to  offer  the vast  majority  of  people  who  recognize  and  want  to  share  in  capitalism’s  ma¬ terial  benefits  but  who  fear  its  social  and  political  consequences.  Then  as  now, many  liberals  only  see  capitalism’s  benefits  while  many  on  the  left  only  see  its radical  flaws,  leaving  it  to  social  democrats  to  grapple  with  a  full  appreciation of  both. Participants  at  both  extremes  of  today’s  globalization  debates  need  to  be reminded  that  it  was  only  through  the  postwar  settlement  that  capitalism  and democracy  found  a  way  to  live  together  amicably  in  much  of  the  West.  With¬ out  the  amazing  economic  results  generated  by  the  operations  of  relatively free  markets,  the  dramatic  improvements  of  mass  living  standards  through¬ out  the  West  would  not  have  been  possible.  Without  the  social  protections and  limits  on  markets  imposed  by  states,  in  turn,  capitalism’s  benefits  would never  have  been  distributed  so  widely  and  political  and  social  stability  would have  been  infinitely  more  difficult  to  achieve.  One  of  the  great  ironies  of  the twentieth  century  is  that  the  very  success  of  this  social  democratic  compro¬ mise  led  it  to  become  a  background  condition  of  modern  life,  letting  us  forget how  new  and  controversial  it  was  at  one  time. Thus  the  appropriate  response  to  contemporary  conditions  is  neither  to worship  capitalism  nor  scorn  it,  but  to  recognize  its  advantages  and  dis¬ advantages  and  figure  out  ways  to  deploy  the  former  against  the  latter.  The challenge  is  to  dust  off  the  principles  underlying  the  postwar  settlement  and generate  from  them  new  initiatives  that  address  today’s  new  problems  and opportunities.  Many  of  the  policies  that  worked  during  the  postwar  era  have Social  Democracy's  Past  and  Potential  Future  47 run  out  of  steam,  and  the  left  should  not  be  afraid  to  jettison  them.  The  im¬ portant  thing  is  not  the  policies  but  the  goals— encouraging  growth  while  at the  same  time  protecting  citizens  from  capitalism’s  negative  consequences.  In the  era  opened  up  by  capitalism’s  most  recent  crisis,  the  opportunity  for  such political  creativity  is  great,  but  it  will  not  last  forever. Building  on  the  best  traditions,  the  center-left  must  reiterate  its  commit¬ ment  to  managing  change  rather  than  fighting  it,  embracing  the  future  rather than  running  from  it.  This  might  seem  straightforward,  but  in  fact  it  is  not generally  accepted.  Many  European  and  American  liberals  and  social  demo¬ crats  are  devoted  to  familiar  policies  and  approaches  regardless  of  their  prac¬ tical  relevance  or  lack  of  success.  And  many  peddle  fear  of  the  future,  fear  of change,  and  fear  of  the  other.  Increasing  globalization  and  the  dramatic  rise of  giants  in  the  developing  world  such  as  China  and  India  are  seen  as  threats rather  than  opportunities. At  its  root,  these  fears  stem  from  the  failure  of  many  on  the  center-left  to appreciate  that  capitalism  can  be  a  positive-sum  game,  not  a  zero-sum  one— that  over  the  long  run  the  operations  of  relatively  free  markets  can  produce net  wealth  rather  than  simply  shift  it  from  one  pocket  to  another.  Because  so¬ cial  democrats  understand  that  basic  point,  they  want  to  do  what  they  can  to encourage  trade  and  growth  and  cultivate  as  large  a  net  surplus  as  possible- all  the  better  to  tap  it  to  pay  for  measures  that  can  equalize  life  chances  and cushion  publics  from  the  terrors  and  blows  that  markets  can  inflict. Helping  people  adjust  to  capitalism,  rather  than  engaging  in  a  hopeless and  ultimately  counterproductive  effort  to  hold  it  back,  has  been  the  historic accomplishment  of  the  social  democratic  left,  and  it  remains  its  primary  goal today  in  those  countries  where  the  social  democratic  way  of  thinking  is  most deeply  ensconced.  Many  analysts  have  remarked,  for  example,  on  the  impres¬ sive  success  that  countries  like  Denmark  and  Sweden  have  had  in  managing globalization  — promoting  economic  growth  has  increased  competitiveness even  as  the  state  has  ensured  high  employment  and  social  security.  The  Scan¬ dinavian  cases  show  conclusively  that  social  welfare  and  economic  dynamism are  not  enemies  but  natural  allies.  Not  surprisingly,  according  to  surveys  it  is precisely  in  these  countries  that  optimism  about  the  future  and  opinions  of globalization  are  highest.  In  other  parts  of  Europe,  on  the  other  hand,  fear  of the  future  is  pervasive  and  opinions  of  globalization  astoundingly  low.  Since the  election  of  2008  opinion  in  the  United  States  has  been  decidedly  more mixed.  The  goal  of  the  American  center-left  should  therefore  be  to  advocate policies  and  programs  that  promote  both  growth  and  social  solidarity,  rather than  forcing  a  choice  between  them.  Concretely  this  means  agitating  for  poli¬ cies— like  reliable,  affordable,  and  portable  healthcare,  tax  credits  and  other 48  Berman government  support  for  retraining,  investment  in  education,  and  unemploy¬ ment  programs  that  are  both  more  generous  and  characterized  by  properly aligned  incentives  — that  will  help  workers  adjust  to  change  rather  than  make them  fear  it. Just  as  important  is  for  the  center-left  to  regain  its  former  optimism  and vision.  Many  self-described  parties  of  the  left  and  center-left  win  elections, but  few  inspire  much  hope  or  offer  more  than  a  kinder,  gentler  version  of  a generic  centrist  platform.  Given  the  left’s  past,  this  is  simply  astonishing.  The left  has  traditionally  been  driven  by  the  conviction  that  a  better  world  is  pos¬ sible  to  achieve  and  that  it  is  the  left’s  job  to  bring  it  into  being.  But  some¬ how  this  conviction  was  lost  during  the  last  few  decades.  As  Michael  Jacobs has  noted,  “Up  through  the  1980s  politics  on  the  left  was  enchanted— not by  spirits,  but  by  radical  idealism;  the  belief  that  the  words  could  be  funda¬ mentally  different.  But  cold,  hard  political  realism  has  now  done  for  radical idealism  what  rationality  did  for  pre-Enlightenment  spirituality.  Politics  has been  disenchanted”  (Jacobs  2002).  Many  have  welcomed  this  shift,  believing that  transformative  projects  are  passe  or  even  dangerous.  But  this  loss  of  faith in  transformation  “has  been  profoundly  damaging,  not  just  for  the  causes  of progressive  politics  but  for  a  wider  sense  of  public  engagement  with  the  po¬ litical  process.” As  social  democratic  pioneers  of  the  late  nineteenth  century  and  the  early twentieth  recognized,  the  most  important  thing  that  politics  can  provide  is a  sense  of  the  possible.  Against  Marxism’s  and  liberalism’s  laissez-faire  and ultimately  passive  views  of  history,  they  pleaded  for  the  development  of  a political  ideology  based  on  the  idea  that  people  working  together  could  and should  make  the  world  a  better  place.  The  result  was  the  most  successful  po¬ litical  movement  of  the  twentieth  century,  one  that  shaped  the  basic  politico- economic  framework  under  which  we  still  live.  The  problems  of  the  twenty- first  century  may  be  different  in  form,  but  they  are  not  different  in  kind.  There is  no  reason  that  the  accomplishment  cannot  be  developed  and  extended. Notes 1.  See  Sassoon  1996,  647,  for  quotes  from  Alain  Touraine,  Dahrendorf,  and  Giddens. 2.  There  is  a  great  debate  in  the  literature  about  whether  “orthodox  Marxism”  is  a logical  continuation  or  betrayal  of  Marx’s  thought.  Since  I  am  not  concerned  here  with the  true  nature  of  Marxism  but  rather  with  how  a  generation  of  socialists  interpreted or  perceived  Marxism,  this  debate  is  not  directly  relevant  to  the  argument  presented here.  Nonetheless,  it  is  clear  that  Marx’s  relative  lack  of  concern  with  politics,  com¬ bined  with  his  emphasis  on  the  primacy  of  economic  forces  in  history,  created  a  fateful Social  Democracy's  Past  and  Potential  Future  49 dynamic  for  the  generation  of  socialists  that  followed  him.  See,  for  example,  Miliband 1977;  Tucker  1970;  Gouldner  1980;  Schwartz  1995;  and  Cohen  1999. 3.  This  is  perhaps  easier  to  understand  if  one  recognizes  that  many  of  the  party’s initial  postwar  leaders  came  from  its  pre-war  ranks.  Carr  1987;  Miller  and  Potthoff 1986. Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale? The  Electoral  Dynamics  of  European Social  Democratic  Parties,  1950-2009 Gerassimos  Moschonas I  wish  it  was  the  sixties. -Radiohead,  “The  Bends”  (quoted  in  Glyn  2006) Is  Something  Important  Happening  to  Electoral  Social  Democracy? In  this  period  of  significant  political  and  ideological  change,  electoral  de¬ velopments  have  attracted  lively  research  on  an  international  scale.  Para¬ doxically,  however,  the  electoral  dynamics  of  party  families  have  not  been sufficiently  studied  from  a  comparative  and  historical  point  of  view.  As  re¬ gards  social  democracy,  a  very  limited  number  of  works  are  devoted  to  the diachronic  development  of  its  electoral  strength  although  arguments  about electoral  trends  are  everywhere  (Merkel  1992a;  Merkel  2001;  Delwit  2005; Bergounioux  and  Grunberg  1996;  and,  for  the  European  elections,  Grunberg and  Moschonas  2005).  What  hasn’t  been  written  and  said,  by  scholars  and pundits  and  politicians  themselves,  about  the  sudden  weakness  or  strong  re¬ surgence,  the  stagnation  or  golden  age,  the  crisis,  the  decline,  the  stability,  or indeed  the  end  of  social  democracy? The  question  of  the  electoral  development  of  social  democracy  will  be  the principal  subject  of  this  chapter,  which  charts  the  electoral  condition  of  Euro¬ pean  socialism  decade  by  decade  from  the  1950s  to  4  October  2009;  1950  is chosen  as  the  starting  point  for  observation  because  an  analysis  of  electoral trends  can  only  usefully  begin  then.  The  immediate  postwar  period  was  cer¬ tainly  a  critical  moment,  but  the  lack  of  electoral  crystallization  and  consoli¬ dation  renders  it  highly  anomalous  and  hence  inappropriate  as  a  point  of  de¬ parture. The  performance  of  socialist  and  social  democratic  parties  will  be  ob¬ served  in  sixteen  West  European  states  (including,  since  the  1970s,  Greece, Portugal  and  Spain).  Italy  will  be  excluded  from  the  statistics,  even  though  it Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  51 is  a  country  where  the  left  has  been  (and  remains)  influential,  and  not  only electorally.  The  bankruptcy  of  the  Italian  Socialist  Party  (PSI)  in  the  1990s  (a unique  case  of  the  actual  disappearance  of  a  socialist  party)  and  its  “replace¬ ment”  by  a  communist  party  putatively  transformed  into  a  “fully  fledged social-democratic  party”  (Favretto  2006,  163)  — today’s  Democratic  Party- make  diachronic  comparison  inappropriate.  This  is  all  the  more  true  because the  electoral  bases  of  these  two  parties,  which  were  rivals  for  many  years, were  historically  very  different  in  terms  of  electoral  sociology.  Including  Italy would  complete  the  general  picture  but  would  also  lead  to  distortions  of  the “dynamic”  picture  that  is  our  main  focus.1 This  effort  will  provide  a  comprehensive  empirical  grounding  to  help answer  the  questions  that  swirl  around  the  state  and  fate  of  the  center-left, and  of  social  democracy  in  particular.  Is  it  possible  to  craft  a  reliable  peri¬ odization  of  the  electoral  development  of  European  socialism?  Was  there  an electoral  golden  age?  Is  the  hypothesis  of  decline  corroborated  by  the  elec¬ toral  facts?  Is  the  thesis  of  overall  stability  (or  “slight  decline”),  which  is dominant  in  the  specialist  literature,  confirmed?  Which  national  parties  have been  the  big  winners  and  the  big  losers  over  these  last  sixty  years?  What happened  in  the  late  1990s,  during  a  “brief  spell  of  social-democratic  hege¬ mony”  (Bonoli  2004, 197),  when  social  democrats  dominated  governments  in Europe?  To  these  questions  I  shall  try  to  provide  a  “quantitative”  response, while  being  fully  conscious  that  the  quantitative  necessarily  prompts  inter¬ pretive  or  explanatory  reflections,  which  will  be  taken  up  in  the  final  part  of this  chapter. The  central  question  is  of  course  whether  something  important  is  hap¬ pening  to  social  democracy  as  an  electoral  force.  The  answer  is  an  unequivo¬ cal  yes.  Social  democracy  is  in  electoral  crisis,  albeit  not  in  all  countries, and  where  it  is,  not  to  the  same  degree  and  not  in  the  same  way.  Despite local  variations,  the  qualifications  suggested  by  the  specialist  literature  have now  been  overtaken  by  the  steady  march  of  electoral  indicators.  The  trend  is neither  cyclical  nor  random.  This  crisis  is  not  “historic,”  and  there  is  probably nothing  inexorable  about  it,  but  it  is  serious.  The  solidity  of  the  “old  house” (to  borrow  a  phrase  from  Leon  Blum)  is  shaken,  and  the  decline  is  profound and  serious.  Social  democracy  is  experiencing  a  new  electoral  era,  even  if  the dynamics  of  electoral  change  proceed  in  zigzags.  The  medium-term  prospects for  social  democrats  look  bleak,  and  the  recovery  will  not  be  easy. Is  there  then  “nothing  but  doom  and  gloom  in  the  house  of  social  democ¬ racy”?  (Berger  2004,  393).  The  answer  is  paradoxical:  in  terms  of  electoral arithmetic  the  crisis  is  serious;  in  terms  of  its  political  significance  for  gov¬ ernance  it  seems  less  so.  This  is  a  new  electoral  era,  and  the  center-left  is  not 52  Moschonas the  only  political  force  to  be  affected,  so  the  concept  of  “electoral  crisis”  does not  have  the  same  content  as  it  did  in  the  past.  There  appears  to  be  a  “broken equilibrium”  in  politics,  rather  than  a  paradigm  shift  (Jouke  de  Vries,  quoted in  Becker  and  Cuperus  2007).  Social  democracy  is  thus  not  “a  threatened species”  (Hinnfors  2006,  32),  at  least  not  yet.  Furthermore,  it  is  not  the  first time  in  history  that  social  democracy  is  perceived  (to  borrow  Stathis  Kaly- vas’s  expression  regarding  Catholicism)  as  “a  declining  and  spent  force,  re¬ treating  in  front  of  modernization”  (Kalyvas  2003,  303)-  This  does  not  alter the  fact  that  social  democratic  parties  are  in  the  process  of  changing  stature and  dimension.  They  have  become  smaller  and  less  imposing  and  also  less stable  and  robust.  There  has  been  a  change  in  scale. The  Three  Phases  of  Electoral  Social  Democracy Over  the  long  term  (1950-2009)  socialists,  considered  as  a  political  family, have  become  weaker  electorally.  In  the  thirteen  countries  where  diachronic comparison  is  possible  (table  1),  electoral  contraction  was  marked  and reached  a  peak  in  the  years  after  2000.  Social  democracy  declined  from  an unweighted  average  of  33.2%  in  the  1950s  and  1960s  to  26.6%  in  the  period 2000-2009,  a  fall  of  6-6  percentage  points,  or  19.8%;  eleven  of  thirteen parties  registered  scores  inferior  to  those  of  the  1950s.  Only  two  parties,  in France  and  Germany,  improved  their  performance,  and  these  parties  had been  decidedly  weak  in  the  1950s  — a  decade  which  for  them,  against  the  gen¬ eral  trend,  was  the  worst  of  the  postwar  period.  From  another  perspective,  if one  compares  the  period  2000-2009  with  the  best  decade  of  each  party,  the universality  of  the  decline  is  still  more  impressive  (see  table  5).  All  parties, without  exception,  were  electorally  less  successful  in  the  1990s  and  2000s than  they  had  been  in  the  past. Social  democratic  parties  obtained  their  best  results  in  the  1950s  and 1960s  (an  unweighted  average  of  33.2%),  fell  back  moderately  in  the  1970s (to  31.7%),  stabilized  at  a  somewhat  lower  level  in  the  1980s  (31.1%),  and then  returned  to  the  path  of  decline  in  the  1990s  (29.2%)  and  2000-2009 (26.6%).  The  decline  had  been  steady,  with  each  decade  being  less  good  elec¬ torally  than  the  previous  one  (-1.5%  in  the  1970s;  -0.6%  in  the  1980s;  -1.9% in  the  1990s;  and  -2.6%  in  the  2000s).  Thus  the  decline  tended  to  become more  marked  in  the  1990s  and  2000s,  although  social  democracy  was  already weaker  in  these  years.  The  data  in  table  1  indicate  that  the  performance  of  so¬ cial  democracy  can  be  meaningfully  broken  up  into  three  phases  of  approxi¬ mately  twenty  years  each: 1.  The  first  involved  an  electoral  bright  spell  (the  1950s  and  1960s).  While Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  53 Table  1.  Electoral  Performance  in  Legislative  Elections  as  Measured  by  Percentage  of Votes  for  Socialist  Parties  by  Decade,  1950-2009 2000- 1950-59 1960-69 I97O-79 1980-89 1990-99 2009 Austria 43.3 43.3 50.0 45.4 37.3 33.7 Belgium 35.9 31.0 26.6 28.0 23.3 24.6 Denmark 40.2 39.1 33.6 30.9 36.0 26.8 Finland 25.3 23.4 24.5 25.4 24.4 23.0 France 15.2 15.9 21.0 34.5 20.6 24.4 Germany 30.3 39.4 44.2 39.4 36.9 31.9 Ireland 10.9 14.7 12.7 8.9 14.9 10.5 Luxembourg 34.1 33.5 24.8 29.0 23.9 22.5 Netherlands 30.7 25.8 28.6 31.0 26.5 21.2 Norway 47.5 45.5 38.8 37.4 36.0 30.8 Sweden 45.6 48.4 43.7 44.5 39.8 37.5 Switzerland 26.5 25.1 24.1 20.6 20.9 21.4 United  Kingdom 46.3 46.1 39.1 29.2 38.8 38.0 Unweighted  average 33.2 33.2 31.7 31.1 29.2 26.6 of  13  countries Greece 19.5 43.4 42.3 41.6 Portugal 33.4 26.4 39.0 39.9 Spain 29.9 43.9 38.2 40.2 Unweighted  average 33.2 33.2 30.9 32.4 31.2 29.2 of  16  countries Source:  The  data  presented  here  and  in  the  following  tables  are  mostly  based  on  voting  statistics published  by  the  relevant  government  agencies.  For  the  most  recent  period  much  of  the  informa¬ tion  is  available  online  at  various  websites.  The  data  have  been  gathered,  checked,  and  assembled into  their  current  form  by  the  author. not  quite  a  “golden  age”  (other  than  in  a  small  number  of  countries,  social democracy’s  performance  was  not  extraordinary),  it  was  unquestionably  the European  center-left’s  best.* 2  Equally  important  was  the  remarkable  electoral stability  of  the  social  democratic  parties  (Spyropoulou  2008,  51-52).  The 1950s  and  1960s  represent  an  electoral  summit  in  two  respects  — high  elec¬ toral  scores  and  low  volatility— that  has  not  been  attained  since. 2.  This  positive  period  was  followed  by  a  generally  moderate  process  of erosion  during  the  1970s  and  1980s.  This  was  also  a  phase  marked  by  electoral disorder  and  significant  national  fluctuations.  This  was  apparently  a  tran¬ sitional  phase  distinguished  by  sharp  and  contradictory  movements.  Thus social  democracy  became  significantly  weaker  in  more  than  half  of  the  thir¬ teen  countries  included  in  table  1  (Denmark,  Britain,  Norway,  Luxembourg, Sweden,  Belgium,  and  Switzerland).  Second,  in  a  number  of  these  countries (Denmark,  Britain,  and  Norway)  spectacular  defeats  were  suffered.  In  the 54  Moschonas 1980s  some  of  the  parties  in  retreat  (the  Social  Democratic  Labour  Party  of Sweden,  or  SAP;  the  Belgian  Socialist  Party,  or  PS;  and  the  Luxembourg  So¬ cialist  Workers’  Party,  or  LSAP)  — recovered  some  of  their  lost  ground,  while others  continued  on  their  downward  slope  (the  Danish  Social  Democrats,  or SD;  and  the  Social  Democratic  Party  of  Switzerland,  or  SP)  or  dramatically accelerated  it  (the  British  Labour  Party).  By  contrast,  four  social  democratic parties  registered  considerable  success:  the  Social  Democratic  Party  of  Ger¬ many  (SPD),  the  Dutch  Labour  Party  (PvdA),  the  Social  Democratic  Party of  Finland  (SDP),  and  most  notably  the  Social  Democratic  Party  of  Austria (SPO).3 Spectacular  defeats  coexisted  with  dazzling  successes,  contraction  with progress,  violent  decline  with  rapid  recovery  of  influence,  volatility  with  sta¬ bility.  Thus  throughout  these  twenty  years  the  electoral  facts  seem  to  lack  any consistent  pattern.  Nevertheless,  if  the  overall  picture  is  mixed,  three  new trends  are  evident: —  A  moderate  electoral  decline  which,  though  not  general,  affected  a  ma¬ jority  of  center-left  parties.  Since  the  electoral  losses  were  modest  in  the aggregate,  and  since  national  developments  were  decidedly  mixed,  this was  probably  not  the  most  important  trend. —  A  small  number  of  “catastrophic”  electoral  results  (Denmark  and  Norway in  1973,  the  United  Kingdom  in  1983).  These  indicate  that  something  un¬ precedented  was  occurring  at  the  core  of  social  democracy’s  electoral  sup¬ port-something  beyond  conjunctural  oscillations.  But  this  “something” applied  to  only  a  very  limited  number  of  elections  and  parties. —  The  increased  volatility  of  social  democratic  performance  is  the  third  and arguably  the  most  important  development.  Table  2  measures  the  number of  elections  per  decade  in  which  socialists  won  or  lost  five  or  more  percent¬ age  points  compared  with  their  score  in  the  previous  election.  The  pattern is  crystal-clear.  Instability  strongly  increases  after  the  1960s.  The  behavior of  social  democratic  voters  becomes  more  volatile  and  anarchic  during  the 1970s,  and  this  pattern  persists. In  sum,  the  contrast  with  the  past  was  neither  consistent  nor  systematic in  the  years  1970-89.  But  it  did  exist.  Mixed  signals  predominated  and  in¬ creased  weakness  involved  only  a  small  number  of  countries.  Further,  the impressive  performance  of  the  Greek,  Spanish,  and  French  socialists  in  the 1980s,  together  with  quite  good  results  in  Belgium,  the  Netherlands,  Finland, and  Luxembourg,  constituted  reasons  for  optimism  (see  also  Delwit  2005, 63).  Whether  from  the  standpoint  of  electoral  arithmetic  or  that  of  the  psy¬ chology  of  actors  and  voters,  this  was  not  tantamount  to  electoral  crisis.  No Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  55 Table  2.  Changes  of  More  Than  5%  in  Socialist  Vote  between  Two  Legislative  Elections Number  of  Cases 1950s 1960s 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s Increase  of  More  Than  5% 2 4 2 7 3 Decrease  of  More  Than  5% 1 4 7 8 8 Note:  Includes  Austria,  Belgium,  Denmark,  Finland,  France,  Germany,  Ireland,  Luxembourg, Netherlands,  Norway,  Sweden,  Switzerland,  and  United  Kingdom. retrospective  reading  of  the  period  can  alter  this  fundamental  reality.  On  the other  hand,  if  there  was  no  electoral  crisis,  there  were  clear  indications  of partial  or  selective  retreat— and  of  great  instability.  In  the  1970s  and  1980s European  socialism  entered  a  new  era. 3.  The  third  period— the  1990s  and  2000s— was  marked  by  a  new  pro¬ cess  of  electoral  retreat.  Throughout  these  nineteen  years  social  democracy’s earlier  losses  were  confirmed.  Worse,  it  lost  further  ground  and  lost  it  more rapidly.  Relative  to  the  high  point  of  the  1950s  and  1960s,  more  than  two- thirds  of  the  losses  (to  be  precise,  -4.5  points,  or  68.2%  of  the  total  decline) occurred  in  this  period.  Individual  parties,  with  the  notable  exception  of British  Labour,  all  turned  in  average  performances  in  the  2000s  that  were decidedly  inferior  to  those  of  the  1970s  and  1980s.  Certainly  the  simultaneous victories  of  the  social  democrats  in  the  second  half  of  the  1990s— an  event rare  in  the  annals  of  electoral  history— created  the  impression  of  a  strong  re¬ surgence  and  a  change  in  trends.  In  fact  the  recovery  of  influence  in  the  late 1990s  was  modest  and  certainly  very  brief  (see  discussion  below).  In  addi¬ tion,  since  2000  the  process  of  decline  has  again  intensified  and  deepened. During  this  third  phase  (1990s  and  2000s)  signs  of  weakening  abounded,  in¬ stability  was  strongly  on  the  increase,  and  electoral  earthquakes  multiplied, demonstrating  the  extent  to  which  socialist  parties  had  become  vulnerable.4 The  electoral  base  of  social  democracy  became  less  broad  and  far  less  solid. The  Complexity  of  the  Decline: North  and  South,  Big  and  Small,  and  the  European  Union The  preceding  analysis  has  not  taken  into  account  results  in  Spain,  Portugal, and  Greece,  for  the  Iberian  countries  were  long  dominated  by  authoritarian regimes  and  there  was  no  social  democratic  party  in  Greece.  When  we  include the  Spanish  Socialist  Workers’  Party  (PSOE),  the  Panhellenic  Socialist  Move¬ ment  of  Greece  (PASOK),  and  the  Socialist  Party  of  Portugal  (PS)  in  our  calcu¬ lations,  the  image  of  electoral  decline  is  considerably  attenuated. 56  Moschonas If  one  compares  the  thirteen  countries  counted  for  the  early  years  with the  sixteen  relevant  to  the  later  years,  the  unweighted  average  declines  from 33.2%  for  the  1950s  and  1960s  to  29.2%  for  the  years  2000-2009.  Viewed  this way,  socialists  lost  four  points  of  the  total  vote,  or  12%  of  their  own  vote  (as opposed  to  a  drop  of  19.8%  for  the  thirteen  parties  for  which  we  possess  an uninterrupted  series  of  electoral  statistics).  A  calculation  of  this  sort  is  meth¬ odologically  debatable  (because  it  compares  thirteen  parties  for  the  1950s with  sixteen  for  the  2000s),  but  it  does  offer  a  more  rounded  sense  of  the “state  we  are  in.”  It  is  also  important  to  note,  from  this  overall  perspective, the  very  good  performances  of  the  socialist  parties  during  the  1980s,  often viewed  as  a  period  of  social  democratic  setback  and  “held  up  as  the  decade of  the  wave  of  triumphant  neo-liberalism”  (Delwit  2005,  63). The  most  interesting  aspect  of  the  positive  news  from  the  south  is  not quantitative  but  qualitative:  when,  against  the  “general”  trend,  a  group  of parties  shows  signs  of  lasting  success,  it  is  the  significance  of  the  general trend  that  warrants  reexamination.  Thus  an  integrated  reading  yields  a  “dual” image  of  the  electoral  dynamic  of  contemporary  social  democracy.  These  two electoral  faces  of  the  socialist  and  social  democratic  family,  both  of  which  are “true,”  bring  out  the  unique  and  somewhat  contradictory  character  of  the  cur¬ rent  situation.  The  southern  performance  illustrates  the  complexity  of  social democratic  decline. A  further  illustration  of  the  political  complexity  that  lies  behind  the  general decline  can  be  seen  in  the  different  dynamics  of  parties  from  large  countries and  those  from  small  countries.  Figure  1  graphs  the  data.  It  is  apparent  that socialist  parties  from  large  countries  (Germany,  Britain,  France,  and  Spain), which  are  the  main  contributors  to  the  socialist  group  in  the  European  Parlia¬ ment  and  exercise  greater  influence  within  the  European  Union  (EU)  system, do  markedly  better  than  those  from  small  countries  (in  the  2000s,  33.6%  as opposed  to  27.8%  for  small  and  medium-sized  countries),  the  reverse  of  what prevailed  in  the  1950s.  In  addition,  they  do  markedly  better  than  the  socialist family  as  a  whole.5  While  the  1950s  were  the  worst  decade  for  socialists  from large  countries  (because  of  the  extreme  weakness  of  the  French  socialists  and the  mediocre  performance  of  the  German  SPD),  the  period  of  the  last  thirty years  was  an  era  of  moderate  success,  with  strong  British  and  Spanish  results making  a  particular  contribution.  Nevertheless,  in  spite  of  this  trend  the  most recent  electoral  developments  in  Germany  (2009)  did  not  help  to  improve  the social  democratic  influence  inside  the  EU. Yet  another  useful  approach  to  the  data  is  to  focus  on  the  performance  of the  center-left  in  the  European  Economic  Community  (EEC)  and  European Union  (EU).  Successive  enlargements  seem  to  have  led  to  political  consolida- Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  57 —  Big  countries  (without  Italy)  Small  and  medium  countries 20  -I - 1 - 1 - 1 - 1 — - 1 - 1950-59  1960-69  1970-79  1980-89  1990-99  2000-2009 Figure  l.  Average  percentage  of  votes  cast  for  socialist  parties  by  decade  in  large  and  in small  or  medium-sized  countries,  1950-2009. tion  for  the  socialist  family  inside  the  EEC/EU  institutional  system.  Figure  2 displays  the  trajectory  of  social  democratic  electoral  strength  in  legislative elections  in  the  countries  of  the  European  Communities  (from  the  “inner  six” of  1957  to  the  larger  group  that  existed  after  the  “Big  Bang”  expansion  of 2004).  The  center-left  achieved  better  results  in  the  period  1986-2004  than  in the  first  three  decades  of  the  EEC.  From  a  level  of  29.3%  in  the  period  1957-72 for  five  countries  (France;  the  Federal  Republic  of  Germany,  or  FRG;  Luxem¬ bourg;  Belgium;  and  the  Netherlands,  with  Italy  again  excluded),  the  average rises  to  31.3%  for  fourteen  countries  for  1996-2004.  Among  the  new  entrants the  parties  of  southern  Europe  (PASOK  since  1981,  PSOE  and  the  Portuguese PS  since  1986)  have  made  the  greatest  contribution  to  this  upward  trend.  The enlargement  of  1995  (Sweden,  Finland,  and  Austria)  also  improved  center-left influence,  albeit  only  slightly.  As  a  result,  the  losses  of  some  of  the  founding members,  notably  in  the  Benelux  countries,  have  been  more  than  made  up  for by  the  new  entrants.  The  consequence  has  been  an  enhanced  socialist  pres¬ ence  in  European  institutions,  notably  the  European  Council.6  Only  the  recent (but,  it  must  be  noted,  the  largest)  enlargement  of  2004  served  to  weaken  the center-left. These  different  calculations  qualify  the  extent  of  social  democratic  decline over  time  and  also  change  the  political  significance  of  the  decline.  The  devel¬ opment  and  maturation  of  the  European  Union,  which  in  the  1990s  became a  much  more  influential  political  entity  than  the  European  Economic  Com¬ munity  of  previous  years,  increased  the  interdependence  between  national 58  Moschonas 4° 38  - 36 34 32 30 28  - 26  - 24  - 22 20 - 1957-72  1973-80  1981-85  1986-94  1995-2004 5  countries  8  countries  9  countries  I  I  countries  14  countries Figure  2.  Average  percentage  of  votes  cast  for  social  democratic  parties  in  legislative elections  within  EEC  and  EU,  1957-2004  (Italy  excluded). states  and  altered  the  centers  of  decision  making.  Especially  since  the  1980s social  democracy  has  become  weaker  as  an  electoral  phenomenon  than  it was  in  the  past.  However,  its  forces  are  now  better  distributed  geographi¬ cally  and  are  also  rather  more  concentrated  in  decision-making  sites.  In  con¬ sequence,  it  is  not  unreasonable  to  think  that  we  are  witnessing  a  decline  of social  democratic  political  influence  that  is  much  less  important  than  the strictly  arithmetical  tendencies  might  imply.  Paradoxically,  and  fortunately for  social  democracy,  electoral  and  political  dynamics  do  not  fully  converge. Classical  Social  Democracy:  The  Locomotive  Breaks  Down This  complex  and  varied  pattern  of  social  democratic  performance  can  be  fur¬ ther  clarified  by  two  exercises  that  group  parties  in  more  politically  and  his¬ torically  meaningful  categories.  The  first  centers  primarily  on  the  governmen¬ tal  capacity  of  parties  and  their  rootedness  in  the  working  class;  the  second effort  involves  a  categorization  based  on  the  type  of  policy  regime,  specifi¬ cally  the  different  “worlds  of  welfare”  that  social  democratic  parties  helped to  create  and  have  then  inhabited. In  tables  3  and  4  center-left  parties  are  divided  into  three  groups  using  a typology  developed  by  Merkel  and  further  refined  for  this  chapter  (Merkel 1992a).  By  far  the  most  important  criterion  is  electoral  status  and  resulting governmental  capacity.  The  second  is  the  relationship  between  parties  and Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  59 Table  3.  Electoral  Performance  in  Legislative  Elections  as  Measured  by  Percentage  of Votes  for  Social  Democratic  Parties  Classified  by  Type,  1950-2009 Social  Democratic  and  Labourist  Parties:  High  Electoral  Status Relative 1950- 59 1960- 69 1970- 79 1980- 89 1990- 99 2000- 2009 Change, 1950-2009 Austria 43.3 43.3 50.0 45.4 37.3 33.7 -22.2 Denmark 40.2 39.1 33.6 30.9 36.0 26.8 -33.3 Germany 30.3 39.4 44.2 39.4 36.9 31.9 5.3 Norway 47.5 45.5 38.8 37.4 36.0 30.8 -35.2 Sweden 45.6 48.4 43.7 44.5 39.8 37.5 -17.9 United  Kngdom Unweighted 46.3 46.1 39.1 29.2 38.8 38.0 -17.9 average 42.2 43.6 41.6 37.8 37.5 33.1 -21.5 Pragmatic  Coalition-Oriented  Parties:  Medium  Electoral  Status Relative 1950- 59 1960- 69 1970- 79 1980- 89 1990- 99 2000- 2009 Change, 1950-2009 Belgium 35.9 31.0 26.6 28.0 23.3 24.6 -31.6 Finland 25.3 23.4 24.5 25.4 24.4 23.0 -9.3 Netherlands 30.7 25.8 28.6 31.0 26.5 21.2 -30.9 Luxembourg 34.1 33.5 24.8 29.0 23.9 22.5 -34.0 Switzerland Unweighted 26.5 25.1 24.1 20.6 20.9 21.4 -19.2 average 30.5 27.8 25.7 26.8 23.8 22.5 -26.1 trade  unions  (no  matter  which  side  historically  has  preceded  or  dominated the  other)  and  the  extent  of  parties’  integration  in  working-class  milieus. The  third  and  least  important  criterion  is  a  judgment  based  largely  upon  the party’s  history  which  allows  me  — only  when  it  comes  to  borderline  cases  — to include  in  the  same  group  parties  with  similar  historical  trajectories.7 The  question  of  electoral  status  is  fundamental,  for  it  determines  whether social  democratic  parties  can  govern  alone  or  as  dominant  coalition  partners and  whether  as  a  consequence  they  have  the  necessary  resources  to  decisively influence  key  policy  decisions  and  policy  outcomes  and  hence  the  capacity  to “narrow  or  widen  the  ‘corridor  of  action’  for  the  subsequent  choices”  (Merkel 2001,  34).  In  this  sense  electoral  influence  is  an  indirect  identity  factor,  a  con¬ stitutive  element  of  party  identity  dynamics.  Using  these  criteria  makes  it possible  to  place  parties  in  one  of  three  quite  distinct  categories. 1.  Social  democratic  and  Labourist  parties:  high  electoral  status.  The 60  Moschonas Table  4.  Electoral  Performance  in  Legislative  Elections  as  Measured  by  Percentage  of Votes  for  Socialist  Parties  in  New  Democracies  by  Decade,  1950-2009 1950- 59 1960- 69 1970- 79 1980- 89 1990- 99 2000- 2009 Spain 29.9 43.9 38.2 40.2 Portugal 33.4 26.4 39.0 39.9 Greece 19.5 43.4 42.3 41.6 Unweighted  average 27.6 37.9 39.8 40.6 parties  in  this  group— Sweden,  Austria,  Denmark,  Norway,  Great  Britain, and  Germany  — represent  governmental  social  democracy  par  excellence. Four  of  them  (the  Swedish,  Austrian,  Danish,  and  Norwegian  parties)  pos¬ sess  the  distinctive  characteristics  of  the  “classical”  social  democratic  model and  pursue  policies  characteristic  of  the  “welfare  statist  model”  (Merkel 1992a,  144-45).  The  British  Labour  Party,  representing  a  different,  so-called Labourist  model,  is  also  included  in  this  group.  Its  high  electoral  status,  its ability  to  govern  in  single-party  governments  (largely  the  result  of  the  elec¬ toral  system  in  the  United  Kingdom),  and  its  historically  great  penetration  in the  working  class  justify  this  choice.  These  five  parties  were  by  far  the  most strongly  working-class  parties  in  the  1950s  and  1960s.8  The  SPD,  a  party  with heavy  history,  completes  the  picture  of  this  first  group.  Its  consistently  solid electoral  performance  (fluctuating  around  or  above  35%  of  the  electorate) and  its  status  as  the  dominant  partner  in  governmental  coalitions  (the  prac¬ tice  of  forming  “great  coalitions”  being  less  frequent  in  Germany  than  in  the consensus-based  democracies  of  the  second  group)  explain  its  inclusion  in this  category.9  Typically  forced  to  govern  in  coalition  governments  and  char¬ acterized  by  a  more  cross-class  base  of  support,  the  German  party  represents something  of  a  borderline  case,  but  on  balance  it  fits  better  in  this  group than  in  any  other.  Included  in  this  first  group  are  the  world’s  strongest  social democratic  parties.  Their  strength  and  durability  have  led  some  of  them  to be  labeled  huge  “tankers,”  to  use  Peter  Glotz’s  term,  that  turn  around  very slowly  (quoted  in  Kitschelt  1992, 198). 2.  Pragmatic  coalition-oriented  parties:  medium  electoral  status.  This grouping  contains  the  social  democratic  parties  of  Belgium,  the  Nether¬ lands,  Luxembourg,  Finland,  and  Switzerland,  which  are  distinguished  by their  intermediate  competitive  status  and  less  dominant  role  in  government. Since  1945  they  have  been  relatively  frequent  participants  in  coalition  gov¬ ernments,  most  often  with  moderate  center,  center-right,  or  Christian  demo¬ cratic  parties.  In  general  they  have  developed  a  mainstream  and  moderate Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  61 social  democratic  profile  with  a  connection  to  trade  unions.  Most  important, they  have  been  more  or  less  systematically  involved  in  the  “consensus-based” politics  typical  of  polities  that  discourage  the  exercise  of  classical  majoritar- ian  politics.10  (This  group  coincides  with  the  “pragmatic  coalescent  type”  of Merkel’s  typology,  with  Germany  excepted  and  Luxembourg  added.) 3.  Late-developing  socialists.  The  center-left  parties  of  Greece,  Spain,  and Portugal  constitute  a  third  category.  Despite  their  recent  electoral  successes these  parties  differ  from  classical  or  labourist  social  democracy  on  account of  their  overall  constitution  and  historical  context.  They  exhibit  medium  or weak  cooperation  with  fragmented  unions;  working-class  tradition  is  weaker in  these  countries,  and  there  is  thus  lower  electoral  penetration  in  the  work¬ ing  class;  they  face  or  have  faced  strong  competition  from  the  left;  and  the political  system  in  which  they  operate  has  historically  less  developed  demo¬ cratic  institutions  and  a  less  extensive  welfare  state.11 Using  this  admittedly  partial  and  necessarily  somewhat  arbitrary  classi¬ fication,  it  can  nevertheless  be  seen  fairly  clearly  that  the  parties  of  the  first group  were  the  electoral  locomotive  of  European  socialism  after  the  Second World  War.  In  the  1950s  the  average  for  these  parties  was  42.2%  (if  we  ex¬ clude  the  German  SPD,  44.6%).  This  impressive  performance  makes  it  pos¬ sible  to  say  that  a  golden  age  of  social  democracy  definitely  existed.  How¬ ever,  it  only  involved  five  socialist  parties— the  Swedish  SAP,  the  Norwegian Labour  Party  (DNA),  the  Danish  SD,  the  British  Labour  Party,  and  the  Aus¬ trian  SPO12— and  did  not  last  much  beyond  the  1960s. Adverse  trends  became  evident  in  the  1970s  with  a  decline  in  the  group’s average  performance,  but  the  news  was  not  all  bad,  particularly  in  Germany and  Austria.  Two  subsequent  and  abrupt  regressions— the  first  in  the  1980s and  the  second  in  the  2000s  — nevertheless  signaled  the  effective  end  of  the propellant  power  of  this  group  of  five  parties. In  the  2000s  the  average  of  their  performance  stood  at  33.1%,  which  meant that  for  the  full  1950-2009  period  the  average  losses  amounted  to  9.1%.  The large  social  democratic  parties  had  lost  21.5%  of  their  previous  influence. Losses  of  this  magnitude  clearly  mattered,  and  they  were  rendered  more  sig¬ nificant  because  they  often  came  in  the  form  of  electoral  earthquakes— as  in Denmark  and  Norway  in  the  1970s,  Britain  in  the  1980s,  and  Denmark  and Norway  again  in  the  2000s.  Thus  the  old  electoral  locomotive  of  European socialism  went  into  a  dangerous  spiral.  The  electoral  retreat  appears  as  a slow,  steady  slide,  almost  without  interruption,  that  is  still  in  progress.  The electoral  golden  age  now  seems  far  removed.  The  years  since  2000  have  also inflicted  a  lot  of  damage.  In  the  period  2000-2009  none  of  the  parties  in  the first  group  received  more  than  an  average  of  38%  of  the  vote,  whereas  during 62  Moschonas the  1960s  none  of  them  averaged  less  than  39.1%.  Thus  the  best  average  results for  the  2000s  are  inferior  to  the  worst  results  for  the  1960s.  This  is  a  clear  indi¬ cation  of  electoral  “banalization”  of  this  distinguished  company  of  parties. The  fate  of  parties  with  intermediate  electoral  status  was  if  anything worse.  This  group  registered  even  greater  losses  than  the  group  of  most  clas¬ sically  social  democratic  parties.  Their  performance  dropped  8  percentage points,  hence  a  loss  of  26.1%  of  their  electoral  strength  during  the  1950s. The  LSAP  lost  34%  of  its  strength  since  the  1950s,  the  Belgian  PS  31.6%,  and the  PvdA  30.9%,  while  the  Dutch  compete  with  the  Norwegians  for  the  gold medal  for  electoral  instability  (cf.  Spyropoulou  2008,  53).  Losses  for  parties in  this  category  differ  from  those  of  the  first  group  in  one  important  respect: they  are  more  randomly  distributed  in  time  and  less  structured.13  It  is  there¬ fore  less  easy  to  locate  a  precise  turning  point  or  cause.  On  the  other  hand the  decline  is  cumulatively  stronger,  and  the  warning  signs  appeared  earlier for  the  social  democratic  parties  more  systematically  involved  in  consensus- oriented  decision  making.  These  “pragmatic  coalition-oriented  parties”  are suffering  more  than  other  parties  of  the  center-left. The  picture  of  declining  strength  of  social  democratic  parties  changes considerably  when  one  looks  to  the  south  (table  4).  The  southern  European parties,  which  turned  in  excellent  electoral  performances  during  the  1980s (with  the  exception  of  the  Portuguese  socialists),  consolidated  their  strong positions  and  improved  their  average  in  the  1990s  and  2000s.  The  improve¬ ment  was  above  all  due  to  the  strong  resurgence  of  the  Portuguese  PS,  which obtained  its  best  historical  result  (45.1%)  in  the  2005  elections  — the  best score  of  any  socialist  party  anywhere  in  Europe  for  2000-2009.  The  PSOE achieved  its  best  results  in  the  1980s  but  also  consolidated  its  position  in  the 2000s  after  a  significant  drop  in  the  1990s.  By  contrast,  PASOK,  although  per¬ forming  very  solidly  overall,  appears  to  have  entered  a  phase  of  soft  electoral decline  (see  Voulgaris  2008)  despite  its  triumphal  return  to  power  in  2009.14 The  southern  pole  is  by  far  the  strongest  in  European  socialism  today— a major  novelty  in  the  electoral  history  of  socialism. These  results  can  be  refined  still  further  by  looking  at  social  democratic parties  in  countries  with  different  kinds  of  welfare  states.  In  table  5  we  clas¬ sify  parties  based  on  whether  they  operate  in  states  with  social  democratic, Christian  democratic,  or  liberal  welfare  regimes  and  compare  their  perfor¬ mance  for  the  period  2000-2009  with  their  best  average  performance  in any  decade  since  the  1950s  (no  matter  which  decade  was  the  best).15  The  re¬ sults  are  stark  and  surprising:  parties  in  classic  “social  democratic”  welfare states  (relative  average  change  -26.7%)  and  those  in  Christian  democratic welfare  regimes  (-28.2%)  have  been  more  adversely  affected  than  those  in Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  63 Table  5.  Welfare  Regimes  and  Change  in  the  Social  Democratic  Vote,  Best  Decade  versus 2000-2009  (percentage  of  votes) Social  Democratic Liberal Christian  Democratic Austria -32.5 Australia -15.7 Belgium -31.6 Finland -9.6 New  Zealand -15.8 France -29.3 Denmark -33.3 United  Kingdom -17.9 Germany -27.8 Norway -35.2 Ireland -29.6 Sweden -22.6 Netherlands -31.6 Switzerland -19.2 Unweighted -26.7 Unweighted -16.5 Unweighted -28.2 average average average Note:  Classification  of  welfare  regime  types  according  to  Stephens,  Huber,  and  Ray  1999. liberal  regimes  (-16.5%).  Interestingly  enough,  in  the  list  of  big  losers  we  find some  of  the  most  prominent  and  most  recognizable  brands  of  European  social democracy:  the  Norwegian  DNA  (-35.2%),  the  Danish  SD  (-33.3%),  the  Aus¬ trian  SPO  (-32.5%),  the  Belgian  PS  (-31.6%),  the  Dutch  PvdA  (-31.6%). Much  the  same  picture  emerges  if  we  use  the  classification  offered  by Esping-Andersen  in  his  The  Three  Worlds  of  Welfare  Capitalism  (1990).  Thus figure  3  displays  the  electoral  influence  of  the  socialist  parties  in  two  extreme groups  of  countries:  the  so-called  high  decommodification  group,  which  in¬ cludes  the  classic  social  democratic  models  of  Sweden,  Norway,  and  Den¬ mark  as  well  as  the  “traditionalist-conservative”  welfare  states  such  as  the 25 1950-59 1960-69 1970-79 1 980-89 1990-99  2000-2009 Figure  3.  Welfare  regimes,  decommodification  status,  and  average  percentage  of  votes cast  for  social  democratic  parties  in  legislative  elections,  1950-2009. 64  Moschonas Netherlands,  Belgium,  and  Austria;  and  the  “low  decommodification”  group of  liberal  regimes,  including  the  United  Kingdom,  Ireland,  New  Zealand,  and Australia  (Esping-Andersen  1990,  52,  47-54).16  For  parties  belonging  to  the high  decommodification  group,  the  decline  is  extraordinary  (a  proportional change  of  -28.15%  compared  to  the  1950s),  while  for  parties  belonging  to  the low  decommodification  group  the  losses  are  much  less  serious  (-15.24%  in relative  terms).  Again  the  contrast  is  too  strong  not  to  matter. Parties  operating  in  liberal  environments  or  Labourist  parties  that  are more  market-friendly  appear  to  be  resisting  decline  better  than  those  in  so¬ cial  democratic  environments.17 Taken  together,  these  data  show  fairly  convincingly  that  the  parties  which have  fared  worse  electorally  are  those  at  the  very  center  of  the  social  demo¬ cratic  project.  The  implications  would  seem  to  be  serious  indeed. The  Myth  of  the  Landslide  of  the  Late  1990s:  A  New  Golden  Age? The  principal  unit  of  analysis  employed  here  — electoral  average  by  decade  — does  not  capture  short-term  fluctuations,  which  are  what  in  fact  determine  a party’s  transition  to  opposition  or  its  arrival  in  government.  In  addition,  it  ar¬ tificially  fractures  electoral  time,  because  political  dynamics  do  not  obey  the logic  of  rounded-up  figures.  Thus  according  to  our  data  the  1990s  represented yet  another  stage  in  the  sequence  of  the  electoral  erosion  of  social  democracy (see  table  1).  However,  toward  the  end  of  the  1990s  twelve  out  of  fifteen  gov¬ ernments  in  the  European  Union  were  either  single-party  social  democratic governments  or  coalition  governments  with  social  democratic  participation. The  “magical  return  of  social  democracy,”  as  it  has  been  called,  does  not  fea¬ ture  prominently  in  our  data  (Cuperus  and  Kandel  1998, 11).  It  was  quite  real, but  it  was  also  fleeting  and  modest  in  its  scope  and  consequences. The  data  in  table  6  describe  the  electoral  cycle  of  the  1990s.  They  show, first  of  all,  that  the  peak  of  social  democratic  influence  was  not  at  the  end  of the  1990s  but  toward  the  middle  of  the  decade.  In  this  period  social  demo¬ crats,  scoring  32.3%,  advanced  by  2  points  compared  with  the  previous  elec¬ tion,  an  undoubtedly  solid  achievement.  Ironically,  however,  at  the  moment (the  late  1990s)  when  the  governmental  power  of  social  democratic  parties was  “at  an  historic  peak”  (Merkel  2001,  35),  they  had  already  begun  their transition  to  electoral  regression  (31.1%  is  the  average  for  the  last  election  in the  1990s,  as  against  32.3%  for  the  penultimate  one).  To  a  certain  extent  this explains  the  short-lived  character  of  their  governmental  domination.  Already on  a  downward  electoral  slope  at  the  end  of  the  decade,  they  saw  things  get worse:  socialists  only  obtained  29.6%  in  the  first  election  in  the  2000s  (-1.5% Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  65 Table  6.  Electoral  Performance  of  the  Socialist  Parties  in  Electoral  Cycle  of  the  1990s (Percentage  of  Votes) Ante¬ penultimate election  of 1990s Penultimate election  of 1990s Last election of  1990s First election of  2000s Unweighted  average  (without Spain,  Portugal,  Greece) 29.0 29.7 28.9 27.5 Total  unweighted  average (all  16  countries) 30.3 32.3 31.1 29.6 *  For  countries  with  only  two  elections  in  the  1990s,  average  of  antepenultimate  election  is  calcu¬ lated  by  taking  into  account  the  last  election  of  the  1980s. compared  with  the  late  1990s  and  -2.7%  compared  with  the  mid-1990s).  The decline  being  rapid  and  marked,  the  new  century  very  soon  put  an  end  to  the socialist  majority  in  the  European  Council. Not  only  was  the  revival  brief,  it  was  also  modest.  If  one  excludes  the southern  parties  from  the  calculations,  the  image  of  electoral  progress  is  con¬ siderably  attenuated.  The  peak  achieved  toward  the  middle  of  the  decade (29.7%  for  the  thirteen  countries)  was  in  fact  below  the  average  social  demo¬ cratic  score— not  the  peak— for  the  1980s  (31.1%),  well  below  the  score  for the  1970s  (31.7%),  not  to  mention  the  scores  for  the  1950s  and  1960s  (33.2%; see  table  1).  Thus  there  was  nothing  extraordinary  about  the  electoral  rise of  the  period,  which  did  not  exceed  the  habitual  electoral  ceiling  of  perfor¬ mances  in  this  era. Third,  the  governmental  swing  in  Europe  was  the  result  of  mixed  tenden¬ cies  at  a  national  level.  Significantly,  nine  of  the  sixteen  parties  considered here  were  in  electoral  decline  by  the  last  election  of  the  1990s,  while  only seven  were  in  ascent.  The  electoral  trend  was  not  general,  which  explains how  socialists  dominated  governments  in  Europe  on  the  basis  of  an  electoral advance  that  was  limited  in  aggregate  terms  but  remarkable  at  the  level  of certain  national  political  systems.  The  modest  impetus  that  imparted  power (when  one  thinks  in  European  terms)  often  concealed  landslides  at  a  national level. On  balance,  the  widespread  view  of  commentators  at  the  time  that  Europe was  experiencing  a  kind  of  social  democratic  “resurrection”  is  not  confirmed by  the  data.  What  made  this  image  plausible  was  the  roughly  simultaneous coming  to  power  of  center-left  parties  in  France,  Britain,  and  Germany.  The image  of  an  electoral  “renaissance”  of  social  democracy  was  fashioned  after these  victories.  Given  the  demographic,  geopolitical,  and  in  part  intellectual 66  Moschonas -• —  Best  electoral  results •  -  -  Worst  electoral  results Figure  4.  Average  percentage  of  votes  cast  for  social  democratic  parties  in  five  best  and five  worst  elections  for  parties  in  each  decade,  1950-2009  (Greece,  Portugal,  and  Spain excluded). influence  of  the  three  countries  concerned,  it  was  politically  legitimate.  But it  was  electorally  exaggerated.  Social  democracy  (with  Greece,  Spain,  and Portugal  excepted)  dominated  governments  in  Europe  on  the  basis  of  crisis figures.  In  retrospect  we  know  that  these  figures  (concerning  the  thirteen parties  of  our  analysis)  were  by  far  the  best  for  the  whole  period  extending from  1990  to  2009.  But  they  were  inferior  to  previous  ones.  Such  perfor¬ mances  do  not  call  into  question  the  cycle  of  erosion. A  rather  more  accurate  understanding  of  the  modest  gains  of  the  1990s can  perhaps  be  gained  by  looking  at  the  best  and  worst  performances  by social  democratic  parties  over  the  longer  period,  1950-2009.  Figure  4  shows the  average  of  the  five  best  and  five  worst  results  for  center-left  parties  for each  decade.  The  decline  is  very  clear.  What  is  equally  clear  is  that  the  best showings  of  the  1990s,  which  led  to  social  democrats  coming  to  office,  did not  come  close  to  matching  the  achievements  of  earlier  periods.  Nor  did  they reverse  the  long-term  trend. Put  another  way,  the  truly  extraordinary  electoral  achievements  of  the 1950s  and  1960s  now  seem  to  be  out  of  social  democratic  reach.  Since  the 1980s  social  democracy  has  achieved  successively  smaller  victories  than  in the  previous  decades.  From  this  perspective  the  results  of  the  late  1990s  were electorally  rather  ordinary.  Social  democracy  as  a  political  phenomenon  has become  smaller,  its  “carrying  electoral  capacity”  correspondingly  weaker. It  was  this  smaller  social  democracy,  semi-strong  and  semi-exhausted,  that Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  67 found  itself  temporarily  in  power  at  the  end  of  the  1990s.  In  a  sense  the  return to  power  was  genuinely  “magical.” What  Kind  of  Crisis? The  electoral  retreat  of  social  democracy  transcends  spatial  boundaries  and national  borders  within  Europe;  it  even  transcends  “oceanic  frontiers”  (cf. Horn  2007,  190).  It  is  a  complex,  multilayered  process,  and  several  causes act  together  to  produce  it.  On  this  very  fluid  terrain,  where  a  whole  host  of parameters  is  in  play  and  where  the  share  of  hypothesis  and  deduction  is large,  we  won’t  venture  to  propose  a  “general  theory”  of  social  democratic electoral  dynamics.  Accordingly,  this  discussion  will  attempt  an  answer  to three  questions:  How  are  we  to  explain  the  divergent  electoral  dynamics  in northern  and  southern  Europe?  Is  the  social  democratic  electoral  decline inexorable  or  irreversible?  And  how  serious  is  the  electoral  crisis  of  social democracy,  and  how  temporary  or  enduring  could  it  be?  The  discussion  aims to  outline  a  general  framework  of  influences;  it  will  offer  nothing  more  than some  reference  points,  “some  indices  of  weighting.” Understanding  the  Winners The  excellent  performances  of  the  Spanish,  Portuguese,  and  Greek  parties represent  the  major  exception  to  the  long-term  process  of  social  democratic decline.  Their  successes,  moreover,  have  lasted  nearly  as  long  as  the  down¬ ward  slope  of  the  other  socialist  parties.  During  the  period  of  initial  success (in  the  1980s)  it  was  reasonable  to  argue  that  there  was  a  two-speed  or  two- track  electoral  pattern  in  operation  — the  old  “mature”  Nordic  parties  versus the  “new,”  expanding,  but  not  yet  consolidated  parties  in  the  south— which might  be  merely  temporary.  Today  this  makes  less  sense,  for  the  southern “latecomers”  have  experienced  not  only  the  initial  upturn  of  the  1980s  but also  serious  setbacks  and  proud  recoveries.  There  is  clearly  more  at  work  here than  a  matter  of  “catching  up”  or  “maturation.” PASOK  and  PSOE  are  by  far  the  most  successful  group  of  parties  in  the European  socialist  and  social  democratic  family.18  The  puzzle  of  their  suc¬ cess  is  all  the  more  intriguing  for  three  reasons.  In  the  first  place,  these  two parties  have  followed  rather  different  political  and  economic  itineraries.  Sec¬ ond,  they  have  failed  to  honor  numerous  electoral  promises.  Finally,  their economic  records  have  generally  not  been  brilliant  (examples:  the  Spanish socialists’  disappointing  jobs  record  or  the  shipwreck  of  Greek  Keynesianism during  the  1980s).  An  extensive  discussion  of  their  accomplishments  is  not 68  Moschonas possible  here,  but  one  obvious  historical  comparison  stands  out:  these  two parties  managed  to  create,  in  much  the  same  fashion  as  the  Swedish  SAP  in the  1930s  and  the  Austrian  SPO  in  the  early  1970s,  a  new  mainstream  that  was ultimately  accepted  and  broadly  legitimated  by  all  political  forces.  They  ex¬ ercised  prolonged  ideological  and  political  domination,  though  shorter  than in  Scandinavia. A  further  and  related  factor  contributed  to  the  initial  success  (at  the  end  of the  1970s  and  during  the  1980s)  of  both  PASOK  and  PSOE:  the  lack  of  credi¬ bility  of  the  principal  right-wing  parties,  a  deficit  linked  to  the  black  pages of  history  of  both  countries  (party  system  factor).  Nonetheless,  a  favorable ideological  framework  does  not  lead  to  a  long-lasting  electoral  dominance. In  effect,  above  and  beyond  the  initial  ideological  weakness  of  the  right, three  policy  factors  explain  the  electoral  dominance  of  PASOK  (1981-2004) and  PSOE  (1982-96  and  from  2004  to  the  present):  first,  the  implementa¬ tion  of  more  advanced  social  policies  than  those  of  right-wing  or  centrist parties  (socialist  policies  on  health,  pensions,  social  benefits,  education,  and reducing  regional  inequalities  largely  explain  the  two  parties’  initial  momen¬ tum  and  the  persistence,  especially  in  the  case  of  PSOE,  of  their  electoral success);  second,  the  institutional  modernization  undertaken  by  the  socialist governments  (a  key  dimension  of  which  was  the  deepening  of  democratiza¬ tion);  third,  measures  of  cultural  modernization  (the  implementation  of  “pro¬ gressive”  reforms  affecting  private  life  and  relations  in  civil  society). Overall  the  socialists  proved  capable  of  clearly  dominating  their  center- right  opponents  in  these  three  areas  (social  policy  and  the  welfare  state, political  liberalism,  and  cultural  liberalism),  and  it  was  these  reforms  that were  supported  by  a  majority  of  public  opinion  throughout  the  socialist reign  (Moschonas  and  Papanagnou,  2007,  75-81).  By  contrast,  their  advan¬ tages  in  economic  modernization  and  European  policy  (joining  the  EEC) were  either  less  strong  (PSOE)  or,  in  an  initial  phase,  nonexistent  (PASOK from  1981  to  1985).  In  this  regard  the  adoption  of  a  European  perspective and  the  neoliberalization  of  their  economic  policy  are  in  themselves  insuf¬ ficient  to  explain  the  two  parties’  electoral  domination  even  though  within the  European  social  democratic  family  PSOE  found  itself  in  the  vanguard  of economic  liberalism  and  Europeanization.  Now,  socialist  ascendancy  in  the areas  of  social  policy,  institutional  modernization,  and  cultural  moderniza¬ tion  was  combined  with  an  advantage  of  physiognomy  in  the  sense  that  this triple  domination  was  profoundly  in  tune  with  significant  distinguishing  fea¬ tures  of  PASOK’s  and  PSOE’s  initial  ideological  and  programmatic  profiles. In  terms  of  identity,  these  thematic  areas  constituted  — after  the  abandoning of  the  “radical  scenario”  — the  main  reference  points  of  southern  specificity Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  69 in  the  social  democratic  family.  Over  the  long  term  the  two  parties  — in  spite of  severe  contradictions,  broken  promises,  ideological  treasons,  and  corrup¬ tion  — took  a  lead  over  their  opponents  on  all  these  fronts.  This  created  a  com¬ posite  political  cycle  in  which  the  economy  was  an  important  but  not  neces¬ sarily  or  always  a  determinant  aspect  (Moschonas  and  Papanagnou  2007). All  this  underlines  the  reality  that  electoral  ascendancy  and  decline  are not  produced  simply  by  sociological  trends  nor  by  deft  political  management of  electoral  clienteles  but  are  more  a  matter  of  having  a  credible  political project,  symbolic  framework,  and  set  of  political  opportunities.  The  southern case  therefore  demonstrates  that  ideas  and  policies  as  well  as  strong  leader¬ ship  count;  that  political  and  ideological  factors  are  critical  in  establishing class  alignments  and  obtaining  good  electoral  results.  Sweden  in  the  1930s, 1950s,  and  1960s  (because  of  the  remarkable  Swedish  model)  and  Austria  in the  1970s  (because  of  the  Austro-Keynesian  stance)  undoubtedly  reinforce this  thesis.  So  too  does  the  more  controversial  British  case  in  the  1990s  and early  2000s. Britain  is  especially  instructive.  The  “Third  Way”  project,  an  aggressive strategy  that  aimed  to  liberate  Labourism  once  and  for  all  from  the  image of  a  “tax-and-spend”  party,  acquired  a  central  place  in  British  politics.  The adoption  of  an  inventive  version  of  economic  liberalism— with  an  empha¬ sis  on  “supply-side”  interventions  in  education  and  training,  a  “huge  invest¬ ment”  in  public  services,  many  measures  taken  to  raise  the  income  of  the poorest— along  with  constitutional  reforms  and  more  generally  a  proven  ca¬ pacity  to  dominate  the  political  agenda,  were  essential  in  producing  repeated favorable  electoral  results  (Seldon  2007,  646;  Stewart  2007,  432;  Shaw  2007, 201-3;  Cronin  in  this  volume).  Labour’s  neoliberal  macroeconomic  manage¬ ment,  complemented  by  an  innovative  and  bold  set  of  social  policies  (not always  social  democratic  in  the  traditional  sense  of  the  term),  appears  to have  generated  a  new  policy  mainstream  in  the  British  political  system.  It is  highly  significant  that  even  David  Cameron,  the  leader  of  the  Conserva¬ tive  Party,  has  come  to  embrace  much  of  the  Labour’s  public  service  reform agenda  (Seldon  2007,  650). Undoubtedly  New  Labour  “killed”  the  old  collectivist  Labourist  spirit  and outlook  (Cronin  2006,  53,  63).  It  also  may  have  encouraged  “the  nation’s values  to  move  in  a  more  conservative  direction”  and  at  least  indirectly undermined  its  capacity  “to  achieve  electoral  success  over  the  long  term” (Curtice  2007,  52).  Under  Blair  overall  income  inequality  remained  “fairly static”  (Stewart  2007,  432-35).  However,  the  most  striking  electoral  fact  of the  period  1997-2005  is  the  Labour  Party’s  very  good  performance  among the  non-manual  labor  categories  of  the  population.  This  improvement,  much 70  Moschonas stronger  than  that  of  other  social  democratic  parties,  is  largely  explained  by Tony  Blair’s  modernization  strategy  (Moschonas  2008b).  New  Labour’s  ag¬ gressive  adoption  of  new  policies  and  ideas  (in  other  countries  the  set  of  new policies  and  ideas  was  more  defensive)  enabled  British  social  democrats  to penetrate  part  of  the  Conservatives’  natural  social  base.  Despite  its  obvious lack  of  a  central  “ethical  motivational  core,”  its  neoliberal  macroeconomic options,  and  its  extremely  catch-all  discourse,  New  Labour  chalked  up  an  im¬ portant  number  of  thematic  victories  that  elicited  public  approval  and  served to  shape  voting.  This  ideologically  “eclectic”  party  (Shaw  2007, 186)  thus  be¬ came  the  driving  force  of  a  significant  political  change.  The  British  case  dem¬ onstrates  that  political  factors  are  important  in  establishing  new  electoral (and  class)  alignments  even  though  after  twelve  years  in  power  Labour  was ultimately  defeated  in  the  elections  of  2010.  Obviously  the  wearing  effect  of being  in  power  for  a  long  period  seems  today  to  exact  a  high  electoral  price— in  all  probability  higher  than  in  the  past.  It  also  seems  to  involve  a  kind  of programmatic  exhaustion.  In  a  case  like  this,  the  theme  of  “change”  — a  cen¬ tral  one  in  the  strategy  of  the  British  conservatives  (“it’s  time  for  change”)  — emerges  as  a  “super  issue”  and  probably  a  decisive  one. The  current  situation  in  Scandinavian  countries  tends  to  confirm  the  thesis that  ideas  and  policies  count:  “if  the  Swedish  party  dropped  the  ‘big  idea’ early,  it  has  had  over  the  years  a  number  of ‘big  issues’  around  which  to  mo¬ bilize  a  wider  base  of  support.  .  .  .  Today,  however,  the  Scandinavian,  and  in particular  the  Swedish  Social  Democrats’  policy  agendas,  appear  bereft  of  big issues”  (Arter  2003,  97).  Put  slightly  differently,  if  ideas  and  big  issues  count, their  lack  counts  too.  The  weakening  performance  of  the  SAP  — a  party  that is  nevertheless  in  a  much  better  electoral  position  than  its  counterparts  in Denmark  and  Norway  — is  powerfully  consistent  with  the  analysis  developed here:  in  2006  the  Swedes  suffered  “their  worst  score  in  a  parliamentary  elec¬ tion  since  1920  — that  is,  since  the  advent  of  fully  democratic  politics”  (Aylott and  Bolin  2007,  621).  The  recent  difficulties  of  the  Swedish  SAP,  whose  party story  still  ranks  as  one  of  the  best  of  all  times,  seem  to  be  intimately  con¬ nected  to  a  crisis  of  “policy  horizons.” Certainly  Sweden  is  still  a  social  democratic  nation,  and  the  social  demo¬ cratic  legacy  is  not  really  affected  by  the  electoral  retreat  of  the  SAP,  which although  weakened  remains  a  powerful  electoral  (and  programmatic)  ma¬ chine.  Scandinavian  social  democrats,  compared  to  the  Spanish,  Greek,  and Portuguese  socialists  or  the  British  Labourists,  are  not  less  effective  in  achiev¬ ing  the  traditional  leftist  goals  of  full  employment  and  social  justice;  quite  the contrary.  Scandinavian  social  democrats  remain  by  far  the  best  “social  brand” in  the  world.  Scandinavia’s  social  experiment  still  represents  a  unique  mix  of Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  71 universal  ideals  and  efficient  policies  (see  Pontusson  2005;  Pontusson  in  this volume).  But  after  racking  up  ideological  and  policy  successes  for  more  than five  decades,  Scandinavian  social  democracy  has  entered  a  new  phase.  It  now has  great  trouble  repeating  its  previous  achievements  (and  electoral  results). It  has  lost  the  way,  its  own  unique  way,  to  connect  with  its  constituencies’ soul.  In  effect  Scandinavian  social  democrats,  confronted  with  a  modernized and  “social”  right  in  their  own  countries,  failed  to  sufficiently  renew  their policy  agenda  and  rearticulate— in  a  hegemonic  manner— their  own  histori¬ cal  legacy.  Thus  they  became  less  effective  in  dominating  their  right-wing opponents. To  sum  up,  the  core  of  our  argument  is  not  that  southern  socialism  has  the mastery  of  ideas  and  policy  renewal  within  European  social  democracy.  The Scandinavians,  British,  French,  and  partly  the  Germans  continue  to  be  the programmatic  avant-gardes  within  the  European  social  democratic  family. For  example,  PASOK’s  triumphal  return  to  power  in  October  2009  was  based on,  among  other  things,  the  promise  that  Greece  will  become  the  “Denmark of  southern  Europe.”  This  promise  says  a  great  deal  about  the  influence  of the  Scandinavian  model.  Northern  and  central  Europe’s  social  democracy  re¬ mains  ideologically  pivotal  and  its  programmatic  and  policy  centrality,  de¬ spite  its  decreasing  electoral  influence,  is  as  pronounced  as  ever  within  the center-left  family. Hence  our  argument— and  hypothesis— is  that  programmatic  and  policy novelty  currently  find  a  more  favorable  political  and  social  terrain  in  non¬ social  democratic  societies  (southern  Europe)  or  liberal  societies  (Great  Brit¬ ain,  etc.)  rather  than  in  classically  social  democratic  ones  (Scandinavia).  In the  latter  countries  social  democracy’s  “ability  to  differ”  is  smaller,  partly  be¬ cause  of  its  previous  successes.  By  contrast,  in  countries  with  less  developed welfare  states,  less  modern  institutional  structures,  or  both,  we  are  witness¬ ing  a  structure  of  opportunities  more  favorable  to  a  left-wing  agenda.  In  con¬ sequence,  our  argument  is  not  “ideational.”  If  ideas  count,  ideas  and  imagi¬ nation  are  not  constraint-free  or  circumstance-free. From  this  point  of  view,  while  the  ideological  and  policy  center  of  so¬ cial  democracy  remains  largely  in  central  and  northern  Europe,  Southern socialist  parties  seem  to  be  in  a  better  position  to  prevail  ideologically  over right-wing  parties.  Among  the  factors  contributing  to  their  good  electoral  re¬ sults,  modernization  (frequently  under  the  form  of  Europeanization)  ranks high  (Moschonas  2002).  The  goal  of  modernization  entails  solving  a  series of  puzzles  that  are  specific  to  these  countries  and  enhance  the  innovative and  problem-solving  part  of  social  democratic  action.  Obviously  this  is  less the  case  in  northern  and  central  Europe,  although  investment  of  the  terms 72  Moschonas “modernity”  and  “modernization”  by  social  democrats  is  not  a  new  phenome¬ non  (examples:  the  SPD’s  promise  in  1969  to  create  a  “modern  Germany”  and the  project  of  Harold  Wilson’s  Labour  Party  of  modernizing  the  British  econ¬ omy).  In  short,  liberal  and  non-social  democratic  environments  create  and recreate  a  living  space  for  social  democratic  and  left-wing  forces.  They  make the  occurrence  of  programmatic  and  policy  ascendancy  a  little  easier  for  the left.  The  latest  Spanish  (2007)  and  Greek  (2009)  elections  brought  this  reality into  sharp  focus. In  more  general  terms,  the  problem  with  the  current  ideological  and  pro¬ grammatic  profile  of  classical  social  democracy  is  that  it  does  not  project  a genuine  “reformist  imaginary.”  Contemporary  social  democracy  is  bereft  of big  political— and  policy— ideas  in  its  electoral  arsenal,  ideas  capable  of  cap¬ turing  intense  public  attention  and  structuring  the  vote.  The  whole  history  of social  democracy,  from  the  Erfurt  Programme  to  the  Stockholm  School  and Austro-Keynesianism,  demonstrates  that  social  democratic  parties  have  suc¬ ceeded  in  establishing  themselves  as  majority  forces  when  they  have  taken an  ideological  lead  over  their  right-wing  opponents  by  embracing  program¬ matic  ideas  and  implementing  policies  which  the  latter  were  not  yet  ready to  accept  or  implement  — like  universal  suffrage  and  political  rights  for  the working  class,  inventive  policies  against  unemployment,  the  welfare  state and  Keynesianism,  or  an  institutionalized  role  for  trade  unions.  Parties  are sites  of  policy-oriented  ideas.  Only  if  parties  differ  can  they  endure  and  domi¬ nate  their  opponents.  It  is  thus  hard  to  see  how  social  democratic  parties  can remain  highly  competitive  if  for  more  than  thirty  years  they  remain  unable to  generate  an  image  of  genuine  ideological  originality.  And  their  deep  com¬ mitment  to  “a  new  round  of  catch-all  policies”  (Allen  2009,  641)  has  not  made things  easier. In  conclusion,  though  it  is  impossible  to  quantify  and  therefore  difficult to  prove  definitively,  the  thematic  victories  won  by  southern  socialists  (and by  New  Labour)  and  the  current  “thematic”  or  “agenda”  crisis  of  “old”  social democratic  parties  would  seem  to  go  a  long  way  toward  explaining  the  con¬ trasting  electoral  dynamics  in  both  the  South  and  the  North. Inexorable  Decline?  The  Class  Factor  and  the  Ideological  Retreat The  question  of  thematic  victories  and  defeats  leads  us  to  the  question  of  the nature  of  the  electoral  crisis  that  social  democracy  experiences.  Is  the  decline “inexorable”  or  “historical,”  reflected  as  it  seems  to  be  in  a  shrinking  of  its core  working-class  clientele  and  a  decreasing  propensity  of  workers  to  vote for  the  left,  phenomena  described  by  Hobsbawm  (1981)  and  Adam  Przewor- Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  73 ski  and  John  Sprague  (1986)  more  than  two  decades  ago?  Undoubtedly  the retreat  is  in  part  a  “class  affair”  and  a  result  of  the  shifting  contours  of  class. But  is  it  not  also  a  product  of  a  political  and  ideological  transformation? The  point  of  departure  for  the  penetrating— and  elegantly  formulated  — argument  of  Przeworski  and  Sprague  is  the  minority  status  of  the  working class  stricto  sensu.  Given  this  inescapable  social  reality,  it  is  argued,  socialist parties  are  condemned  to  minority  electoral  status  when  they  pursue  “pure” class  strategies,  but  they  also  lose  votes  among  the  working  class  when  they follow  cross-class  strategies.  Confronted  with  this  dilemma  (i.e.,  a  persistent trade-off  between  working-class  and  middle-class  votes),  social  democrats have  been  “unable  to  win  either  way,”  and  the  situation  only  worsens  with time  (Przeworski  and  Sprague  1986;  Przeworski  1985, 102-36). This  view  has  been  widely— and  in  part  rightly— criticized  on  method¬ ological  and  empirical  grounds  (Sainsbury  1990;  King  and  Wickham-Jones 1990;  Merkel  1992b).  Certainly  much  has  changed  since  these  arguments were  first  made.  Nevertheless  the  curve  of  recent  electoral  developments, notably  what  we  could  identify  as  the  second  wave  of  electoral  results  (1990s and  2000s),  shows  that  the  paths  of  social  democratic  retreat  closely  re¬ semble  Przeworkski’s  and  Sprague’s  scenario  of  “irreversible”  decline. First,  the  development  of  social  democracy’s  electoral  performances  in the  long  run  possesses  all  the  characteristics  of  a  decline  that  is  difficult  to arrest.  Second,  sociological  data  for  the  full  period  of  1967-2007  show  that social  democracy’s  positions  within  the  working  class  have  been  gradually but  considerably  weakened  since  the  1970s.  At  the  same  time,  social  demo¬ cratic  parties  that  have  in  recent  years  pursued  the  most  strongly  cross-class strategies  have  resisted  decline  much  better  and  even  made  progress  among the  middle  classes  (Moschonas  2002  and  2008b).  Third,  the  class  structure  of social  democracy  has  changed  in  such  a  way  that  two  social  poles  of  almost equal  arithmetical  importance  now  coexist  within  social  democratic  elector¬ ates:  the  working  class  and  the  middle  strata  (Moschonas  2002;  cf.  Merkel 1992b,  27).  On  balance,  and  despite  the  many  criticisms  of  the  thesis  pre¬ sented  by  Przeworski  and  Sprague  in  Paper  Stones  (1986),  it  would  appear that  the  dilemmas  and  trade-offs  discussed  nearly  a  quarter-century  ago  are real  enough.  And  despite  the  changing  terms  of  the  trade-off  (because  of  the gradual  consolidation  of  new  dividing  lines,  such  as  the  cultural  one,  or  the new  polarization  between  winners  and  losers  of  European  integration  and globalization),  the  hard  core  of  the  argument  (not  some  follies  of  the  statisti¬ cal  calculations)  seems  to  me  solid. Without  offering  a  full  account  of  the  issue,  let  us  however  notice  some stubborn  facts  which  seem  to  contradict,  or  at  least  qualify,  this  line  of  argu- 74  Moschonas ment.  First,  the  electoral  trade-off  between  working-class  and  middle-class votes  did  not  take  place  (as  far  as  classical  social  democratic  parties  are  con¬ cerned)  in  the  1950s  and  1960s,  when  social  democracy  was  at  its  ideological best,  but  later.  It  was  really  only  with  the  breakdown  of  the  Keynesian  para¬ digm  that  social  democracy’s  positions  were  weakened,  both  electorally  and in  the  working-class  milieu.  Furthermore,  the  available  evidence  indicates that  disaffection  with  social  democratic  parties  tends  to  accelerate  after  a governmental  failure  of  the  left,  especially  in  social  policy.  Bad  results  in government  precipitate  and  structure  working-class  defection  (Cautres  and Heath  1996,  566-68;  also  Kitschelt  1999,  324,  3443- Second,  the  “new”  economic  policies  adopted  by  social  democratic  gov¬ ernments  since  the  mid-1980s  have  for  the  most  part  not  lacked  coherence, technocratic  effectiveness,  inventiveness,  or  social  compassion.  However, all  poll  research  indicates  that  they  did  not  produce  positive  electoral  and identity  effects  equivalent  to  those  of  the  Keynesian  era.  Thus  the  politico- economic  originality  of  the  social  democratic  alternative— or,  to  put  it  better, the  understanding  by  voters  of  its  originality  and  virtues  —  has  been  impaired. It  would  seem  that  the  decline  in  the  politics  of  growth  makes  it  impossible to  interpret  social  democracy  “as  quite  dramatic  evidence  of  the  politics  of solidarity”  (Hibbs  1993,  66).  This  evolution,  together  with  the  collapse  of communism,  constituted  a  major  turning  point.  It  created  what  Laclau  (2005, 138)  has  labeled  a  “drastic  rearticulation  of  the  political  imaginary,”  which has  been  accompanied  by  the  tendency  to  class  dealignment  since  the  1970s and  1980s. These  factors  would  support  either  an  analysis  that  favors  political  (and policy)  explanations  of  the  electoral  decline  over  more  narrowly  sociological explanations  or  one  that  insists  on  the  impossibility  of  effective  political  man¬ agement  of  complex  sociological  dynamics  (Przeworski’s  and  Sprague’s  view). If  so,  the  trade-off  between  working-class  and  middle-class  votes  should  be seen  primarily  as  part  of  the  wider  process  of  political  and  ideological  retreat brought  about  by  the  end  of  the  so-called  social  democratic  consensus.  In  fact the  economic  setting  for  left-wing  political  ideas  changed  dramatically  after the  1970s  and  1980s.  The  new  economic  policies  of  social  democratic  parties, together  with,  to  paraphrase  George  Ross  (1987,  32),  the  sudden  absence  of plausible  ideological  ways  of  being  a  social  democrat,  generated  a  break  in social  democratic  identity.  In  this  broader  context  the  working-class  defec¬ tion  was  less  the  inevitable  effect  of  an  inescapable  electoral  dilemma  than an  effect  of  the  end  of  the  postwar  economic  and  ideological  cycle.  It  was  pre¬ cisely  the  inability  of  social  democrats,  with  or  without  their  enduring  “elec¬ toral  dilemma,”  to  reestablish  the  conditions  for  more  egalitarian  policies Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  75 that  generated  (and  later  amplified)  the  defection  of  the  working-class  elec¬ torate  (Lavelle  2008).  It  was  also  this  failure  that  favored,  albeit  indirectly, the  consolidation  of  a  cultural  vote  and  to  some  extent  amplified  the  electoral trade-off  between  working-class  and  middle-class  votes.  In  consequence,  the electoral  trade-off  became  important  within  the  new  horizon  of  the  political and  ideological  evolution  of  left  politics.  In  the  absence  of  a  credible  social democratic  project  for  the  future,  ideological  dynamics  and  class  dynamics converged  and  created  the  electoral  crisis. Let  us  return  for  a  moment  to  the  “winners”— the  winners  of  the  1990s  and 2000s,  but  also  those  of  previous  decades.  The  Swedish  party  in  the  1930s, the  social  democrats  as  a  family  in  the  first  postwar  period,  the  Austrian party  in  the  1970s,  the  French  PS  in  the  1970s  and  1980s,  the  southern  parties since  the  1980s— all  demonstrated  that  political  action  and  policy-oriented ideas  count.  These  were  instances  of  successful  “hegemonic”  political  strate¬ gies,  and  in  pursuing  these  strategies  electoral  trade-offs  were  not  crucial  for determining  electoral  outcomes.  However  much  Przeworski’s  and  Sprague’s arguments  are  tempting,  however  well  they  highlight  the  real  trade-off  be¬ tween  worker  and  nonworker  votes,  “they  deny,”  as  Merkel  perceptively notes,  “the  possibility  to  pursue  the  interests  of  different  classes  in  a  single synthetic  political  strategy”  (Merkel  1992b,  17;  see  also  Sainsbury  1990,  48). In  reality  the  “dilemma  of  electoral  socialism”  denies  the  best  moments  of social  democratic  history.  But  it  describes  much  better  the  current  situation. The  current  problem  of  the  socialist  leaderships  is  thus  not  so  much  one of  tactics  concerning  electoral  target  groups  (middle  classes  or  lower  classes) nor  one  of  political  strategy,  be  it  classical  (positioning  oneself  more  to  the left  or  more  to  the  right)  or  less  classical  (positioning  oneself  along  the  left- libertarian  versus  right-authoritarian  political  dimension).  It  is  rather,  and most  importantly,  a  basic  ideological  and  programmatic  problem:  How  is the  ideological  and  programmatic  ascendancy  of  social  democracy  to  be  re¬ stored?  To  define  the  problem  this  way  is  not  to  deny  the  importance  of  the question  of  strategic  options  — market-liberalizing  centrist,  left-libertarian, ora  mixture  of  both  — or  social  and  cultural  divides  (Kitschelt  1994;  Kitschelt 1999).  It  is  to  suggest,  however,  that  national  strategic  options  and  there¬ fore  electoral  performances  are  subordinate  to  a  broader  balance  of  ideo¬ logical  forces.  From  this  point  of  view  the  end  of  the  “old”  ideological  and programmatic  ascendancy  explains  why  approaches  emphasizing  strategic dilemmas  and  agency,  no  matter  how  valid  they  are,  cannot  sufficiently  ac¬ count  for  the  major  fact  that  in  the  last  decades,  in  all  kinds  of  possible  trade¬ offs  and  strategic  scenarios,  social  democracy  experienced  an  unprecedented electoral  downturn.19  In  essence  the  data  and  analysis  presented  here  both 76  Moschonas point  to  a  tendance  lourde  that  transcends  national  strategic  subtleties:  what¬ ever  the  strategic  posture  adopted,  whatever  the  social  democratic  response to  its  “strategic  dilemmas”  (Kitschelt,  1999,  321-44),  social  democracy  has proved  incapable  of  making  up  the  electoral  ground  it  lost  in  the  1970s  and 1980s.  National  strategic  options  and  different  configurations  of  competition are  especially  salient  for  any  detailed  understanding  of  national  or  short-term electoral  tendencies  (see  Kitschelt  and  Rehm  2005;  Kitschelt  1999),  but  they do  not  account  for  the  general  downward  electoral  trend. To  summarize,  if  past  social  democratic  electoral  dominance  was  the  re¬ sult  of  powerful  historical  forces  that  brought  about  the  rise  and  consolida¬ tion  of  social  democratic  ideas,  another  powerful  movement  has  led  to  the rise  of  neoliberal  ideas  and  so  has  reversed  the  earlier  pattern.  The  new  social democratic  ideological  and  programmatic  stance  — formulated  in  the  second half  of  the  1990s  around  the  ideas  of  the  “Third  Way”— lacks  the  “stature and  the  coherence”  of  previous  social  democratic  projects  (cf.  Bonoli  2004, 197).  Social  democrats  are  no  longer  one  step  ahead  of  the  right-wing  parties on  issues  such  as  social  policy,  welfare,  economic  efficiency,  or  moderniza¬ tion,  and  they  are  losing  votes.  They  are,  it  can  be  argued,  one  step  ahead  in the  domain  of  cultural  liberalism  or  cultural  libertarian  orientation,  and  they are  accordingly  gaining  votes  among  the  educated  middle  strata.  As  Arthur Schlesinger  put  it  (1986,  276),  “politics  in  the  end  is  the  art  of  solving  substan¬ tive  problems.” All  this  does  not  attenuate  the  depth  of  the  current  social  democratic  elec¬ toral  decline;  rather  the  contrary.  But  in  ideological  and  programmatic  mat¬ ters,  there  is  nothing  “inexorable.”  A  hegemonic  relation  can  always,  sooner or  later,  be  overturned  or  reversed.  If  so,  nothing  can  prove  that  possibili¬ ties  for  a  new  cycle  of  social  democratic  ideological  domination  have  been permanently  lost.  The  thesis  that  the  current  electoral  decline  is  “historical” (or  “inexorable”)  is  rather  difficult  to  sustain.  Electoral  prospects  remain  an open-ended  battlefield,  even  if  the  terrain  and  the  advantage  have  shifted. Relativizing  Recovery  Prospects,  Relativizing  Crisis So  how  serious  is  the  electoral  crisis  of  social  democracy?  And  how  tempo¬ rary  or  enduring  might  it  be?  The  answer  is  that  there  is  no  easy  recovery, no  easy  and  rapid  exit.  The  medium-term  prospects  for  social  democrats look  bleak.  They  look  bleak  first  of  all  because  of  the  “rationale  of  numbers,” which  are  clear.  The  tendency  is  neither  circular  nor  one  of  trendless  fluctua¬ tion.  The  electoral  erosion  is  present  in  all  but  the  three  southern  countries in  Europe;  it  is  similar  everywhere  and  without  any  reversions  to  the  status Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  77 quo  ante.  The  scope,  the  phases,  the  highs  and  lows  may  differ,  but  the  trend is  universal  and  well  structured.  There  has  occurred  a  non-conjunctural  at¬ tenuation  of  the  bond  between  socialist  parties  and  the  electorate. Prospects  are  also  bleak  because  the  electoral  erosion  does  have  sociologi¬ cal  underpinnings  in  the  process  of  class  dealignment.  The  tendency  toward a  gradual  distancing  between  working-class  voters  and  social  democratic parties  has  lasted  for  nearly  forty  years.  It  is  a  sociological  tidal  wave  (less pronounced  in  some  countries  such  as  Sweden,  unmistakable  and  aggres¬ sive  in  some  others  such  as  Denmark)  that  reduces  social  democracy’s  natu¬ ral  level  of  support  and  renders  a  recovery  more  difficult.  In  addition,  social democracy’s  restructured  base  has  become  the  locus  of  a  profound  tension between  two  economically  and  culturally  distinct  groups,  the  working  class and  the  salaried  middle  strata.  The  “fragmented”  social  composition  of  social democratic  electorates  may  add  numbers  on  occasion,  but  it  is  also  a  con¬ straining  factor  reducing  the  freedom  to  maneuver  of  socialist  leaderships. It  is  an  internal  constraint  in  a  period  when  the  “external”  constraints  are  all but  rare. Third,  and  much  more  importantly,  the  electoral  weakening  of  social democratic  parties  coincides  with  a  parallel  crisis  of  political  projects  and imaginaries  (see  discussion  above).  A  host  of  economic  and  institutional  fac¬ tors,  national  and  international  — rather  than  some  lack  of  imagination  on the  part  of  social  democratic  headquarters— explains  social  democracy’s  in¬ capacity  to  provide  “new  clues”  for  perceiving  economic  and  social  reality. In  particular,  the  combined  forces  of  globalization  and  Europeanization  (in great  part  put  in  place  by  social  democrats  themselves)  have  not  only  changed the  balance  between  politics  and  markets  but  created  a  redoubtable  problem of  collective  action  and  coordination  for  all  those  aspiring  to  a  left-wing  re¬ form  strategy  (Moschonas  2009).  The  extraordinary  strengthening  of  the  EU from  1985  until  the  end  of  the  1990s  has  functioned  as  a  “conservative”  insti¬ tutional  trap  for  the  future,  by  locking  in  a  neoliberal  policy  logic  both  at  the EU  level  and  in  part  at  the  national  level  (McGowan  2001;  Moschonas  2009; Bailey  2009b;  Ross  in  this  volume).  Moreover,  the  “nationalism  paradox”  of European  unification  (Cuperus  2007)  reinforces  cultural  voting  and  becomes an  additional  factor  of  electoral  weakness  for  parties  of  the  social  democratic type  as  well  as  a  factor  favoring  the  consolidation  of  new  populist  parties. Could  this  situation  change  easily?  The  answer  is  an  unqualified  no,  be¬ cause  these  “internal”  and  “external”  factors  represent  sizable  and  not  short¬ term  obstacles  to  any  policy  reorientation.  In  a  sense,  today  the  “old”  diffi¬ culty  of  effective  political  management  of  complex  class  dynamics  is  largely aggravated  by  the  “new”  difficulty  of  effective  political  management  of  even 78  Moschonas more  complex  economic  and  institutional  dynamics.  Thus  the  lack  of  a  win¬ ning  ideological  and  programmatic  formula,  of  a  “single  synthetic  political strategy,”  already  at  the  source  of  the  recent  electoral  crisis,  risks  being  a  rela¬ tively  lasting  phenomenon.  With  respect  to  the  social  democratic  electoral prospects,  globalization  and  the  EU  are  obstacles  to  a  sustained  electoral  re¬ covery  of  social  democracy. A  Less  Serious  Crisis  of  Social  Democratic  Governance? Is  there  nothing  but  gloom  and  doom  ahead  for  European  socialists?  Here  we must  take  note  of  an  irony,  a  contradiction  between  electoral  trends  and  the prospects  for  getting  and  holding  office  and  for  governing  that  offers  a  less depressing  picture.  Nearly  all  the  available  evidence  suggests  that  the  social democratic  decline  is  part  of  a  deeper  and  vaster  electoral  change  which  af¬ fects  other  political  forces  — Christian  democracy  in  particular— as  much  as it  does  the  center-left.  It  is  a  period  of  fluid  electoral  landscapes  and  greater fragmentation  that  is  inauspicious  for  parties  of  majority  aspiration  or  parties in  office,  whether  they  are  social  democrats  or  their  opponents.  Thanks  to  the consolidation  of  new  party  actors— the  average  number  of  relevant  political parties  is  clearly  on  the  rise  in  western  democracies  (Henjak  2003)  — and  new or  renewed  party  families  (extreme  right,  greens,  or  radical  left),  the  phe¬ nomenon  of  electoral  erosion  must  be  relativized. The  real  political  force  of  social  democracy  is  obviously  reduced  by  its declining  electoral  performances,  but  it  is  indirectly  enhanced  by  the  splin¬ tering  of  the  competition  and  the  slumping  fortunes  of  its  main  opponents. If  the  present  is  judged  in  the  light  of  past  electoral  achievements,  from  the viewpoint  of  electoral  history  the  crisis  is  indeed  serious.  But  if  the  present  is judged  relative  to  itself,  from  the  viewpoint  of  the  actual  balance  of  forces,  it is  less  serious  and  different  in  kind.  The  unique  moment  of  the  1990s,  when modest  aggregate  gains  for  the  center-left  generated  great  governmental change,  showed  clearly  that  electoral  power  is  a  relative  quantity  in  the  con¬ temporary  world.  Electoral  power  is  not  merely  a  matter  of  percentages. Social  democratic  parties  have  in  this  sense  not  fundamentally  changed their  competitive  status  — as  certain  Christian  democratic  parties  have  done. They  have  not  become  politically  bankrupt,  and  they  remain  everywhere  key forces  in  the  political  system,  situated  in  an  electoral  zone  close  to  the  gov¬ ernmental  threshold  (Bergounioux  and  Grunberg  1996,  279).  This  is  a  stra¬ tegic  position  that  slows  the  process  of  erosion  in  difficult  times,  and  ac¬ celerates  the  process  of  recovery  in  better  times.  Even  in  countries  where the  downward  trend  in  social  democratic  voting  was  marked  by  brutal  “rup- Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  79 tures,”  there  was  always  a  reverse,  if  not  quite  equal,  subsequent  swing  of  the pendulum,  which  has  typically  brought  back  the  defeated  socialist  party  close to  the  governmental  threshold.  This  tendency  to  recover  indicates  a  margin of  safety  and  offers  a  timely  reminder  of  the  capacity  of  social  democracy to  remain  a  “credible  contender  for  power”  (Kalyvas  2003,  294)  in  a  politi¬ cal  context  characterized  by  “chronic  political  instability”  (Wolfreys  2006). We  would  argue  therefore  that  the  electoral  crisis  of  social  democracy  might be— in  its  political  and,  notably  its  governmental  consequences— less  marked and  less  serious  than  the  data  suggest. Conclusions:  A  Change  of  Scale Social  democracy  is  between  a  rock  and  a  hard  place.  In  a  way  it  put  itself there.  But  in  several  other  ways  numerous  “outside”  factors  — sociological, cultural,  institutional  — exerted  important  influence  on  its  electoral  dynam¬ ics.  Social  democratic  parties  in  Europe  are  caught  in  a  net  of  multicausal constraints,  including  shifting  demographics,  ideological  waves,  European integration,  globalization,  governmental  performances,  and  programmatic choices.  Some  of  these  factors  are  part  of  the  explanatory  background;  others (governmental  performances,  programmatic  choices,  strategic  leadership) are  “direct  causes.” In  any  case,  a  full  explanation  of  the  social  democratic  electoral  retreat  was outside  the  scope  of  this  chapter.  As  for  its  structure,  my  main  and  central ambition  was  to  document  and  specify  the  extent,  contradictions,  and  true scale  of  social  democratic  electoral  influence.  My  purpose  was  also  to  discuss two  questions:  First,  how  is  one  to  explain  the  divergent  electoral  dynamics in  northern  and  southern  Europe?  Second,  is  the  electoral  decline  inexorable; is  it  “historical,”  as  described  by  Adam  Przeworski  and  John  Sprague  more than  two  decades  ago? Let  us  now  try  to  recapitulate,  clarify,  and  in  part  reformulate  some  of  the theses  of  this  chapter. The  process  of  social  democratic  decline  is  highly  systematic:  it  is  relatively strong;  it  encompasses  nearly  all  countries  (with  the  exception  of  southern Europe);  it  is  confirmed  from  one  decade  to  the  next;  it  becomes  deeper  as  it progresses;  it  already  has  a  past  and  a  history;  even  when  the  electoral  pendu¬ lum  swings  back  it  systematically  yields  “smaller”  victories  than  in  the  past; and  it  provokes  occasionally  “catastrophic”  results  and  temporary  “minor” collapses.  The  electoral  dynamic  of  European  social  democracy  is  clearly  de¬ clining  and,  at  the  same  time,  the  volatility  of  its  performances  is  on  the  in¬ crease. 8o  Moschonas The  dynamic  of  decline  is  nevertheless  complex,  with  the  crisis  proceed¬ ing  in  zigzag  fashion.  It  is  evidenced  in  narrow  defeats  and  victories,  and landslide  defeats  and  victories.  It  does  not  progress  in  a  linear  fashion  but largely  takes  the  form  of  volatile  performances  (supported  by  volatile  voters). A  gradual,  slow  decline  at  the  aggregate  level  is  however  frequently  violent  at a  national  level.  While  it  is  conjuncturally  discontinuous,  it  is  persistent  over the  long  term. Our  initial— chronological  — option  to  regroup  electoral  performances  by decade,  and  not  into  political  and  economic  cycles,  actually  yields  a  better description  of  the  electoral  development  of  social  democracy.  However  our data  are  interpreted,  the  available  electoral  evidence  fully  justifies  a  division of  the  electoral  time  span  of  social  democracy  into  three  phases  (each  lasting approximately  twenty  years:  the  1950s  and  1960s,  the  1970s  and  1980s,  and the  1990s  and  2000s).  This  kind  of  division  underscores  better  the  specificity of  the  intermediate  phase  (the  1970s  and  1980s:  a  period  full  of  contradic¬ tory  trends),  as  well  as  the  scale  of  the  electoral  crisis  of  the  1990s  and  2000s, and  refines  approaches,  such  as  Merkel’s,  that  distinguish  between  the  period prior  to  1973  and  subsequent  years.  Developments  in  Australia  and  New  Zea¬ land  also  confirm,  even  more  emphatically,  that  the  period  of  weakening  par excellence  is  the  last  twenty  years.  Broad  economic  and  ideological  cycles hold  an  important  independent  power  in  influencing  electoral  performances, but  have  no  direct,  self-evident,  and  immediate  influence  on  electoral  results. In  any  case,  within  the  small  sphere  of  numbers  and  symbols  one  can  consider 1973,  the  year  of  the  two  dramatic  defeats  in  Denmark  and  Norway,  as  the  de¬ fining  moment  of  electoral  change. A  particularly  troubling  finding  is  that  those  parties  closest  to  the  “clas¬ sical”  social  democratic  model  (whatever  its  definition)  have  been  affected more  strongly  than  others  and  are  to  this  extent  more  than  others  in  the  eye of  the  storm.  It  is  the  epicenter  of  historical  social  democratic  forces,  the  hard core  of  the  socialist  family,  which  is  under  the  most  intense  pressure  (with the  partial  exception  of  Sweden).  On  the  other  hand,  and  perhaps  for  some equally  troubling,  Labourist  parties  of  the  Anglo-Saxon  type  have  been  more resilient.  In  addition,  and  again  somewhat  surprisingly,  parties  of  high  elec¬ toral  status  and  parties  in  more  majoritarian  political  systems  have  resisted better  than  those  in  “consensus-based”  democracies.  It  is  of  course  impos¬ sible  to  draw  firm  lines  between  these  different  experiences,  but  it  is  surely noteworthy  that  parties  belonging  to  liberal  environments  (the  United  King¬ dom,  Ireland,  but  also  New  Zealand  and  Australia)  or  non-social  democratic environments  (Spain,  Portugal,  Greece:  the  fourth  world  of  welfare  capital¬ ism,  see  Leibfried  2000,  193)  have  been  doing  better  than  those  in  more  so- Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  81 cial  democratic  environments.  The  tendency  opens  new  research  agendas  and suggests  new  and  stimulating  topics  of  inquiry. Given  these  realities,  it  would  seem  that  those  arguing  for  only  a  “slight decline”  in  center-left  fortunes  have  underestimated  the  magnitude  and  na¬ ture  of  the  electoral  erosion  (Merkel  2001;  Delwit  2005).20  In  addition,  the very  widespread  belief  in  an  electoral  renaissance  of  social  democracy  in the  late  1990s  is  largely  misleading.  Even  the  triumphant  social  democracy of  the  late  1990s  clearly  had  less  mastery  over  its  electorate  and  its  envi¬ ronment  than  its  predecessors  prior  to  1980.  The  current  influence  of  social democracy  in  fact  oscillates  at  around  80%  of  its  level  in  the  1950s  and  1960s (Spain,  Greece,  and  Portugal  not  included).  The  drop  is  strong,  although  it  is not  cataclysmic.  Thus  we  are  not  witnessing  the  “end”  or  the  “death”  of  elec¬ toral  social  democracy.  Nevertheless,  the  paths  of  retreat  show  that  the  elec¬ toral  ebbing  and  greater  instability  of  social  democratic  parties  is  a  genuinely firm  trend,  a  tendance  lourde. It  is  clear  as  well  that  the  “political  power  of  economic  ideas,”  to  borrow the  apt  expression  of  Peter  Hall  (Hall  ed.  1989),  which  was  an  asset  in  the past,  has  become  a  liability  for  today’s  social  democratic  parties.  The  domi¬ nation  of  liberal  economic  ideas  has  destabilized  social  democracy.  To  some extent  social  democracy  was  able  to  integrate  the  neoliberal  register  into its  own  political  rhetoric  and  governmental  output.  But  this  “grafting”  — the left’s  absorption  of  the  right’s  economic  agenda  (Duncan  2006,  483)— while electorally  successful  when  first  tried  in  the  1990s,  might  well  serve  to  under¬ mine  its  capacity  “to  achieve  electoral  success  over  the  long  term”  (Curtice 2007,  52;  also  Bailey  2009a,  32).  In  addition,  the  competitive  security  of  so¬ cial  democracy  seems  affected  by  a  certain  revival  of  the  radical  left  (commu¬ nists,  post-communists,  left  socialists). If  the  center-left’s  ability  to  contest  the  neoliberal  paradigm  may  have been  limited  in  the  period  since  1980,  it  is  also  quite  possible  that  the  new hegemony  can  be  undermined  from  within,  from  the  difficulty  of  achieving a  self-regulation  of  market  forces.  As  the  subprime  mortgage  crisis  and  the broader  economic  recession  have  recently  demonstrated,  the  blind  mechan¬ ics  of  markets  and  the  “irrational  exuberance”  of  financial  forces  (Krugman 2005,  30)  may  well  reactivate  core  social  democratic  ideas  about  the  regula¬ tory  role  of  politics  and  states.  Moreover,  and  fortunately  for  social  democ¬ racy,  there  is  abundant  evidence  that  in  the  OECD  countries  “popular  support for  egalitarianism  is  very  much  alive”  (Glyn  2006, 177).  Even  so,  recent  social democratic  moves  to  the  left,  evident  at  the  level  of  discourse,  risk  being without  important  policy  consequences  because  of  European  constraints  (in part  put  in  place  by  social  democrats  themselves). 82  Moschonas Recent  developments  in  Europe  offer  fresh  evidence.  Despite  the  excep¬ tional  emergency  circumstances,  social  democratic  leaders,  always  trapped by  European  institutional  constraints  and  poor  cooperation,  had  great  diffi¬ culty  in  inventing  new  policies  attuned  to  both  the  scale  of  the  crisis  and  the requirements  of  the  European  stage.  In  reality  they  were  seeking  Keynesian solutions  to  the  crisis  while  at  the  same  time  striving  to  maintain  a  neoliberal status  quo  and  to  preserve  the  Stability  and  Growth  Pact.  In  this  sense  social democracy’s  moves  to  the  left  are  institutionally  “rootless.”  For  now  social democracy  is  still  lacking  a  winning  ideological  and  programmatic  formula in  the  domain  of  economic  and  social  policy. It  is  too  soon  to  determine  the  influence  of  the  economic  crisis  on  the  elec¬ toral  cycle.  Nonetheless,  early  post-crisis  election  results  do  not  show  prom¬ ise  of  much  better  times.  In  sum,  two  parties,  the  Norwegian  DNA  (  +  2.7%) and  the  Greek  PASOK  (+5.8%),  registered  important  electoral  progress  (com¬ pared  with  their  previous  electoral  performance),  while  four  are  in  decline (Austria,  Luxembourg,  Portugal,  and  Germany).  Among  the  latter,  for  the Austrian  SPO  (-6%),  the  Portuguese  PS  (-8.5%),  and  of  course  the  German SPD  (-11.2%)  the  losses  are  highly  significant.  To  these  three  cases  of  elec¬ toral  setback  we  should  doubtless  add  the  “catastrophic”  result— a  defeat without  precedent— in  the  European  Union  elections  of  June  2009.  Yet  the number  of  elections  is  too  limited  to  provide  sufficient  data  to  (re)establish  a trend.  In  any  case,  in  a  time  of  distrustful  electorates  and  of  ideological  and policy  uncertainty,  a  long-term  trend  will  not  change  without  a  good  political reason. Overall,  our  findings  largely  confirm  the  thesis  that  social  democratic parties  have  come  down  a  notch  in  the  political  market;  they  have  become “smaller.”  And  they  will  probably  remain  so  for  a  long  time  to  come.  Being “smaller,”  whether  in  the  South  or  the  North,  will  not  prevent  socialists  from governing  or  winning  elections,  but  it  could  prevent  them  from  being  consis¬ tently  successful  over  a  long  period.  Social  democracy  has  changed  in  stat¬ ure  and  dimension,  but  its  level  of  influence  is  still  close  to  the  governmental threshold.  It  remains  in  the  game  of  governmental  alternation  and  is  still  a “credible  contender  for  power.”  Any  further  losses  beyond  the  current  point of  electoral  erosion,  however,  could  at  least  in  some  countries  make  less  cred¬ ible  the  strategy  of  acting  like  the  natural  party  of  government,  or  one  of  sev¬ eral.  Is  social  democracy  at  the  point  of  crossing  this  “critical  threshold”? Probably  not,  for  political  traditions  take  “a  long  time  to  establish  and  a  long time  to  break  down”  (Wolfreys  2006).  Historical  parties,  like  spirits,  live  on and  persist.  Nevertheless,  the  major  defeat  in  the  European  elections  of  2009 is  a  powerful  warning  signal.  Concerning  the  long-term  future,  the  evidence is  far  from  clear. Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  83 Social  democratic  parties  have  changed  in  scale.  In  a  sense  — in  just  the sense  that  I  have  tried  to  develop  in  this  chapter— this  change  of  scale  is  “his¬ torical.”  It  describes  a  new  condition.  But  this  “new”  condition  does  not  imply that  the  downward  trend  (at  the  aggregate  level)  will  expand  and  deepen.  It does  imply,  however,  that  there  is  no  easy  return  to  the  electoral  status  quo ante.  There  is  nothing  contradictory  in  the  supposition  that  social  democracy at  the  aggregate  level  is  likely  neither  to  easily  recover  nor  suffer  further  dra¬ matic  weakening.  Both  tendencies  may  be  part  of  what  makes  the  new  situa¬ tion  “new.” I  shall  permit  myself  a  final  thought  that  mixes  optimism  and  pessimism. In  my  view,  the  more  time  passes— and  this  is  something  that  does  not  emerge from  the  figures  presented  here— the  more  northern  socialists  and  southern socialists  will  come  to  have  the  “same  shadow,”  the  same  electoral  future. This  tendency  will  likely  persist  until  the  moment  when  a  new  reversal  oc¬ curs,  as  it  surely  will.  This  too  does  not  emerge  from  the  figures.  But  it  repre¬ sents  the  great  lesson  of  the  last  130  years  of  the  history  of  European  capital¬ ism,  a  history  intimately  bound  up  with  that  of  social  democracy. Notes Part  of  this  research  was  carried  out  in  2005,  during  my  three-month  residence  as  a visiting  scholar  at  Yale  University  (Political  Science  Department  and  the  Yale  Center of  International  and  Area  Studies)  under  a  grant  from  the  Fulbright  Foundation  in Greece.  I  am  indebted  to  Stathis  Kalyvas,  who  made  my  stay  at  Yale  easier  and  more productive.  I  am  grateful  to  James  Cronin,  George  Ross,  and  James  Shoch,  whose patient  and  meticulous  editing  and  critical  advice  have  significantly  improved  the quality  of  this  contribution.  I  would  like  to  thank  Vassia  Stagia  for  her  valuable  help  in updating  my  data  base  and  constructing  some  of  the  tables.  I  would  also  like  to  thank Vivian  Spyropoulou  for  generously  allowing  me  access  to  her  data,  thereby  facilitating my  work  in  checking  figures. 1.  The  decision  by  Merkel  (2001)  and  Delwit  (2005)  to  include  the  Italian  center- left  in  their  calculations  is  no  doubt  intellectually  legitimate,  since  the  space  of  the center-left,  with  or  without  the  PSI,  has  always  been  occupied  by  an  organized  politi¬ cal  force.  In  my  view  my  choice  has  the  merit  of  greater  consistency.  In  any  event,  with or  without  Italy  the  aggregate  trend  does  not  change  significantly. 2.  The  designation  (Golden  Age)  produces  “a  false  impression  of  social  democratic potency  in  the  years  of  the  ‘long  boom’”  (Callaghan  2000,  436). 3.  For  the  Austrians  and  the  Germans  the  1970s  were  the  best  decade  of  the  entire postwar  period  (with  an  average  score  that  was  impressive  for  the  SPO— 50%— and excellent  for  the  SPD— 44.2%).  For  the  Dutch  (31%)  and  the  Finnish  (25.4%)  the  1980s were  their  best  years. 4.  Some  examples  illustrate  the  new  situation  with  perfect  clarity:  -17.1%  for  the 84  Moschonas French  socialists  in  1993  (1988:  34.7%;  1993:  17.6%);  -10.8%  for  the  Norwegians  in 2001;  -7.9%  for  the  Dutch  in  1994  and  another  -13.9%  in  2002;  -8.9%  for  the  Swedes in  1998;  -7.9%  for  the  Austrians  in  1994;  -6.8%  for  the  Danish  in  2001;  -6.7%  for  the Belgians  in  2007.  Notwithstanding  its  small  size,  even  the  Irish  Labour  Party  experi¬ enced  great  instability.  It  more  than  doubled  its  electoral  strength  in  1992  and  then  lost 8.9%  in  the  subsequent  election  (1989:  9.5%;  1992;  19.3%;  1997: 10.4%). 5.  Overall  we  witness  the  same  trend  in  European  elections  (Grunberg  and  Moscho¬ nas  2005). 6.  In  the  European  Parliament  as  well,  successive  enlargements  of  the  EEC/EU  have played  an  important  role  in  the  electoral  consolidation  of  the  socialist  family  (Grun¬ berg  and  Moschonas  2005). 7.  Contra  Merkel  (1992a,  142),  I  do  not  group  the  French  SFIO/PS  and  the  Greek PASOK  with  parties  of  the  “roman”  variety  (despite  important  similarities),  and  con¬ versely,  in  an  analysis  focused  on  electoral  trends,  I  find  it  difficult  to  consider  the  Ger¬ man  SPD  and  the  Austrian  SPO  as  belonging  to  different  typological  groups  (despite important  dissimilarities). 8.  These  parties,  from  the  standpoint  of  electoral  sociology,  were  characterized during  the  1960s  by  an  electoral  penetration  that  approximated  or  exceeded  two-thirds of  the  working-class  vote  in  Sweden  and  Norway,  60%  in  Great  Britain,  Denmark,  and Austria,  and  just  over  50%  in  Germany  (Moschonas  2002,  50). 9.  Merkel  includes  the  SPD  in  the  “pragmatic  coalescent”  group.  He  also  constructs a  “Labourist”  group  containing  the  British  and  Irish  Labour  parties  (Merkel  1992a, 144-45).  Historical  and  profile  affinities  partly  justify  this  choice.  Nevertheless,  the political  role  assumed  by  the  above-mentioned  parties  in  their  respective  political  sys¬ tems  is  very  dissimilar  because  of  their  differing  electoral  size. 10.  The  border  case  here  is  the  Finish  SDP.  A  powerful  party  in  the  1930s,  it  suffered from  the  consolidation  of  an  influential  communist  pole  and  the  division  of  the  labor movement.  The  era  of  consensualism  in  Finish  politics,  which  began  in  the  mid-1960s and  ended  only  recently,  allowed  for  SDP’s  frequent  participation  in  government.  The intermediate  competitive  status  of  the  party  explains  its  inclusion  in  the  second  group (see  Sundberg  1999,  57,  59). 11.  The  French  SFIO/PS  party  is  not  included  in  this  group.  The  marked  specificity  of French  socialism  makes  it  a  “unique”  case  (medium  electoral  status  but  in  a  majoritar- ian  political  system;  often  governing  in  single-party  governments;  no  connection  with the  trade-union  movement;  well- developed  democratic  institutions  and  welfare  state; and  last  but  not  least,  an  uninterrupted  series  of  electoral  data).  The  French  party, traditionally  capable  of  the  best  and  the  worst,  is  characterized  by  a  congenital  insta¬ bility.  Badly  weakened  in  the  1950s  and  1960s  and  thus  a  mere  shadow  of  its  former self  in  the  run-up  to  1968  (Horn  2007, 163, 136;  Ross  and  Goldhammer  in  this  volume), it  made  significant  breakthroughs  in  the  1980s.  Overall  it  tends  to  stabilize  at  a  higher level  compared  to  the  1950s. 12.  Although  this  party  experienced  its  real  national  golden  age  a  little  later,  in  the 1970s. Historical  Decline  or  Change  of  Scale?  85 13.  In  the  light  of  this  picture  of  abrupt  declines  and  destabilization,  the  Finnish distinguish  themselves  by  their  remarkable  stability.  The  exception  came  in  the  1990s, when  they  made  a  modest  breakthrough  in  1995  (28.3%),  only  to  return  immediately afterward  to  more  traditional  results  (22.9%  in  1999). 14.  In  the  elections  of  2007  PASOK  posted  its  worst  electoral  performance  (38.1%) since  the  late  1970s.  However,  we  should  note  the  excellent  performance  of  the  Greek socialists  in  2009  (43.92%). 15.  Here  we  use  the  definitions  offered  by  Stephens,  Huber,  and  Ray  (1999). 16.  Two  more  countries,  Canada  and  the  United  States,  included  by  Esping-Andersen in  the  low  decommodification  group  (1990,  52)  are  not  part  of  our  calculations  for  evi¬ dent  reasons. 17.  The  partial  exception  would  be  Sweden,  though  the  SAP  is  rather  friendly  toward a  market  economy.  See  Hinnfors  (2006)  and  Pontusson  (this  volume). 18.  The  Portuguese  PS  has  been  moderately  successful,  but  not  on  the  scale  of  the Spanish  and  Greek  parties  (see  Magone  2007;  Delwit  2007). 19.  Thus  according  to  Kitschelt,  “given  that  social  democratic  politicians  are  ratio¬ nal  .  .  .  the  current  search  for  new  ‘winning  electoral  formulas’  on  the  political  left may  yield  considerable  electoral  and  programmatic  instability  of  social  democratic parties  across  Europe  rather  than  uniform  and  progressive  decline”  (1999,  344-45). Since  Kitschelt  wrote,  we  have  seen  both  electoral  and  programmatic  instability  and an  (almost)  uniform  and  progressive  decline. 20.  Our  individual  country  data  confirm  Merkel’s  findings  with  only  rare  and  slight differences.  By  employing  Merkel’s  periodization  and  approach  (inclusion  of  Italy,  ex¬ clusion  of  Luxembourg),  I  recalculated  the  average  electoral  results  for  the  periods 1950-73  and  1990-99  (see  Merkel  2001,  34).  According  to  this  calculation,  the  inclu¬ sion  of  Italy  in  the  Merkel’s  data  attenuates  the  social  democratic  retreat  by  1.3  points, and  the  inclusion  of  Spain,  Greece,  and  Portugal  in  the  diachronic  comparison  adds  2.1 more  points  to  the  downward  trend  for  the  period  in  question. In  his  detailed  study,  however,  Pascal  Delwit  clearly  highlights  the  main  tendency: the  downward  trend  “for  the  great  majority”  of  social  democratic  parties  as  well  as  the “structural  erosion”  of  the  Scandinavian  ones  (Delwit  2005,  66-67). Part  II Varieties  of  Social  Democracy  and  Liberalism Once  Again  a  Model Nordic  Social  Democracy  in  a  Globalized  World Jonas  Pontusson What  are  the  prospects  for  social  democracy  in  the  current  era  of  global  eco¬ nomic  crisis?  The  answer  to  this  question  surely  depends  on  what  we  mean by  “social  democracy.”  And  to  specify  this  we  need  empirical  referents.  By  my reading  of  public  debates  as  well  as  academic  literature  on  both  sides  of  the Atlantic,  it  has  become  increasingly  common  over  the  last  couple  of  decades to  conflate  “social  democracy”  with  “Social  Europe.”  This  is  unfortunate on  two  counts.  First,  the  economic  performance  of  continental  Europe  has been  sluggish  by  comparison  to  that  of  liberal  market  economies  such  as  the United  States  and  the  United  Kingdom.  Second,  the  notion  of  “Social  Europe” usually  connotes  institutional  arrangements— patient  capital,  codetermina¬ tion,  vocational  training  — that  cannot  readily  be  transposed  to  other  settings. To  the  extent  that  this  is  what  social  democracy  is  all  about,  its  relevance  to contemporary  politics  in  the  United  States  or  other  liberal  market  economies would  appear  to  be  very  limited. The  basic  aim  of  this  chapter  is  in  a  sense  to  rescue  social  democracy  from the  economic  travails  of  continental  Europe  by  reinstating  the  Nordic  coun¬ tries  as  the  main  exemplars  of  the  social  democratic  approach  to  managing capitalism.  The  reasons  why  the  Nordic  countries  have  figured  so  promi¬ nently  in  discussions  of  social  democracy  hardly  need  to  be  rehearsed.  In  a nutshell,  unions  and  social  democratic  parties  have  historically  been  stronger and  more  influential  in  the  Nordic  countries  than  in  any  other  liberal  democ¬ racies.  Social  democratic  parties  governed  Sweden,  Denmark,  and  Norway more  or  less  continuously  from  the  1930s  into  the  1970s  and  remain  major contenders  for  government  power  in  all  the  Nordic  countries,  including  Fin¬ land.1  As  commonly  noted  in  the  existing  literature,  moreover,  even  center- right  parties  in  the  Nordic  countries  have  to  a  large  extent  embraced  social democratic  policy  priorities.  All  of  this  is  well  established.  The  “news”  that 90  Pontusson my  discussion  builds  on  is  that  the  Nordic  countries  again  became  economic success  stories  over  the  period  stretching  from  the  mid-1990s  until  the  onset of  the  global  economic  crisis  in  2008.  Not  only  did  the  Nordic  countries  ex¬ perience  more  rapid  growth  than  just  about  any  other  OECD  economies  in this  period  (except  Ireland),  they  also  appear  to  have  adjusted  successfully to  changes  in  the  global  economy  by  shifting  into  more  knowledge-intensive services  and  manufacturing.  The  question  becomes  whether  there  is  some¬ thing  social  democratic  about  the  recent  success  of  the  Nordic  economies.  If the  answer  to  that  question  is  yes,  then  it  becomes  plausible  to  argue  that  so¬ cial  democracy  represents  a  realistic  alternative  to  market  liberalism,  worthy of  examination  and  perhaps  emulation  by  progressive  political  forces  outside the  Nordic  area. The  chapter  consists  of  three  parts.  In  the  first  part,  I  delineate  what  is  dis¬ tinctively  social  democratic  about  the  four  Nordic  countries  by  identifying policies  (and  policy  outcomes)  on  which  these  countries  differ  from  Germany and  other  “social  market  economies”  in  continental  Europe.  Building  on  sev¬ eral  existing  typologies,  I  use  the  term  “social  market  economies”  (SMEs)  to encompass  France  as  well  as  Germany  and  its  smaller  next-door  neighbors: Austria,  Switzerland,  Belgium,  and  the  Netherlands.2  In  essence  I  consider policies  that  the  Nordic  countries  have  in  common  to  be  core  social  demo¬ cratic  policies  provided  that  they  also  distinguish  the  Nordic  countries  from continental  SMEs  and  that  they  can  be  traced  to  social  democratic  initiatives. This  exercise  yields  the  following  broad  features  of  what  I  will  refer  to  as  the “social  democratic  policy  regime”:  universalism  in  the  design  of  social  insur¬ ance  schemes,  direct  public  provision  of  social  services,  solidaristic  wage  bar¬ gaining,  active  labor  market  policies,  policies  to  promote  female  employment and  gender  equality  in  the  labor  market,  and  finally,  high  levels  of  invest¬ ment  in  public  education  and  policies  to  equalize  educational  opportunity. Throughout  the  following  discussion  I  emphasize  complementarities  among these  policies.  I  also  emphasize  that  these  policies  were  designed  to  promote labor  mobility  and  productivity  as  well  as  to  redistribute  income  and  equalize opportunity. In  the  second  part  of  the  chapter  I  address  the  institutional  conditions  for the  success  of  social  democratic  policies  by  engaging  with  the  varieties-of- capitalism  literature.  Contrary  to  what  this  literature  seems  to  imply,  I  do  not believe  that  the  economic  benefits  of  social  democratic  policies  are  contin¬ gent  on  the  persistence  of  “patient  capital”  and  manufacturing  systems  that rely  on  the  kinds  of  skills  acquired  by  workers  through  vocational  training along  German  lines.  I  argue  that  social  democratic  policies  have  benefits  for  a wide  range  of  business  activities  and  that  more  footloose  or  short-term  inves- Once  Again  a  Model  91 tors  should  be  able  to  recognize  these  benefits.  At  the  same  time,  I  argue  that the  effective  implementation  of  core  components  of  the  social  democratic policy  regime  depends  on  the  participation  of  organized  business  and  above all  on  the  existence  of  encompassing  and  cohesive  unions. In  the  third  part  I  contrast  the  economic  performance  of  the  Nordic  coun¬ tries  since  1995  with  that  of  continental  SMEs.  Here  my  core  arguments  are that  the  welfare  states  of  the  Nordic  countries  facilitated  the  adoption  of  de- regulatory  reforms  that  contributed  to  economic  growth  and  restructuring and  that  the  egalitarianism  of  these  countries,  particularly  in  the  realm  of education,  has  also  contributed  directly  to  their  economic  success.  In  addi¬ tion  to  developing  these  arguments,  I  present  data  showing  that  the  growing gap  between  labor-market  “insiders”  and  “outsiders”  is  first  and  foremost  a continental  phenomenon.  This  and  other  dualist  trends  have  been  much  less pronounced  in  the  Nordic  countries. By  way  of  conclusion,  I  will  briefly  address  the  implications  of  the  current economic  crisis  for  the  social  democratic  project  as  I  understand  it,  as  well  as the  lessons  that  progressive  forces  in  the  United  States  might  draw  from  the Nordic  experience. Nordic  Egalitarianism  versus  Continental  Social  Protection In  emphasizing  differences  between  Nordic  and  continental  political  econo¬ mies,  my  discussion  builds  on  the  insights  of  Esping-Andersen  (1990)  and subsequent  comparative  welfare-state  literature  (notably  Huber  and  Stephens 2001  and  Swank  2002).  This  literature  teaches  us  that  the  “conservative”  wel¬ fare  states  of  continental  Europe  — above  all  Germany  and  France— provide insurance  against  income  losses  associated  with  unemployment,  poor  health, and  old  age  that  is  roughly  comparable  to  the  insurance  provided  by  Nordic welfare  states,  but  they  do  so  in  ways  that  to  a  much  greater  extent  preserve existing  income  and  status  differentials.  Generalizing,  we  might  say  that  the two  core  pillars  of  social  protection  in  continental  Europe  are  legislation  and regulatory  practices  that  restrict  the  ability  of  employers  to  fire  workers,  and mandatory  social  insurance  based  on  earnings-differentiated  benefits. Relative  to  the  continental  model,  the  welfare  states  built  up  by  Scandina¬ vian  social  democrats  in  the  1940s  and  1950s  were  based  on  the  idea  of  “so¬ cial  citizenship,”  which  concretely  manifested  itself  in  the  emphasis  on  flat- rate  benefits  and  government-provided  services  financed  out  of  general  taxes (rather  than  earmarked  payroll  contributions).  Starting  with  the  introduction of  supplementary  pension  schemes  in  the  1960s,  earnings-related  benefits  as¬ sumed  a  prominent  role,  but  the  emphasis  on  the  public  sector  has  remained 92  Pontusson a  distinctive  feature  of  Nordic  welfare  states.  Equally  important,  these  wel¬ fare  states  incorporated  the  principle  of  earnings-differentiated  benefits  into comprehensive  social  insurance  systems  that  covered  everyone,  as  distinct from  the  occupationally  (and  sometimes  sectorally)  segregated  insurance schemes  characteristic  of  continental  welfare  states. Setting  aside  the  public  provision  of  services,  the  Nordic  countries  do  not spend  significantly  more  of  their  GDP  on  income  transfers,  yet  they  achieve a  much  larger  reduction  of  household  income  inequality  through  income transfers  than  most  of  their  continental  neighbors  do.3  Redistribution  through taxes  and  transfers  is  clearly  one  crucial  reason  why  the  Nordic  countries have  a  much  more  equal  distribution  of  disposable  income  and  also  lower poverty  rates  than  the  social  market  economies  of  continental  Europe,  let alone  the  liberal  market  economies  of  the  Anglophone  world  (see  table  i).4 It  is  important  to  note  that  redistribution  was  not  the  only  motivation  be¬ hind  the  distinctive  approach  to  welfare-state  design  adopted  by  Scandina¬ vian  social  democrats.  Another  important  motivation  was  the  idea  that  pub¬ lic  provision  of  benefits,  organized  on  a  universalistic  basis,  would  facilitate labor  mobility  across  firms  and  across  sectors  of  the  economy  and  thereby provide  for  a  more  efficient  allocation  of  labor.  The  attitude  toward  employ¬ ment  security  adopted  by  the  Swedish  social  democrats  in  the  1950s  and 1960s  is  also  very  relevant  in  this  context.  Cognizant  of  Sweden’s  export  de¬ pendence  and  the  need  for  economic  restructuring  in  response  to  changes  in world  markets,  Swedish  union  leaders  and  social  democratic  politicians  very explicitly  eschewed  the  idea  that  the  government  should  provide  workers with  security  in  their  current  jobs.  Their  stated  goal  was  to  provide  for  “secu¬ rity  in  the  labor  market,”  as  distinct  from  “job  security.”  Pursuing  this  goal  en¬ tailed  generous  unemployment  compensation  to  protect  workers  against  the income  losses  associated  with  unemployment,  but  also  active  labor  market policies  to  help  workers  find  new,  higher-paying,  and  otherwise  better  jobs. In  the  context  of  severe  industrial  adjustment  problems,  the  Swedish  labor movement  in  the  1970s  pushed  for  new  laws  restricting  the  ability  of  em¬ ployers  to  fire  workers.  By  recent  OECD  measures,  employment  protection in  Sweden  is  slightly  stricter  than  in  Germany  and  less  strict  than  in  France (Pontusson  2005a,  120).  Yet  Denmark  stands  out  as  one  of  the  West  European countries  with  the  least  restrictive  laws  governing  the  ability  of  employers  to fire  workers.  In  this  respect  Denmark  might  be  said  to  have  remained  more true  to  traditional  social  democratic  principles  than  Sweden,  but  it  should also  be  noted  that  standard  OECD  measures  ignore  the  fact  that  Swedish  em¬ ployment  protection  legislation  gives  firms  and  unions  the  right  to  negotiate alternative  arrangements,  and  the  typical  tendency  is  for  collective  bargain- Table  1.  Measures  of  Inequality,  circa  2000 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) Female/ Female/ Male 95-5 90-10 Male Employ- Ratio Household Full-Time Full-Time ment on Information- Income Poverty Wage Wage Rate Literacy Age Inequality Rate Ratio Ratio Ratio Tests Literacy LME  average .332 14.4 3.58 .767 .812 2.53 52 United  States .370 17.7 4.35 .755 .857 2.79 53 Continental  average .267 7.3 3.00 .797 .781 2.00 58 Germany .275 8.4 2.93 .760 .797 1.73 59 Nordic  average .244 5.9 2.23 .817 .919 1.76 68 Denmark .225 5.4 2.16 .893 1.65 65 Finland .247 5.4 2.41 .788 .929 1.86 63 Norway .251 6.4 2.00 .906 1.75 69 Sweden .252 6.5 2.35 .845 .949 1.79 74 Limited  market  economy  (LME)  average  =  unweighted  average  for  Australia,  Canada,  Ireland, the  United  Kingdom,  and  the  United  States Continental  average  =  unweighted  average  for  Austria,  Belgium,  France,  Germany,  the  Nether¬ lands,  and  Switzerland  in  columns  1-5,  Belgium,  Germany,  the  Netherlands,  and  Switzerland  in columns  6-7 Nordic  average  =  unweighted  average  for  the  four  Nordic  countries  (except  for  column  4) (1)  Gini  coefficient  for  disposable  household  income  (adjusted  for  household  size).  The  figures refer  to  2000  except  for  Australia  (2001),  the  United  Kingdom  (1999),  and  the  Netherlands  (1999). Source:  http://www.lisproject.org/keyfigures.htm. (2)  Percentage  of  population  living  in  households  with  less  than  50%  of  the  median  disposable household  income.  Same  years  and  source  as  column  (1). (3)  The  ratio  of  earnings  in  the  90th  percentile  to  earnings  in  the  10th  percentile,  gross  earn¬ ings  for  full-time  employees.  The  figures  refer  to  1999-2000  except  for  Denmark  (1990).  Source: Organisation  for  Economic  Cooperation  and  Development  (OECD)  Relative  Earnings  Database (unpublished). (4)  The  ratio  of  the  median  female  wage  to  the  median  male  wage,  full-time  employees  only. Same  years  and  source  as  column  (3). (5)  The  ratio  of  the  female  employment  rate  to  the  male  employment  rate  in  2000  (employment rate  =  employed  individuals  as  a  percentage  of  the  population  between  the  ages  of  15  and  64). Source:  OECD  2004,  295-96. (6)  The  ratio  of  95th-percentile  test  scores  to  sth-percentile  scores  on  literacy  tests  for  popula¬ tion  aged  15-65  in  1994-98.  Source:  OECD  2000, 135-36. (7)  Percentage  of  the  population  scoring  at  level  3  or  better  on  literacy  tests.  Same  years  and source  as  column  (6). 94  Pontusson ing  agreements  to  be  more  flexible  than  what  the  law  prescribes.  Particularly if  we  extend  our  perspective  to  encompass  additional  issues  such  as  health and  safety,  the  Nordic  countries  are  still  distinguished  not  only  from  France but  also  from  Germany  by  their  (de  facto)  reliance  on  collective  bargaining rather  than  government  legislation  to  regulate  employment  conditions. Alongside  welfare-state  universalism,  the  so-called  Rehn-Meidner  model deserves  a  prominent  place  in  most  discussions  of  Nordic  social  democracy  as a  distinctive  policy  regime.  Conceived  by  economists  working  for  the  Swedish confederation  of  blue-collar  unions  in  the  1950s,  this  intellectual  construct became  the  justification  for  an  aggressive  union  push  for  wage  leveling  and for  the  expansion  of  active  labor  market  policies  in  the  1960s  and  1970s.  To varying  degrees  and  with  some  modifications,  unions  and  social  democratic parties  in  the  other  Nordic  countries  emulated  the  policies  associated  with the  Rehn-Meidner  model. The  Rehn-Meidner  model  articulated  the  egalitarian  goals  of  the  labor movement  as  part  of  a  strategy  to  promote  productivity  growth  and  contain wage  inflation.  On  the  one  hand,  a  concerted  union  effort  to  provide  low- wage  workers  with  higher  wage  increases  than  market  forces  dictated  would squeeze  the  profits  of  less  efficient  firms  (or  sectors)  and  force  them  either to  rationalize  production  or  go  out  of  business.  On  the  other  hand,  wage restraint  by  well-paid  workers  would  promote  the  expansion  of  more  effi¬ cient  firms  (or  sectors).  For  the  unions  to  pursue  this  strategy  the  government needed  to  develop  active  labor  market  measures  that  would  ease  the  transi¬ tion  of  workers  from  less  efficient  to  more  efficient  firms  and  sectors  and  also to  curtail  wage  drift  caused  by  bottlenecks  in  the  supply  of  labor.5 The  insight  at  the  core  of  the  Rehn-Meidner  strategy  is  that  low  wages  rep¬ resent  a  subsidy  to  inefficient  capital.  At  the  same  time,  Rehn  and  Meidner recognized  that  wage  differentials  were  necessary  as  an  incentive  for  workers to  acquire  skills  and  take  on  more  responsibility  in  the  production  process. The  goal  of  union  wage  policy  should  be  to  eliminate  differentials  based  on corporate  profitability  while  maintaining  differentials  based  on  skills  and effort.  In  other  words,  the  goal  of  union  wage  policy  should  be  “equal  pay  for equal  work,”  as  distinct  from  “equal  pay  for  everyone.” In  practice  it  proved  difficult  for  Swedish  unions  to  maintain  the  distinc¬ tion  between  “good”  and  “bad”  wage  differentials  in  the  context  of  full  em¬ ployment  and  economy-wide  wage  bargaining.  Solidaristic  wage  policy  may have  become  too  egalitarian  in  the  course  of  the  1960s  and  1970s,  produc¬ ing  a  generalized  profits  squeeze  and  ultimately  a  campaign  by  employers  to decentralize  wage  bargaining  in  the  1980s  (Pontusson  and  Swenson  1996). While  Norway  has  retained  peak-level  wage  negotiations,  the  locus  of  Danish Once  Again  a  Model  95 wage  bargaining  has  also  shifted  to  the  industry  level  (Wallerstein  and  Golden 2000).  With  respect  to  formal  institutional  arrangements,  we  can  no  longer speak  of  a  Nordic  model  of  wage  bargaining  that  is  clearly  distinct  from  the continental  model.  In  marked  contrast  to  the  social  market  economies  of continental  Europe,  however,  union  membership  held  up  quite  well  in  the Nordic  countries  in  the  1980s  and  1990s  (see  table  2),  and  partly  as  a  result  of this,  Nordic  unions  appear  to  have  retained  a  greater  capacity  to  coordinate their  wage  demands  based  on  solidaristic  principles.  As  table  1  shows,  wage compression  remains  a  distinctive  characteristic  of  the  Nordic  countries  as  a group. The  Nordic  social  democrats  began  to  articulate  gender  equality  as  a  core component  of  their  reformist  project  in  the  1960s  and  policies  to  promote women’s  participation  in  the  labor  force— chiefly  parental  leave  insurance and  public  childcare— emerged  as  a  widely  admired  feature  of  the  Nordic model  in  the  1970s.  The  literature  on  gender  and  the  welfare  state  (e.g., Sainsbury  1999)  commonly  draws  a  sharp  contrast  between  the  progressive, gender-egalitarian  approach  to  family  policy  characteristic  of  the  Nordic countries  and  the  conservative,  “male-breadwinner”  approach  of  Germany and  other  continental  countries  in  which  Christian  democratic  ideology  has been  influential.  Relatedly,  I  want  to  emphasize  the  affinity  between  gender- egalitarian  policies  adopted  in  the  1970s  and  existing  social  democratic  com¬ mitments  to  the  public  sector  and  to  solidaristic  wage  policy.  While  the  ex¬ pansion  of  welfare-related  public  services  became  the  principal  source  of new  employment  for  women  from  the  1960s  through  the  1980s,  the  closing of  the  pay  gap  between  men  and  women  was  from  the  beginning  a  major  ob¬ jective  of  solidaristic  wage  policy. Column  4  in  table  1  reports  on  gendered  pay  differentials,  measured  as  the ratio  of  the  median  female  wage  to  the  median  male  wage,  but  these  data pertain  to  full-time  employees  alone,  and  we  only  have  data  for  two  of  the Nordic  countries,  Sweden  and  Finland.  Combining  these  two,  quite  disparate observations  yields  an  average  that  is  two  percentage  points  higher  than  the average  for  continental  SMEs,  but  there  is  also  a  lot  of  variation  among  conti¬ nental  SMEs  in  this  regard.  The  contrast  between  the  Nordic  countries  and  the continental  SMEs  is  much  clearer  in  column  5,  which  reports  on  employment- rate  differentials  between  men  and  women.  Women  have  a  much  higher  labor force  participation  rate  in  Nordic  countries  than  in  either  continental  SMEs  or Anglophone  LMEs. The  final  contrast  that  I  wish  to  draw  between  Nordic  and  continental  po¬ litical  economies  concerns  education  and  skill  formation.  This  is  a  topic  that has  recently  caught  the  attention  of  students  of  comparative  political  econ- 96  Pontusson omy.  In  the  Varieties-of-Capitalism  (VofC)  tradition,  skill  formation  has  come to  be  seen  as  the  crucial  link  between  social  provisions  and  production  strate¬ gies  (cf.  Estevez-Abe,  Iversen,  and  Soskice  2001;  Iversen  2005;  and  Iversen and  Stephens  2008).  In  a  nutshell,  the  standard  VofC  argument  is  that  high levels  of  employment  protection  and  social  insurance  in  the  Nordic  countries as  well  as  continental  Europe  are  associated,  as  both  cause  and  effect,  with the  fact  that  these  economies  rely  more  heavily  than  liberal  market  econo¬ mies  do  on  firm-  and  industry-specific  skills.  Investment  in  specific  skills  is riskier  than  investment  in  general  skills,  and  if  this  sort  of  investment  is  to  be undertaken,  there  must  be  some  assurance  of  good  long-term  employment prospects  in  the  firm  or  industry  to  which  the  skills  apply,  as  well  as  some assurance  of  income  support  during  possible  spells  of  unemployment.  In  turn, firms  that  rely  on  specific  skills  can  be  expected  to  join  with  skilled  workers in  a  cross-class  alliance  in  support  of  social  protection  as  well  as  vocational training. In  my  view  this  argument  captures  something  quite  essential  about  the social  market  economies  of  continental  Europe,  but  it  misses  several  impor¬ tant  things  about  the  Nordic  experience.  To  begin  with,  the  tension  between vocational  training  that  follows  the  German  model  and  social  democratic  am¬ bitions  to  remove  barriers  to  class  mobility  through  educational  achievement deserves  to  be  noted.  In  Sweden  education  reforms  in  the  1950s  and  1960s  in¬ corporated  vocational  training  for  fifteen-  to  eighteen-year-olds  into  the  new (comprehensive)  secondary  schools,  effectively  eliminating  apprenticeship- based  training  (Pontusson  1997).  Though  some  apprenticeship-based  training survived  in  Denmark,  the  thrust  of  postwar  educational  changes  in  the  other Nordic  countries  appears  to  have  been  similar  to  what  we  observe  in  Swe¬ den.  While  the  UNESCO  sources  cited  by  Iversen  and  Stephens  (2008,  616) indicate  that  the  proportion  of  school-age  cohorts  engaged  in  “vocational training”  is  about  the  same  in  the  Nordic  countries  as  in  Germany  (and  much higher  than  in  Austria  or  Switzerland),  the  question  becomes  whether  the  fig¬ ures  are  really  comparable.  Based  on  the  results  of  adult  literacy  tests,  there  is good  reason  to  believe  that  the  general-skills  component  of  vocational  train¬ ing  is  more  pronounced  in  the  Nordic  countries. A  second  and  related  point  is  that  Denmark,  Norway,  and  Sweden  stand out  as  the  three  OECD  countries  that  spend  the  largest  share  of  their  GDP on  public  education,  with  Finland  ranked  fifth  (following  New  Zealand)  on this  measure  (Iversen  and  Stephens  2008,  616;  see  also  Pontusson  2005a, 134).  Partly  in  response  to  deteriorating  employment  conditions,  the  Nordic countries  increased  spending  on  higher  education  quite  dramatically  in  the 1980s  and  1990s,  but  their  most  remarkable  achievement  in  this  realm  has Once  Again  a  Model  97 to  do  with  basic  skills.  In  the  international  adult  literacy  study  carried  out by  the  OECD  and  Statistics  Canada  in  the  second  half  of  the  1990s,  the  four Nordic  countries  stood  out  not  only  as  the  countries  with  the  highest  mean scores  but  also  as  the  countries  with  the  most  compressed  distributions  of  test scores  (see  table  1,  column  6).  The  proportion  of  the  population  that  passed the  study’s  threshold  for  “information  age  literacy”  was  also  higher  in  the Nordic  countries  than  in  any  of  the  countries  included  in  the  study  (table  1, column  7). The  Nordic  experience  suggests  that  educational  equality  and  economic equality  are  closely  linked.  As  Blau  and  Kahn  (2005)  point  out,  compression of  educational  achievement  can  be  invoked  to  explain  cross-national  varia¬ tion  in  wage  inequality.  At  the  same  time,  we  might  reasonably  suppose  that children  from  low-income  households  are  better  able  to  take  advantage  of educational  opportunities  when  the  distribution  of  household  income  and living  conditions  is  more  equal  (cf.  Iversen  and  Stephens  2008,  621-22).  The very  low  rates  of  child  poverty  in  the  Nordic  countries  deserve  to  be  men¬ tioned  in  this  context  (see  Pontusson  2005a,  160). Relatively  high  skill  levels  at  the  bottom  of  the  skill  hierarchy  may  have enabled  employers  in  the  Nordic  countries  to  contend  with  the  challenges posed  by  solidaristic  wage  policy,  allowing  them  to  deploy  new  technolo¬ gies  and  thereby  improve  productivity  with  low-skilled  workers.  Also,  the expansion  of  higher  education  has  undoubtedly  curtailed  the  growth  of  re¬ turns  to  education  in  these  countries.  In  both  these  ways  public  investment in  education  has  made  it  easier  for  unions  to  practice  wage  solidarity.  In  the realm  of  traditional  manufacturing,  the  argument  about  skills  facilitating  the deployment  of  new  technologies  surely  pertains  to  technical  as  well  as  gen¬ eral  skills.  What  is  most  distinctive  about  the  skill  profile  of  the  Nordic  coun¬ tries,  however,  is  the  quality  of  general  skills  at  the  bottom  of  the  distribu¬ tion.  Public  investment  in  education  is  particularly  relevant  to  explaining why  the  Nordic  economies  have  outperformed  the  continental  economies  in knowledge-intensive  manufacturing  and  private  services  over  the  last  fifteen years  (a  topic  to  which  I  shall  return). To  sum  up,  the  preceding  discussion  calls  into  question  the  attempt  by Esping-Andersen  (1990)  to  capture  what  Nordic  social  democracy  has  been about  with  the  concept  of  “decommodification.”  Socializing  social  benefits  or, in  other  words,  reducing  the  role  of  firms  (and  families)  as  providers  of  social benefits  has  indeed  been  an  objective  of  Nordic  social  democracy,  but  none of  the  policies  enumerated  above  have  entailed  decommodification  in  the broader  sense  of  an  emancipation  of  workers  from  their  dependence  on  the labor  market.  Quite  the  contrary,  the  thrust  of  the  social  democratic  project 98  Pontusson is  to  bring  people  into  the  labor  market  and  then  to  empower  them  as  sellers of  labor  power.  In  a  sense  the  concept  of  decommodification  is  more  appli¬ cable  to  policies  associated  with  Christian  democracy  and  other  strands  of traditional  conservatism  on  the  European  continent  (including  the  Mediter¬ ranean  countries):  employment  protection,  early  exit  from  work,  and  policies designed  to  keep  women  in  the  role  of  homemakers. From  a  social  democratic  perspective  the  empowerment  of  workers  as sellers  of  labor  depends  not  only  on  the  existence  of  a  finely  meshed  social safety  net  but  also  on  full  employment,  access  to  education  (skills),  and  union representation.  These  should  be  considered  core  components  of  the  social democratic  project.  My  discussion  also  suggests  that  egalitarianism  repre¬ sents  a  more  prominent  feature  of  Nordic  social  democracy  than  Esping- Andersen’s  seminal  interpretation  recognized. As  indicated  above,  rejection  of  the  idea  of  a  trade-off  between  equality and  efficiency  is  a  defining  feature  of  Nordic  social  democracy.  In  this  re¬ gard  I  want  to  emphasize  that  the  main  intellectual  tradition  of  Nordic  social democracy  conceives  “economic  efficiency”  in  terms  that  are  quite  consis¬ tent  with  mainstream  economics.  At  least  as  I  understand  them,  Nordic  so¬ cial  democrats  do  not  deny  that  egalitarianism  might  conflict  with  efficiency. Their  core  claim  is  rather  that  it  is  possible  to  redistribute  income  in  ways that  also  promote  productivity  growth  and  a  more  efficient  allocation  of  re¬ sources. Social  Democracy  and  Varieties  of  Capitalism The  question  of  why  social  democratic  ideas  have  been  particularly  influ¬ ential  in  the  Nordic  countries  lies  well  beyond  the  scope  of  this  chapter,  but I  want  to  briefly  address  the  related  question  of  the  extent  to  which  social democratic  policies  presuppose  a  particular  type  of  capitalism.  Specifically, I  wish  to  question— or  at  least  qualify— what  I  take  to  be  an  implication  of the  VofC  literature,  namely  that  the  institutional  framework  characteristic  of “coordinated  market  economies”  (CMEs)  constitutes  a  precondition  for  suc¬ cessful  social  democracy.6 According  to  the  VofC  literature,  encompassing  and  organizationally  co¬ herent  (more  or  less  centralized)  unions  and  employer  organizations  are  an important  part  of  what  distinguishes  coordinated  market  economies  from liberal  market  economies,  but  the  distinction  between  these  two  types  of capitalism  ultimately  hinges  on  corporate  finance  and  ownership  (cf.  Soskice 1999;  Hall  and  Soskice  2001).  Coordinated  market  economies  are  first  distin¬ guished  by  limited  firm  exposure  to  capital  markets,  with  banks  providing Once  Again  a  Model  99 long-term  finance  to  the  corporate  sector  and  ownership  being  concentrated in  the  hands  of  a  few  long-term  stakeholders.  Cross-share  holdings  among firms  are  also  common  in  coordinated  market  economies,  protecting  firms against  volatile  capital  markets  and  the  threat  of  hostile  takeovers  while  also providing  the  basis  for  coordination  among  firms. We  can  distinguish  several  arguments  that  construe  the  dynamics  of  co¬ ordinated  market  economies  as  supportive  of  social  democracy— and  con¬ versely,  construe  “stock-market  capitalism”  as  a  force  working  against  social democratic  policies.  To  begin  with,  patient  capital  arguably  allows  firms  to provide  long-term  employment  for  their  employees,  and  long-term  employ¬ ment  in  turn  provides  the  basis  for  trust  and  employees’  commitment  to  the success  of  the  firm.  Partly  as  a  result  of  cooperative  labor  relations  within firms,  the  comparative  advantage  of  CMEs  lies  in  the  production  of  industrial goods  of  high  quality.  Their  production  strategies  in  turn  allow  for  the  high wages  and  taxes  upon  which  the  social  democratic  project  depends.  They  may also  allow  for  the  compression  of  wage  differentials.  More  specifically,  as  we have  already  seen,  recent  contributions  to  the  VofC  literature  argue  that  reli¬ ance  on  specific  skills  makes  employers  in  coordinated  market  economies interested  in  employment  protection  and  generous  social  insurance  schemes. These  arguments  pertain  to  the  congruence  of  social  democratic  policies with  the  production  strategies  of  dominant  business  segments.  In  a  different vein,  one  might  also  argue  that  the  effective  implementation  of  social  demo¬ cratic  policies  depends  on  the  cooperation  of  organized  business  as  well  as organized  labor  or,  in  other  words,  that  the  effective  implementation  of  these policies  presupposes  “corporatist”  institutional  arrangements.  From  this  per¬ spective  firms  in  liberal  market  economies  might  stand  to  gain  from  social democratic  policies,  but  they  do  not  have  the  capacity  to  help  governments implement  these  policies  (e.g.,  Martin  2004). For  the  VofC  literature,  then,  social  democracy  does  not  represent  a  viable policy  regime  for  liberal  market  economies,  while  its  prospects  in  coordi¬ nated  market  economies  are  quite  favorable.  At  the  same  time  the  VofC  litera¬ ture  argues  strenuously  against  the  proposition  that  capital  mobility  and  in¬ tensified  international  competition  favor  LMEs  over  CMEs.  The  standard  VofC argument  on  this  score  is  that  the  institutional  differences  between  CMEs  and LMEs  are  the  source  of  different  comparative  advantages:  CME  firms  and  LME firms  pursue  different  innovation  and  production  strategies,  but  these  strate¬ gies  are  equally  viable.  Rather  than  generate  pressures  for  convergence  on the  liberal  model,  globalization  actually  serves  to  crystallize  differences  be¬ tween  the  two  types  of  capitalist  economies  (Soskice  1999). In  my  view  the  implications  of  capital  mobility  and  the  globalization  of ioo  Pontusson finance  over  the  last  two  decades  are  more  far-reaching  than  VofC  scholars typically  recognize.  On  average,  European  firms  may  still  be  less  exposed to  capital  markets  than  American  firms  are,  but  ownership  structures  and corporate  governance  practices  have  clearly  shifted  in  a  “liberal”  direction across  the  coordinated  market  economies.  In  addition,  the  VofC  argument about  comparative  advantage  is  strikingly  manufacturing-centered  and ignores  the  macroeconomic  implications  of  differential  growth  rates  across industrial  sectors.7  CME  firms  specializing  in  “incremental  innovation”  may well  be  able  to  thrive  in  the  new  world  economy,  but  if  sectors  in  which  com¬ petition  hinges  on  “radical  innovation”  grow  at  a  much  faster  rate,  this  surely poses  a  problem  for  countries  that  have  a  comparative  advantage  in  incre¬ mental  innovation. On  the  other  hand,  I  want  to  suggest  that  the  VofC  literature  exaggerates the  extent  to  which  the  fate  of  social  democracy  is  tied  to  the  persistence  of “patient  capital”  and  manufacturing  systems  that  rely  on  the  kinds  of  skills that  workers  acquire  through  vocational  training  of  the  sort  given  in  Ger¬ many.  As  noted  above,  what  distinguishes  the  Nordic  countries  in  the  realm of  education  and  skill  formation  is  not  vocational  training  but  rather  pub¬ lic  investment  in  human  capital  in  a  much  broader  sense.  Such  investment facilitates  productivity  growth  across  a  wide  range  of  business  activities,  and more  footloose  or  short-term  investors  should  be  quite  readily  able  to  recog¬ nize  its  benefits.  The  same  basic  argument  holds,  it  seems  to  me,  for  other components  of  the  social  democratic  policy  regime,  notably  the  promotion  of women’s  participation  in  the  labor  force,  the  emphasis  on  getting  the  unem¬ ployed  back  to  work,  and  the  mobility-enhancing  implications  of  universal- istic  social  insurance  schemes.  As  for  wage  solidarity,  let  me  simply  reiterate that  it  is  a  policy  designed  to  benefit  any  and  all  firms  with  above-average profits.  In  short,  I  fail  to  see  any  compelling  reason  why  the  economic  and social  benefits  of  social  democratic  policies  should  be  more  pronounced  in coordinated  market  economies  than  in  liberal  market  economies. The  proposition  that  the  effective  implementation  of  social  democratic policies  presupposes  institutional  arrangements  of  the  CME  type  cannot  be as  readily  dismissed.  Solidaristic  wage  bargaining  and  active  labor  market policies  surely  require  participation  and  coordination  by  employers  as  well as  unions.  While  this  is  less  obviously  so  for  other  components  of  the  social democratic  policy  regime,  such  as  parental  leave  insurance  and  public  spend¬ ing  on  primary  and  secondary  education,  the  notion  of  a  “policy  regime” implies  interdependence  among  different  policies.  However,  the  argument about  institutional  capacity  has  more  to  do  with  encompassing  unions  and employer  associations  than  with  corporate  finance  and  governance  institu- Once  Again  a  Model  101 Table  2.  Unionization  Rates,  1980  and  2000 1980 2000 Change LME  average 43 27 -16 United  States 22 13 -9 Continental  average 35 23 -12 Belgium 54 56 2 Germany 35 25 -10 Nordic  average 72 71 -1 Denmark 79 74 -5 Finland 69 76 7 Norway 58 54 -4 Sweden 80 79 -1 Note:  Continental  average  excludes  Belgium;  otherwise countries  included  in  group  averages  are  the  same  as  in table  1  (columns  1-5). Source:  OECD  2008b,  24-25,  34-35. tions.  Historically  the  concentration  of  ownership  and  capitalists  with  inter¬ ests  in  a  number  of  different  firms  may  have  been  a  precondition  for  the emergence  of  relatively  centralized  employer  and  trade  associations  in  north¬ ern  Europe,  but  it  does  not  follow  that  recent  changes  in  the  structure  of ownership  and  control  undermine  existing  corporatist  arrangements. Even  more  so  than  strong  business  organizations,  strong  unions  must  be considered  an  institutional  prerequisite  for  successful  social  democracy.  By “union  strength”  I  have  in  mind  both  high  levels  of  unionization  and  an  or¬ ganizational  structure  that  makes  coordination  among  unions  possible.  The latter  feature  is  not  adequately  captured  by  centralization  of  authority  in the  hands  of  national  union  officials.  Union  strength  involves  limits  on  the autonomy  of  locals  and  shop  stewards  but  also,  perhaps  more  importantly, clear  jurisdictional  boundaries  and  the  absence  of  inter-union  competition over  members.  As  emphasized  by  Kjellberg  (1983),  Nordic  unions  are  distin¬ guished  by  strong  locals  as  well  as  strong  peak  associations. Strong  and  coordinated  industrial  unions  are  clearly  critical  to  the  imple¬ mentation  of  solidaristic  wage  policy.  Here  I  want  to  emphasize  the  less  com¬ monly  recognized  point  that  strong  local  unions  have  made  it  possible  for Nordic  social  democrats  to  eschew  detailed  government  regulation  of  em¬ ployment  and  working  conditions,  instead  relying  on  local  unions  to  protect workers  in  this  realm.  I  have  yet  to  puzzle  through  the  micro-foundations  of this  argument,  but  I  am  strongly  inclined  to  believe  that  collective  bargain¬ ing  provides  a  more  flexible  path  to  employment  security  than  government 102  Pontusson legislation  and  that  reliance  on  this  method  attenuates  the  trade-off  between employment  security  and  employment  growth. Does  union  strength  ultimately  depend  on  the  broader  (or  deeper)  institu¬ tional  conditions  emphasized  by  the  VofC  literature?  Leaving  aside  Belgium, average  union  density  in  continental  SMEs  was  actually  lower  than  in  Anglo¬ phone  LMEs  in  1980  and  fell  by  nearly  as  much  over  the  last  two  decades  of the  twentieth  century  (see  table  2).  It  is  possible  that  some  of  the  institutional features  of  continental  SMEs  actually  contributed  to  union  decline.  The  prac¬ tice  of  extending  bargained  wage  contracts  to  firms  (or  workers)  that  were not  party  to  the  contract  poses  the  obvious  question  of  why  workers  would choose  to  join  unions  in  these  countries.  Similarly,  employment  protection legislation  and  works  councils  would  seem  to  deprive  unions  of  an  important role  at  the  local  level.  Here  is  another  complementarity  (or  “virtuous  circle”) that  deserves  to  be  noted:  the  social  democratic  policy  regime  depends  on strong  unions,  but  it  also  sustains  strong  unions.8 Economic  Growth  and  Social  Solidarity,  1995-2007 As  Martin  and  Thelen  (2007)  have  recently  asserted,  using  Denmark  and  Ger¬ many  as  illustrative  cases,  the  trajectories  of  the  Nordic  countries  and  con¬ tinental  Europe  have  diverged  since  the  early  1990s.  Economic  growth  and cooperation  between  unions  and  employers  have  been  restored  and  social solidarity  has  been  maintained  in  the  Nordic  countries.  By  contrast,  Martin and  Thelen  observe  an  erosion  of  social-market  institutions  and  rising  labor- market  dualism  in  Germany  and  other  continental  countries.  In  what  follows I  will  elaborate  on  this  divergence  and  relate  it  to  my  earlier  discussion. To  begin  with,  table  3  brings  out  the  contrast  between  the  Nordic  coun¬ tries  and  continental  Europe  with  respect  to  overall  economic  performance. To  summarize,  the  Danish,  Norwegian,  and  Swedish  economies  have  grown by  an  average  annual  rate  of  about  3%  per  capita  while  the  Finnish  econ¬ omy  has  grown  by  an  annual  rate  of  nearly  4%  since  the  end  of  the  eco¬ nomic  crisis  of  the  early  1990s.  For  Finland  and  Sweden  in  particular,  but  also for  Denmark,  this  represents  a  strong  improvement  on  the  1980s  and  early 1990s,  when  Nordic  growth  — except  for  Norway,  which  benefited  from  oil  ex¬ ports— lagged  behind  not  only  the  United  States  but  also  continental  Europe by  a  significant  margin.  Over  the  thirteen  years  from  1995  through  2007  even Denmark,  which  grew  more  slowly  than  the  other  Nordic  countries,  grew at  the  same  rate  as  the  average  for  Anglophone  LMEs  (slightly  higher  than the  United  States  growth  rate)  and  outperformed  the  average  for  continental SMEs  by  one  percentage  point  per  year.9 Once  Again  a  Model 103 Table  3.  Average  Annual  Growth  Rate  of  Real  GDP  per  Capita 1984-94 1995-2007 LME  average 2.8 2.9 Ireland 4.0 7.5 United  States 3.0 2.8 Continental  average 2.3 1.9 Germany 2.8 1.5 Nordic  average 1.9 3.2 Denmark 2.0 2.9 Finland 1.2 3.8 Norway 2.8 3.1 Sweden 1.4 3.1 Note:  Countries  included  in  group  averages  are  the  same  as  in table  1  (columns  1-5),  except  that  lme  average  excludes  Ireland. Source:  OECD  2008a,  249. Like  the  rest  of  Western  Europe,  the  Nordic  countries  have  relied  heavily on  productivity  growth  to  achieve  economic  growth,  and  employment  growth has  been  sluggish.  In  Sweden  and  Finland  unemployment  remains  much higher  than  it  was  before  the  economic  crisis  of  the  early  1990s.  Without minimizing  this  problem,  which  was  the  main  reason  why  the  Swedish  social democrats  lost  the  election  of  2006,  it  is  noteworthy  that  Sweden  and  Finland managed  to  avoid  the  pattern  of  Germany  and  other  continental  SMEs  from the  mid-1970s  through  the  mid-1990s,  when  each  successive  recession  was associated  with  a  ratcheting  up  of  the  “equilibrium  rate”  of  unemployment. In  Sweden  open  unemployment  jumped  from  1.2%  in  1991  to  9.9%  but  subse¬ quently  fell  back,  fluctuating  in  the  range  of  5  to  7%  between  2001  and  2007. In  Finland  the  rate  of  unemployment  peaked  at  15.1%  in  1995  and  fluctuated between  7%  and  9%  in  2001-7.  It  also  deserves  to  be  noted  that  Norway  and Denmark  have  successfully  maintained  very  low  rates  of  unemployment  over the  last  ten  years,  significantly  below  the  United  States  rate,  let  alone  the  EU rate.10  Perhaps  most  importantly,  economic  growth  has  been  accompanied  by a  very  significant  reduction  in  the  duration  of  average  unemployment  spells in  the  Nordic  countries  since  the  mid-1990s  (see  table  8). Nordic  economic  success  over  the  last  ten  to  fifteen  years  has  occurred  in the  context  of  a  continued  shift  to  services  as  the  principal  source  of  employ¬ ment.  As  table  4  illustrates,  the  continental  SMEs  experienced  the  biggest shift  toward  a  postindustrial  employment  structure  in  the  1990s  and  early 2000s,  but  the  Nordic  economies  had  gone  farther  down  this  path  by  the  late 1980s  and  the  Nordic  economies  remained  more  postindustrial  than  the  con- 104  Pontusson Table  4.  Services  as  Percentage  of  Total  Civilian Employment,  1991-2007 1991 2007 Change LME  average 68.1 74.7 6.6 United  States 71.8 78.8 7.0 Continental  average 60.5 71.2 10.7 Germany 55.0 67.7 12.7 Nordic  average 67.0 73.9 6.9 Denmark 66.6 73.6 7.0 Finland 62.3 69.7 7.4 Norway 70.5 76.0 5.5 Sweden 68.4 76.1 7.7 Note:  Countries  included  in  group  averages  are  the same  as  in  table  1  (columns  1-5). Source:  OECD  2008b,  24-25,  34-35. tinental  SMEs  by  the  end  of  the  recent  boom.  The  continued  shift  to  service employment  is  particularly  noteworthy  because  the  public  sector’s  share  of total  employment  has  either  contracted  or  remained  constant  in  the  Nordic countries  since  the  early  1990s. By  all  accounts  the  embrace  of  information-processing  and  communica¬ tion  technologies  was  a  very  important  component  of  economic  recovery  in Sweden  and  Finland  in  the  1990s.  Alongside  the  rise  of  Ericsson  and  Nokia  as global  ICT  firms,  these  countries  have  become  home  to  clusters  of  smaller  ICT companies  (Richards  2004).  Relatedly,  the  spread  of  ICT  use  across  manufac¬ turing  and  public  as  well  as  private  services  appears  to  have  been  an  impor¬ tant  factor  behind  rapid  productivity  growth  not  only  in  Sweden  and  Finland but  also  in  Denmark  and  Norway. For  1995-2006  table  5  reports  on  annual  growth  of  value  added  in  four broad  sectors:  (1)  low-technology  manufacturing,  (2)  high  and  medium-to- high  (hmh)  technology  manufacturing,  (3)  finance  and  business  services, and  (4)  other  private  services.11  As  the  table  indicates,  the  United  States  out¬ performed  Germany  and  the  average  for  continental  SMEs  in  every  one  of these  sectors,  but  the  performance  gap  was  particularly  pronounced  for  HMH manufacturing  and  other  private  services.  Interestingly,  HMH  manufactur¬ ing  and  other  private  services  are  also  the  two  sectors  in  which  Sweden  and Finland  clearly  outperformed  the  continental  SMEs  in  this  period.  The  very strong  performance  of  these  countries  in  HMH  manufacturing,  with  growth rates  one  and  a  half  times  the  United  States  rate,  is  particularly  striking.  It Once  Again  a  Model  105 Table  5.  Average  Annual  Growth  of  Value  Added  by  Sector,  1996-2006 High  and Medium-  Financial Low- Technology Manufacturing a to-High- Technology Manufacturing11 and Business Services' Other Private Services'1 United  States 1.1 6.0 3.7 4.5 Continental  average' 0.7 3.4 2.8 2.4 Germany 0.4 1.0 3.5 2.1 Denmark -1.0 1.7 2.9 3.1 Finland 2.5 9.1 2.5 4.7 Norway 1.0 1.5 4.3 4.2 Sweden 0.9 9.1 3.2 4.0 a  Food  products,  beverages,  tobacco,  wood  and  wood  products,  pulp  and  paper  products,  print¬ ing  and  publishing,  other  manufacturing  and  recycling. b  Chemicals  and  chemical  products,  machinery  and  equipment,  transport  equipment. 'Finance,  insurance,  real  estate,  and  business  services  (computer  and  related  activities,  research and  development,  renting  of  machinery  and  equipment,  etc.). d  Wholesale  and  retail  trade,  restaurants  and  hotels,  transportation,  storage,  and  communica¬ tions. 'Same  countries  as  in  table  1  (columns  1-5). Source:  OECD,  STAN  Structural  Analysis  Database,  version  2008  (http: //stats. oecd.org/). is  also  noteworthy  that  all  four  Nordic  countries  enjoyed  stronger  output growth  than  the  continental  SMEs  in  a  wide  range  of  private  services. The  emergence  of  the  Nordic  countries  as  models  of  how  high-wage  coun¬ tries  can  meet  the  challenges  of  globalization  by  shifting  to  more  knowledge- intensive  manufacturing  and  service  production  is  reflected  in  recent  reports by  the  World  Economic  Forum  (WEF).  According  to  the  forum’s  most  recent report  on  information-age  preparedness  (released  in  April  2008),  Denmark is  the  most  “networked  economy”  in  the  world,  followed  by  Sweden  in  sec¬ ond  place,  Finland  in  sixth  place,  and  Norway  in  tenth  place.  On  the  forum’s broader  index  of  global  competitiveness,  Denmark,  Sweden,  and  Finland ranked  third,  fourth,  and  fifth  in  2008.  By  contrast,  continental  SMEs  other than  Switzerland  are  notably  absent  from  the  top-ten  list  on  both  WEF  in¬ dexes.12 The  WEF  rankings  take  into  account  the  regulatory  environment  as  well  as the  quality  of  human  capital,  infrastructure,  and  government  support  for  re¬ search  and  development.  It  is  commonplace  in  OECD  publications  to  attribute the  recent  successes  of  the  Nordic  economies  to  deregulatory,  liberalizing  re¬ forms  undertaken  in  the  1980s  and  1990s  (e.g.,  OECD  2007a).  Let  me  briefly io  6  Pontusson illustrate  the  kinds  of  reforms  involved  here  with  reference  to  Sweden.  To begin  with,  the  Swedish  social  democrats  engaged  in  deregulation  of  capital markets  and  financial  services  on  a  scale  quite  similar  to  Mrs.  Thatcher’s  “Big Bang”  in  the  second  half  of  the  1980s.  By  all  accounts  this  reform  contributed to  the  ensuing  assets  bubble  and  the  banking  crisis  of  1991-92,  but  it  also seems  to  have  improved  access  to  capital  for  Swedish  firms  — and  certainly had  important  consequences  for  the  ownership  and  governance  of  Swedish business.  Foreign  capital  entered  on  a  massive  scale  through  the  foreign  ac¬ quisition  of  Swedish  firms  as  well  as  portfolio  investment  in  the  1990s  (Hen- rekson  and  Jakobsson  2005). In  eliminating  a  variety  of  tax  expenditures  while  lowering  the  nominal rate  of  profits  taxation,  the  Swedish  tax  reform  of  1990  was  also  inspired  by market-liberal  thinking.  Less  commonly  noted,  the  social  democrats  presided over  a  comprehensive  dismantling  of  price  supports  and  other  regulations of  agriculture  in  1990.  Furthermore,  successive  Swedish  governments  in  the 1980s  and  1990s  enacted  measures  that  effectively  broke  up  public  utilities and  telecommunications  monopolies  and  partially  privatized  the  ownership of  relevant  state  enterprises.  Across  the  entire  range  of  markets  for  manufac¬ tured  goods  and  private  services,  government  reforms  have  sought  to  encour¬ age  competition  and  entrepreneurship. With  Norway  as  something  of  a  laggard,  the  other  Nordic  countries  have engaged  in  similar  deregulatory  reforms.  A  systematic  comparative  analysis lies  far  beyond  the  scope  of  this  chapter,  but  I  doubt  that  anyone  would  con¬ test  the  proposition  that  Sweden,  Denmark,  and  Finland  have  embraced  and implemented  the  deregulation  of  capital  markets,  product  markets,  and  pri¬ vate  services  to  a  considerably  greater  extent  than  continental  SMEs  like  Ger¬ many  and  France.13 The  Nordic  countries  reduced  the  income  replacement  provided  by  vari¬ ous  social  insurance  programs  and  also  cut  spending  on  public  services  in  the early  1990s,  but  reforms  of  the  welfare  state  were  far  more  circumscribed than  the  deregulatory  reforms  enumerated  above.  Budgetary  pressures  rather than  market-liberal  ideas  clearly  constituted  the  primary  motivation  behind these  reforms,  and  spending  cuts  were  restored  as  economic  growth  picked up  in  the  second  half  of  the  1990s.  Under  the  umbrella  of  “flexicurity,”  Den¬ mark  reformed  its  system  of  unemployment  support  in  the  1990s,  restrict¬ ing  the  duration  of  passive  income  support  while  expanding  the  rights  of the  long-term  unemployed  to  individually  tailored  retraining  (Madsen  2002), but  this  reform  can  hardly  be  described  as  “market-liberal.”  To  the  contrary, it  represents  an  embrace  of  the  principles  of  Swedish  active  labor  market policy.  Other  social  policy  reforms  can  also  be  said  to  have  shored  up  existing Once  Again  a  Model  107 welfare  states.  Perhaps  most  importantly,  it  is  striking  that  after  two  decades of  reform,  public  monopolies  in  the  provision  of  education,  healthcare,  child¬ care,  and  elderly  care  remain  effectively  intact  in  the  Nordic  countries. The  trajectory  of  Nordic  political  economies  might  thus  be  characterized as  one  of  far-reaching  but  targeted  or  “asymmetric”  liberalization,  as  dis¬ tinct  from  the  across-the-board  liberalization  of  Thatcher’s  Britain.  As  I  have emphasized  throughout  this  chapter,  the  asymmetric  embrace  of  markets  in some  realms  and  rejection  of  market  solutions  in  other  realms  has  long  been a  hallmark  of  Nordic  social  democracy.  With  the  benefit  of  hindsight,  the  de- regulatory  reforms  enumerated  above  may  have  been  an  essential  part  of  the political  process  that  enabled  the  social  democrats  to  regain  their  capacity  to define  the  terms  of  economic  and  social  policy  debate.  At  the  same  time,  it seems  plausible  to  argue  that  the  Nordic  countries  have  been  able  to  engage in  far-reaching  deregulation  precisely  because  their  citizens  enjoy  generous, publicly  provided  welfare  provisions  that  render  them  less  sensitive  to  the fate  of  the  companies  in  which  they  work.  In  other  words,  the  Nordic  experi¬ ence  of  the  last  couple  of  decades  suggests  that  the  compensatory  logic  of social  welfare  articulated  by  Katzenstein  (1985)  applies  to  domestic  liberal¬ ization  as  well  as  trade  liberalization. Released  shortly  before  the  election  of  2006,  a  report  on  the  Swedish  econ¬ omy  by  a  team  of  American  and  Swedish  economists  (Freeman,  Swedenborg, and  Topel  eds.  2006)  concluded  that  “excessive  egalitarianism”  remained  a drag  on  economic  growth  and  that  the  economic  boom  provided  a  favorable environment  for  allowing  income  differentials  to  rise.  By  contrast,  I  suggest that  the  egalitarianism  of  the  Nordic  countries  has  contributed  positively  to their  economic  success  since  the  early  1990s.  As  I  see  it,  three  mechanisms are  at  work.  First,  coordinated  wage  bargaining  with  strong  unions  has  lim¬ ited  wage  differentials  resulting  from  corporate  profitability  and  kept  pres¬ sure  on  firms  to  improve  productivity.  Even  within  the  private  service  sec¬ tor,  the  logic  of  the  Rehn-Meidner  model  still  seems  to  work.14  Indeed,  it  is tempting  to  argue  that  the  shift  from  peak-level  to  industry-level  wage  bar¬ gaining  has  reduced  the  need  for  unions  in  the  Nordic  countries  to  pursue inter-occupational  leveling  and  hence  enabled  them  to  pursue  wage  policies based  more  exclusively  on  Rehn-Meidner  principles. Second,  there  can  be  little  doubt  that  high  levels  of  public  investment  in families  and  education  since  the  1970s  (or  earlier)  contributed  to  the  strong performance  of  the  Nordic  economies  in  the  1990s  and  2000s,  and  especially to  the  growth  of  more  knowledge-intensive  sectors.  The  broad  base  of  gen¬ eral  skills— or  in  other  words,  the  relatively  high  level  of  general  skills  at the  bottom  of  the  skill  distribution  — clearly  represents  the  distinctive  ad- io8  Pontusson vantage  of  the  Nordic  countries,  not  only  in  allowing  for  the  use  of  informa¬ tion  technology  in  the  production  of  goods  and  services  but  also  in  making for  more  sophisticated  consumers  of  ICT  products.  As  noted  earlier  (table  l), “information-age  literacy”  is  more  widespread  in  the  Nordic  countries  than in  any  other  OECD  countries. Finally,  the  Nordic  economies  have  benefited  in  more  or  less  tangible  ways from  high  levels  of  female  labor  force  participation  and  gender  equality. Though  I  have  no  quantitative  evidence  on  this  score,  the  large-scale  entry  of women  into  managerial  positions  in  the  corporate  sector  represents  an  im¬ portant  new  development  in  the  Nordic  countries  over  the  last  two  decades. There  is  every  reason  to  suppose  that  the  quality  of  management  improves  as the  pool  of  potential  managers  increases. The  final  contrast  that  I  want  to  draw  between  Nordic  and  continental  tra¬ jectories  since  the  early  1990s  concerns  labor-market  dualism.  The  growth of  precarious  forms  of  employment  and  conflicts  of  interest  between  labor insiders  and  outsiders  has  recently  emerged  as  a  prominent  theme  in  the comparative  political  economy  of  advanced  industrial  states.  While  King  and Rueda  (2008)  treat  dualist  tendencies  as  a  common  feature  of  all  OECD  coun¬ tries,  others  (e.g.,  Iversen  and  Stephens  2008,  605)  conceive  growing  dualism as  a  distinctively  continental  European  phenomenon.  In  the  latter  vein  Palier and  Thelen  (2010)  argue  that  growing  labor-market  dualism  in  France  and Germany  is  a  result  of  the  distinctive  political  dynamics  of  labor-market  and social  policy  reforms  in  these  countries. Tables  6-9  present  some  preliminary  evidence  in  support  of  the  proposi¬ tion  that  dualist  tendencies  have  been  less  pronounced  in  the  Nordic  coun¬ tries  than  in  continental  Europe  over  the  last  ten  to  fifteen  years.  To  begin with,  table  6  reports  on  the  percentage  of  the  labor  force  employed  under fixed-term  contracts.  In  the  mid-1990s  fixed-term  contracts  were  more  com¬ mon  in  the  Nordic  countries  than  in  Germany  and  the  continental  SMEs  as a  group.  However,  the  incidence  of  fixed-term  employment  declined  in  the Nordic  countries  (except  for  Sweden)  while  it  increased  on  the  European  con¬ tinent  in  the  late  1990s  and  early  2000s.  In  this  respect  the  Nordic  experience seems  to  resemble  the  experience  of  the  United  States  more  than  that  of  con¬ tinental  Europe. Part-time  employment  is  commonly  viewed  as  another  form  of  precari¬ ous  employment  (e.g.,  King  and  Rueda  2008).  As  shown  in  table  7,  part-time workers  as  a  proportion  of  all  workers  increased  very  markedly  in  Germany from  1994  to  2007.  The  incidence  of  part-time  employment  also  increased  in the  other  continental  SMEs  over  this  period,  but  it  declined  in  Sweden  and Norway,  as  in  the  United  States,  and  remained  constant  in  Denmark.  Start- Table  6.  Fixed-Term  Employment  as  Percentage  of Total  Labor  Force,  1994-2002 1994 2002 Change LME  average 8.1 7.1 -1.0 United  States 5.1 4.0 -1.1 Continental  average 9.3 11.3 2.0 Germany 10.3 12.0 1.7 Nordic  average 14.5 12.4 -2.1 Denmark 12.0 8.9 -3.1 Finland 18.3 16.1 -2.2 Norway 12.9 9.9 -3.0 Sweden 14.6 14.8 0.2 Note:  LME  average  excludes  Australia;  otherwise  coun¬ tries  included  in  group  averages  are  the  same  as  in  table  1 (columns  1-5).  Figures  in  column  1  are  from  1997  for  Fin¬ land  and  Sweden,  1996  for  Norway. Source:  OECD  Labour  Market  Statistics  Database  (down¬ loaded  and  compiled  by  David  Rueda). Table  7.  Part-Time  Employment  as  Percentage  of Employed  Population,  1994-2007 1994 2007 Change LME  average 17.3 18.6 1.3 United  States 14.2 12.6 -1.6 Continental  average 18.8 28.8 10.0 Germany 13.5 22.2 8.7 Nordic  average 15.9 16.1 0.2 Denmark 17.3 17.7 0.4 Finland 8.9 11.7 2.8 Norway 21.5 20.4 -1.1 Sweden 15.8 14.4 -1.4 Note:  Part-time  employment  defined  as  less  than  30  hours per  week  in  one’s  main  job.  For  lack  of  data  for  1994,  LME average  excludes  Australia  and  continental  average  ex¬ cludes  Austria;  otherwise  countries  included  in  group  aver¬ ages  are  the  same  as  in  table  1  (columns  1-5). Source:  OECD  2008c,  352. no  Pontusson Table  8.  Long-Term  Unemployment  (More Than  6  Months)  as  Percentage  of  Total Unemployment,  1994-2007 1994 2007 Change LME  average 49.9 30.2 -19.7 United  States 20.3 17.6 -2.7 Continental  average 60.0 60.1 0.1 Germany 63.8 71.3 7.5 Nordic  average 48.1 27.3 -20.8 Denmark 54.0 29.5 -24.5 Finland 37.9 Norway 43.7 25.1 -18.6 Sweden 46.7 27.3 -19.4 Note:  To  capture  change  over  time,  Nordic  average  ex¬ cludes  Finland;  otherwise  the  countries  included  in  group averages  are  the  same  as  table  1  (columns  1-5). Source:  OECD  2008c,  355. Table  9.  Incidence  of  Low  Pay,  1994-2004 1994 1996 1997 1999 2002 2003 2004 United  States 25.1 23.3 United  Kingdom 19.5 21.4 Germany 11.6 15.8 Netherlands 11.9 14.8 Denmark Finland Sweden 7.3 5.7 7.3 9.3 6.4 Note:  Figures  represent  percentage  of  full-time  employees  earning  less  than  two-thirds  of  the median  wage  for  full-time  employees. Source:  OECD  Relative  Earnings  Database. ing  at  a  much  lower  level,  Finland  is  the  only  Nordic  country  that  conforms to  the  continental  European  pattern  with  respect  to  the  growth  of  part-time employment. Trends  in  the  incidence  of  long-term  unemployment  constitute  another point  of  contrast  between  the  Nordic  countries  and  continental  Europe  that is  relevant  to  the  theme  of  labor-market  dualism.  Table  8  reports  on  the  per¬ centage  of  the  unemployed  who  have  been  unemployed  for  more  than  six months.  During  the  economic  crisis  of  the  early  1990s  this  figure  shot  up  in the  Nordic  countries,  but  it  never  quite  reached  continental  levels,  and  it  has Once  Again  a  Model  ill subsequently  been  more  or  less  halved  in  Denmark,  Norway,  and  Sweden (with  data  for  the  mid-1990s  missing  for  Finland).  Again,  the  contrast  with continental  Europe  is  striking.  In  Germany  the  incidence  of  long-term  unem¬ ployment  rose  dramatically  while  the  overall  unemployment  rate  held  more or  less  steady  from  1994  to  2007.  Averaging  across  six  continental  SMEs,  the incidence  of  long-term  unemployment  remained  constant  while  the  overall unemployment  rate  dropped. Finally,  table  9  presents  some  fragmentary  data  on  the  incidence  of  low- pay  employment,  defined  here  as  the  percentage  of  full-time  workers  earn¬ ing  less  than  two-thirds  of  the  median  wage.  The  evidence  suggests  that  the low-pay  labor  force  has  grown  in  the  Nordic  countries  as  well  as  continental Europe,  but  the  increases  in  Denmark  and  Sweden  are  notably  smaller  than those  observed  in  Germany  and  the  Netherlands.  As  the  incidence  of  low-pay employment  in  continental  Europe  has  begun  to  approach  levels  character¬ istic  of  liberal  market  economies,  represented  by  the  United  Kingdom  and the  United  States  in  table  9,  the  Nordic  countries  stand  out  even  more  by  this measure. It  deserves  to  be  noted  that  overall  wage  inequality  among  full-time  em¬ ployees  and  inequality  of  gross  earnings  among  working-age  households  have actually  increased  more  in  Sweden  than  in  Germany  since  the  1990s  (Pontus- son  2005a,  45).  In  Sweden  low-skilled  and  low-paid  workers  have  fared  rela¬ tively  well  while  highly  educated  workers  have  gained  relative  to  the  middle. This  pattern  of  inequality  growth,  which  resembles  that  of  liberal  market economies,  may  be  more  conducive  than  the  continental  pattern  to  the  per¬ sistence  of  a  redistributive  coalition  of  low-income  and  middle-income  voters (cf.  Lupu  and  Pontusson  2010).  For  our  purposes,  suffice  it  to  say  that  the  re¬ covery  and  successful  restructuring  of  the  Nordic  economies  over  the  last fifteen  years  have  not  brought  about  any  dramatic  increase  in  the  gap  be¬ tween  labor-market  insiders  and  outsiders.15  Relative  to  continental  SMEs, the  Nordic  economies  may  be  less  in  need  of  labor-market  dualism  because they  rely  more  extensively  on  general  skills  and  because  their  labor  markets are  more  flexible. THE  POLICY  REGIME  associated  with  Nordic  social  democracy  cannot  be captured  by  a  simple  formula  along  the  lines  of  “politics  against  markets” (Esping-Andersen  1985).  Rather,  this  policy  regime  represents  an  essentially pragmatic  approach  to  managing  contemporary  capitalism,  characterized  by a  combination  of  collective  bargaining  and  government  intervention  to  regu¬ late  labor  markets,  direct  government  provision  of  public  goods,  and  redis¬ tributive  taxes  and  incomes  transfers  to  correct  for  inequalities  generated by  markets.  Nordic  social  democrats  have  not  only  been  willing  to  concede 112  Pontusson a  lot  of  terrain  to  markets,  they  have  celebrated  the  efficiency  of  markets  as mechanisms  to  allocate  productive  resources.  The  “market-friendliness”  of social  democracy  became  more  pronounced  in  the  1980s  and  1990s,  but  it was  also  quite  pronounced  in  the  1950s  and  1960s,  and  the  generous  bound¬ aries  that  social  democratic  ideology  sets  for  market  solutions  to  societal problems  remain.  To  my  mind,  it  is  the  radical  trade-union  initiatives  of  the 1970s  (Pontusson  1992)  rather  than  the  deregulatory  reforms  and  budget¬ balancing  measures  of  the  1990s  that  represent  a  radical  break  with  the  social democratic  tradition.  In  particular,  it  is  noteworthy  that  postwar  Nordic  gov¬ ernments  pursued  quite  restrictive  fiscal  policies  (premised  on  full  employ¬ ment,  the  Rehn-Meidner  model  incorporated  this  policy  stance). What  are  the  consequences  of  the  global  economic  crisis  that  began  to unfold  in  the  fall  of  2008  for  the  social  democratic  policy  regime  as  I  have conceived  it  in  this  chapter?  A  few  brief  comments  must  suffice.  The  origins of  the  crisis  clearly  call  into  question  the  laissez-faire  approach  to  financial markets  adopted  by  Nordic  social  democrats,  along  with  just  about  all  other major  political  parties,  in  the  1980s  and  1990s.  It  also  seems  clear,  already, that  recovery  from  the  crisis  will  require  fiscal  stimulus  on  a  scale  that  ex¬ ceeds  anything  the  Nordic  countries  have  experienced  since  the  1930s.  The Nordic  countries  are  neither  immune  to  the  crisis  nor  particularly  vulnerable. Most  importantly  for  present  purposes,  the  main  policy  challenges  would seem  to  lie  outside  the  realm  of  the  social  democratic  policy  regime.  The social  democratic  policy  regime  itself  does  not  prescribe  a  particular  fiscal policy  stance,  restrictive  or  expansionary,  and  macro-economic  conditions  do not  alter  the  (desirable)  effects  of  its  core  components.  The  same  argument holds,  I  think,  with  respect  to  the  question  of  how  financial  markets  should be  regulated.  These  observations  imply  an  important  clarification  of  the  pre¬ ceding  discussion:  the  social  democratic  policy  regime  as  I  conceive  it  is  not a  comprehensive  regime  that  encompasses  all  aspects  of  economic  and  social policy. I  have  argued  that  the  social  democratic  policy  regime  remains  viable under  conditions  of  globalization  and  liberalization.  To  clarify  further,  this part  of  my  argument  pertains  specifically  to  the  political  and  economic  via¬ bility  of  the  social  democratic  policy  regime.  Throughout  this  chapter  I  have quite  deliberately  shied  away  from  the  question  of  which  conditions  will  en¬ able  parties  pursuing  social  democratic  policies  to  be  electorally  successful. As  Moschonas  (this  volume)  shows,  a  secular  decline  of  electoral  support  for mainstream  social  democratic  parties  has  occurred  across  northern  Europe over  the  last  two  or  three  decades.  The  reasons  for  this  are  complex,  but  one thing  seems  clear:  societal  demand  for  social  democratic  policies  has  not  di- Once  Again  a  Model  113 minished.  With  rising  inequality  and  employment  insecurity,  the  opposite  is surely  true.  One  might  plausibly  argue  that  the  decline  of  unions  and  other social  and  political  trends  have  diminished  the  voice  of  those  who  benefit most  from  social  democratic  policies.  The  Nordic  experience  suggests  another possibility,  namely  that  other  political  parties— other  left  parties  as  well  as centrist  and  center-right  parties— have  embraced  social  democratic  policies and  thereby  weakened  the  electoral  appeal  of  social  democratic  parties.  In my  mind  the  extent  to  which  the  social  democratic  policy  regime  depends  on electoral  mobilization  by  social  democratic  parties  is  an  open  question. In  closing,  let  me  very  briefly  address  the  question  of  the  relevance  of  the social  democratic  policy  regime  for  progressive  politics  in  the  United  States and  other  liberal  market  economies.  In  contrast  to  adherents  of  the  Varieties- of-Capitalism  school,  I  have  emphasized  in  this  chapter  that  core  policies associated  with  Nordic  social  democracy  are  broadly  conducive  to  produc¬ tivity  growth  and  benefit  more  efficient  and  knowledge-intensive  firms  across manufacturing  and  services.  In  addition,  I  have  tried  to  suggest  that  “stock- market  capitalism”  does  not  necessarily  render  these  policies  inoperative. The  pragmatic  nature  of  the  social  democratic  approach  also  deserves  to  be noted  in  this  context.  With  regard  to  wage  solidarity,  for  example,  the  social democratic  approach  does  not  prescribe  some  particular  leveling  of  wage  dif¬ ferentials  that  must  be  obtained:  any  standardization  of  wages  across  firms with  variable  profitability  is  considered  desirable. In  short,  I  believe  that  there  is  quite  a  lot  of  room  for  social  democracy  in liberal  market  economies.  At  the  same  time,  I  have  emphasized  that  the  im¬ plementation  of  solidaristic  wage  policy  and  other  components  of  the  social democratic  policy  regime  presuppose  relatively  strong  unions.  To  some  ex¬ tent  government  may  be  a  “functional  substitute”  for  strong  unions.  Most obviously,  we  might  think  of  minimum  wage  legislation  as  a  substitute  for solidaristic  wage  bargaining,  curtailing  the  extent  to  which  low  wages  subsi¬ dize  inefficient  firms.  Similarly,  government  legislation  can  obviously  provide workers  with  protection  against  unfair  dismissals  and  serve  to  enforce  occu¬ pational  health  and  safety  standards.  I  do  not  wish  to  imply  that  government should  desist  from  these  activities,  but  the  comparison  of  the  Nordic  coun¬ tries  and  continental  Europe  introduces  a  cautionary  note,  for  it  suggests  that extensive  government  regulation  of  labor  markets  and  employment  condi¬ tions  may  preempt  unionization.  Building  stronger  unions  must  surely  be  an indispensable  part  of  any  effort  to  move  economic  and  social  policies  in  the United  States  in  a  social  democratic  direction. 114  Pontusson Notes I  thank  Jim  Cronin,  George  Ross,  and  Jim  Shoch  for  their  comments  and,  above  all, their  patience.  For  help  with  table  5,  I  am  grateful  to  my  research  assistant,  Michael Becher.  Above  all,  I  am  very  much  indebted  to  Mary  O’Sullivan,  whose  criticisms forced  me  to  make  major  revisions  at  a  stage  when  I  thought  that  I  was  almost  finished with  this  paper. 1.  Perhaps  it  is  needless  to  say  that  I  use  the  term  “Nordic”  rather  than  “Scandina¬ vian”  because  I  think  that  Finland  deserves  to  be  included  among  the  countries  with a  social  democratic  policy  regime.  From  a  comparative  Nordic  perspective,  the  Finn¬ ish  experience  is  exceptional  on  at  least  two  counts:  the  country  industrialized  much later  than  in  Scandinavia,  and  political  and  ideological  struggles  on  the  left  divided  the labor  movement.  As  a  result,  the  Finnish  social  democratic  party  never  assumed  the same  position  as  its  Scandinavian  sister  parties  held  in  the  1950s  and  1960s,  yet  Finnish politics  clearly  shifted  in  a  social  democratic  direction  in  the  1970s  and  1980s.  Argu¬ ably,  policy  diffusion  among  the  Nordic  countries  contributed  to  this  development. 2.  “Liberal  market  economies”  (LMEs)  constitute  another  comparison  group  to which  the  following  discussion  will  refer.  Exemplified  by  the  United  States,  this  group also  includes  Australia,  Canada,  Ireland,  and  the  UK.  Pontusson  2005a  juxtaposes LMEs  and  SMEs  and  then  distinguishes  between  Nordic  and  continental  SMEs.  To  em¬ phasize  differences  between  Nordic  and  continental  political  economies,  I  here  reserve the  term  “social  market  economies”  (coined  by  German  Christian  Democrats  in  the 1950s)  for  continental  countries  with  comprehensive  systems  of  social  protection.  This terminological  change  is  part  of  an  effort  to  correct  what  I  now  consider  a  fundamental ambiguity  in  Inequality  and  Prosperity  (2005).  See  Pontusson  2006  for  an  earlier  “cor¬ rection”  along  similar  lines. 3.  Among  continental  welfare  states  Belgium  stands  out  as  comparable  to  the Nordic  welfare  states  in  terms  of  its  redistributive  impact.  See  Pontusson  2005a,  153- 62. 4.  Like  most  of  the  tables  that  follow,  table  1  sorts  countries  into  three  groups  and reports  group  averages  as  well  as  individual  figures  for  the  United  States,  Germany, and  the  four  Nordic  countries.  Of  course  group  averages  sometimes  hide  significant variation  within  groups:  the  main  instances  of  divergence  within  the  continental  and Nordic  groups  will  be  noted  in  the  text. 5.  See  Pontusson  1992  for  a  more  detailed  discussion  of  solidaristic  wage  policy  as a  form  of  industrial  policy. 6.  To  clarify,  the  Nordic  countries  and  the  continental  European  countries  that  I  call “social  market  economies”  are  all  (with  the  possible  exception  of  France)  “coordinated market  economies”  by  the  criteria  of  the  VofC  literature.  Japan  is  commonly  thought to  exemplify  yet  another  CME  variant. 7.  See  Pontusson  2005b  for  a  more  comprehensive  critique  of  the  VofC  approach. 8.  Rothstein  (1992)  makes  a  similar  argument  about  unemployment  insurance.  It is  hardly  a  coincidence  that  public  subsidies  to  union-administered  unemployment Once  Again  a  Model  115 funds  play  a  very  prominent  role  in  the  unemployment  insurance  systems  of  Sweden, Denmark,  and  Finland  and  that  these  countries  also  have  very  high  and  apparently resilient  rates  of  unionization.  Among  continental  SMEs  Belgium  alone  has  a  Ghent system  of  unemployment  insurance.  For  the  Nordic  countries  this  feature  represents  a very  notable  departure  from  welfare-state  universalism. 9.  Note  that  in  making  these  comparisons  I  do  not  include  Ireland  in  the  LME  aver¬ age,  for  the  simple  reason  that  Ireland  grew  at  twice  the  rate  of  any  other  country  in¬ cluded  in  table  3  during  the  1990s. 10.  At  2.6%,  the  Norwegian  unemployment  rate  was  the  lowest  of  any  OECD  country in  2007.  Three  other  countries  performed  better  than  Denmark  (3.8%)  by  this  measure: Korea,  the  Netherlands,  and  Switzerland.  The  unemployment  rates  reported  here  are standardized  rates  from  the  OECD  (2008b,  335). 11.  I  follow  OECD  convention  in  classifying  manufacturing  sectors  as  either  “low- technology”  or  “HMH.” 12.  In  2008  the  Netherlands  ranked  seventh  on  networked  readiness  while  Germany ranked  tenth  on  global  competitiveness.  For  further  details  see  http:/ywww.weforum •org. 13.  See  OECD  2007,  44,  for  comparative  data  on  product  market  regulations. 14.  By  contrast,  Iversen  and  Wren  (1998)  seem  to  posit  (for  reasons  that  I  do  not  fully understand)  that  the  logic  of  the  Rehn-Meidner  model  only  applies  to  manufacturing. 15.  The  pioneering  discussion  by  Rueda  (2007)  of  the  politics  of  insider-outsider conflict  misses  this  contrast  between  Nordic  and  continental  political  economies (which  all  score  high  on  his  measure  of  “corporatism”). Embracing  Markets,  Bonding  with  America, Trying  to  Do  Good The  Ironies  of  New  Labour James  Cronin Not  long  after  Labour  won  office  in  1997,  Tony  Blair  and  Gerhard  Schroder put  their  names  to  a  book  entitled  The  Third  Way  (Blair  and  Schroder  1999). It  was  not  destined  to  be  a  best-seller,  but  it  did  capture  the  feeling  in  the  late 1990s  that  perhaps  New  Labour  had  solved  the  problem  of  how  to  be  a  social democratic  party  in  an  era  largely  inhospitable  to  parties  and  movements  of the  left.  The  party  came  to  power  armed  with  a  supposedly  new  outlook  and program  and  it  had  ridden  its  new  message  to  an  overwhelming  electoral  vic¬ tory.  Was  New  Labour  the  future? A  decade  later  very  few  progressives,  whether  European  social  democrats or  American  liberals,  would  assign  to  New  Labour  such  a  historic  role.  The war  in  Iraq  largely  discredited  Blair’s  government  at  home  and  abroad,  and the  fallout  from  Iraq  served  to  confirm  for  many,  especially  on  the  left,  the suspicion  that  Labour  under  Blair’s  leadership  had  sold  its  soul  for  politi¬ cal  power  (Shaw  2007).  Gordon  Brown’s  tenure  was  worse,  for  although  he sought  to  separate  himself  from  what  were  seen  as  the  negatives  of  Tony Blair,  he  did  not  succeed  in  regaining  popular  support.  Brown  had  some  bad luck,  though  no  more  than  is  normal  for  a  leader,  and  he  suffered  as  the economy  collapsed  as  well,  but  these  factors  alone  cannot  account  for  the dramatic  decline  in  his,  and  the  party’s,  support.  At  least  three  other  factors would  appear  to  have  been  at  work:  Brown’s  unattractive  persona;  a  perhaps normal  but  in  this  case  unusually  rapid  shift  away  from  the  party  that  had held  power  for  over  a  decade;  and  the  quite  important  fact  that  the  Tories  had not  only  a  new  and  younger  and  more  attractive  leader  but  also  a  new  set  of policies  that  at  least  in  theory  were  much  closer  to  those  of  Labour  than  its earlier  policies  had  been. The  Ironies  of  New  Labour  117 The  effect  of  all  this  has  been  a  kind  of  amnesia  and  absence  of  context  in the  assessment  of  what  Labour  achieved  in  its  decade  in  power.  Critics  focus reasonably,  but  far  too  narrowly,  on  the  recent  defeat  or  on  the  party’s  diffi¬ culties  over  Iraq,  and  their  eagerness  to  pronounce  the  “end  of  New  Labour” suggests  an  antipathy  masking  itself  as  history.  The  newly  elected  leader,  Ed Miliband,  largely  based  his  campaign  on  the  need  to  go  beyond  New  Labour and  in  this  way  abetted  those  who  never  liked  it.  The  unfortunate  effect  is  to largely  pass  over  the  actual  record  of  Labour  in  government.  There  is  also  a tendency  to  forget  that  the  appropriate  context  for  assessing  New  Labour  is the  record  of  failure  and  frustration  that  preceded  it:  specifically,  the  eigh¬ teen  years  that  Labour  spent  in  the  wilderness  after  1979,  as  Thatcher  and  her successors  effectively  destroyed  what  Labour  had  built  over  generations  and in  the  process  transformed  the  political  landscape  in  Britain.  This  particular piece  of  forgetting  has  also  allowed  people  to  believe  that  because  Labour won  large  parliamentary  majorities  in  1997  and  again  in  2001,  the  party  was free  to  do  more  or  less  whatever  it  chose  to  do  while  in  office.  Forgetting  the context  affects  the  assessment  of  foreign  policy  as  well  and,  because  the  war in  Iraq  turned  out  so  badly,  critics  have  not  been  compelled  to  confront  the very  complicated  question  of  what  a  “progressive”  foreign  policy  would  look like  in  an  age  of  globalization,  “rogue  states,”  jihadist  terror,  and  interna¬ tional  uncertainty.  It  has  been  enough  to  denounce  what  was  done  and  those who  did  it.  Fair  enough  for  debate,  not  good  enough  as  history  or  as  political analysis,  and  quite  unhelpful  in  answering  the  perennial  but  now  especially urgent  question:  “What  is  to  be  done?” Forged  in  Adversity:  The  Making  of  New  Labour New  Labour’s  claims  to  be  new  were,  and  indeed  still  are,  sometimes  dis¬ puted.  Inevitably  the  party  in  its  current  form  bears  the  marks  of  its  origins and  its  long  history,  not  least  in  its  name.  Nevertheless  it  is  also  the  product of  a  protracted  and  systematic  effort  to  “modernize”  the  party,  to  reimagine its  vision,  to  remake  its  program,  and  to  develop  new  sources  of  support.1  The effort  was  a  response  to  the  challenges  confronting  all  social  democratic  and liberal  parties,  but  it  is  important  to  understand  just  how,  and  how  seriously, these  challenges  presented  themselves  in  Britain.  Everywhere  the  center-left was  forced  to  deal  with  the  perceived  ineffectiveness  of  Keynesian  formu¬ las  in  solving  the  economic  problems  of  the  1970s  and  1980s.  This  is  not  to say  that  Keynesian  solutions  were  by  themselves  wrong  or  their  theoreti¬ cal  underpinnings  less  firm  than  those  supporting  rival  policy  frameworks. The  point  is  that  the  conventional  wisdom  associated  with  Keynesianism  — n8  Cronin the  priority  in  policymaking  given  to  full  employment,  the  assumed  compat¬ ibility  between  large  state  expenditures  and  sustained  growth,  the  notion that  moderate  shifts  in  fiscal  and  monetary  policy  could  effectively  manage economic  problems  — ceased  to  be  compelling  and  so  came  to  be  less  widely accepted. Nowhere  did  this  process  go  further  or  have  more  devastating  effects  than in  Britain.  The  “stagflation”  of  the  1970s  was  superimposed  upon  a  pattern  of long-term  economic  decline  in  the  United  Kingdom,  and  policymakers  were asked  to  address  both  the  short-term  crisis  and  the  secular  trend.  They  failed on  both  counts,  calling  into  question  all  their  policy  nostrums  and  discredit¬ ing  mainstream,  consensually  oriented  Conservatism  as  well  as  the  Labour Party.  Labour  was  particularly  vulnerable  because  it  was  in  office  during  the period  1974-79,  the  worst  of  the  crisis,  and  so  bore  much  of  the  blame,  and because  even  while  it  was  in  office  its  policies  were  incoherent.  The  party was  deeply  split  between  the  left,  centered  increasingly  on  the  figure  of  Tony Benn,  and  those  on  a  looser  right,  though  it  is  perhaps  more  accurate  to  call them  centrists  or  simply  moderates.  The  left  wanted  more  state  ownership and  planning,  more  spending  and  taxes,  and  a  “fundamental  and  irreversible” shift  in  power  away  from  corporations  and  elites— what  together  became  the “alternative  economic  strategy.”  The  strategy  was  premised  on  withdrawal from  the  European  Community  and  the  need  to  construct  an  autarchic  “siege” economy  during  the  transition.  Centrists  within  the  party  were  more  corpo- ratist  in  approach,  keen  to  build  on  the  party’s  historic  ties  to  the  trade  unions to  craft  a  social  contract  that  would  hold  down  wages  and  prices  while  re¬ distributing  wealth  toward  the  poorest  by  increasing  “the  social  wage.”2  This was  basically  a  strategy  to  manage  the  economic  crisis  of  the  1970s  and  do some  good  for  the  least  well-off  workers  in  the  process.  Actual  policy  was decided  and  implemented  by  party  moderates,  though  the  left  won  many rhetorical  battles  and  the  unions  exercised  a  veto  over  initiatives  from  wher¬ ever  they  came.  By  1979  policy  had  failed  dramatically,  and  the  Labour  gov¬ ernment  led  by  James  Callaghan  found  itself  presiding  over  a  “winter  of  dis¬ content”  brought  on  by  a  rebellion  from  within  the  ranks  of  trade  unionists, especially  in  the  public  sector.  Pictures  of  garbage  piling  up  in  the  streets,  re¬ ports  of  graves  undug  and  of  ambulance  drivers  refusing  to  drive  the  sick  to hospitals,  paved  the  way  for  the  election  of  Margaret  Thatcher  and  a  dramatic break  with  all  the  orthodoxies  of  the  Labour  Party,  those  of  its  right  as  much as  its  left.  The  shift  away  from  Keynes  would  be  truly  seismic  in  Britain,  and it  would  be  ongoing. The  turn  away  from  Keynes  and  the  state  and  toward  the  market  was  the defining  and  enduring  feature  of  Thatcherism.  Its  “neoliberal”  program  had The  Ironies  of  New  Labour  119 enormous  effects  on  the  economy  and  society:  it  shifted  the  burden  of  taxes away  from  the  wealthy;  it  abolished  exchange  controls  and  deregulated  in¬ dustry  and  finance;  it  renounced  the  government’s  traditional  commitment to  full  employment  and  replaced  it  with  commitments  to  fiscal  orthodoxy  and the  control  of  inflation;  it  abandoned  previous  “corporatist”  policies,  accord¬ ing  to  which  key  decisions  were  discussed  with  representatives  of  industry and  the  trade  unions— instead  the  government  chose  to  confront  the  trade unions  and  restrict  the  scope  and  effectiveness  of  industrial  action.  Thatcher¬ ism  divested  the  state  of  ownership  and  hence  control  of  key  industries  and to  that  degree  gave  away  critical  levers  over  the  economy,  and  it  sold  off  the bulk  of  the  public  housing  that  half  a  century  of  progressive  urban  policy  had built. What  was  decisive  and  brilliant  about  these  moves  was  that  they  were largely  irreversible.  Once  the  state  has  given  up  control  and  ownership  over essential  industries  and  resources,  it  is  hard  or  at  least  prohibitively  expensive to  get  them  back;  once  taxes  on  the  well-to-do  are  reduced,  raising  them  again is  nearly  impossible  short  of  a  national  emergency;  once  working  people  get a  taste  of  homeownership,  they  do  not  want  to  lose  what  they  now  own;  once the  unions  have  been  reduced  in  membership  and  political  influence,  they stay  relatively  powerless.  Thatcher’s  governments  left  a  huge  legacy  that  was very  hard  to  displace,  and  it  was  this  institutional  inheritance  that  Labour was  forced  to  deal  with.  New  Labour  has  often  been  criticized  for  accept¬ ing  too  much  of  this  legacy.3  The  party’s  record  in  office,  it  followed,  would amount  to  little  more  than  a  “humane  Thatcherism”  or,  as  one  analyst  labeled it,  a  kind  of  “compensatory  neoliberalism.”4  Such  criticism,  however,  is  fun¬ damentally  and  historically  naive,  for  it  vastly  underestimates  the  weight  and durability  of  what  Thatcher  brought  about. Labour  in  Britain  also  confronted,  more  sharply  than  the  center-left  else¬ where,  a  rapidly  changing  electorate.  The  transition  from  an  industrial  to  a postindustrial  economy,  from  the  production  of  goods  to  the  provision  of  ser¬ vices,  was  more  drastic  and  abrupt  in  Britain  than  elsewhere  in  Europe  or even  in  America.  As  of  the  1960s  Britain  still  had  hundreds  of  thousands  of workers  employed  in  industries  like  mining,  textiles,  and  shipbuilding.  These were  among  the  leading  industries  of  the  first  industrial  revolution  and,  ap¬ propriately,  were  often  Victorian  in  their  use  of  technology,  their  manage¬ ment  structures,  and  their  approach  to  marketing.  They  were  old  and  destined to  disappear.  The  United  Kingdom  also  had  its  share  of  firms  operating  in  the industries  characteristic  of  the  second  industrial  revolution— steel,  chemi¬ cals,  later  motor  cars  and  other  consumer  durables— but  even  here  produc¬ tivity  lagged  and  techniques  compared  poorly  with  those  prevalent  among 120  Cronin Britain’s  continental  competitors  and  in  the  United  States.  But  neither  Labour nor  the  Tories  had  much  of  a  plan  for  managing  the  rundown  of  old  industries and  the  shift  into  newer  lines  of  work.  The  historic  strength  of  finance  and services  did  provide  employment  for  an  ever-expanding  share  of  the  work¬ force,  prompting  endless  discussions  during  the  1950s  and  especially  the 1960s  about  the  “black-coated  worker”  (Britain’s  term  for  the  white-collar worker)  and  “affluent  worker”  and  their  impact  on  politics.  But  into  the  1970s very  large  numbers  continued  to  work  in  manual  jobs  in  older  industries.  The effect  on  Labour  as  a  party  was  twofold:  first,  it  only  gradually  and  incon¬ sistently  redirected  its  appeal  toward  white-collar  workers  and  did  little  to adapt  its  message  and  appeal;  and  second,  its  policies  were  overwhelmingly oriented  to  protecting  a  workforce  whose  physiognomy  was  already  changing and  about  to  change  even  more.  The  clearest  manifestation  of  this  social  fact was  the  enormous  clout  of  coal  miners  within  the  counsels,  thinking,  and  lore of  the  party:  mining  strikes  in  the  early  1970s  virtually  brought  down  the  Con¬ servative  government  led  by  Edward  Heath,  for  example,  and  served  as  the template  for  what  “direct  action”  could  achieve;  and  it  would  be  the  miners whose  desperate  but  doomed  strike  in  1984-85  sealed  the  fate  of  the  enduring tradition  of  Labour  as  the  party  committed  overwhelmingly  to  the  defense  of manual  workers. For  the  Labour  Party,  therefore,  the  transformation  from  a  party  of  the workers  to  a  catch-all  cross-class  party  came  very  late  and  all  of  a  sudden. During  the  Thatcher  period,  in  fact,  entire  industries  and  working-class  com¬ munities  simply  disappeared,  and  when  the  economy  slowly  began  to  grow again  in  the  1980s  it  did  not  in  any  sense  revive;  rather,  it  expanded  by  means of  new  industries  in  new  locations  and  in  the  process  created  the  outlines  of a  new  social  structure.  The  Labour  Party  was  therefore  forced  in  the  1980s not  only  to  develop  new  policies  but  to  do  so  while  confronting  a  new  elec¬ torate.  It  was  this  novelty  that  Marxism  Today,  the  most  thoughtful  and  en¬ gaged  advocate  of  a  reoriented  Labour  Party,  tried  to  capture  with  the  phrase “New  Times.”  Deploying  the  classically  Marxian  trope  of  “base  and  super¬ structure,”  the  New  Times  were  said  to  be  rooted  in  the  transformation  from a  “Fordist”  to  a  “post-Fordist”  economy  and  required  that  ideas  and  policies be  updated  accordingly.  The  party  had  to  alter  its  traditional  rhetoric,  policy assumptions,  and  even  emotional  attachments  if  it  was  to  compete  effectively in  a  post-Fordist,  Thatcherite,  neoliberal  world.  As  with  the  shift  away  from Keynes,  the  Labour  Party  was  pushed  to  reconstruct  its  social  base,  the  con¬ stituencies  and  interests  that  it  spoke  for,  dramatically  and  abruptly. The  need  to  reshape  the  Labour  Party  was  made  still  more  urgent  by  the electoral  landscape  of  the  1980s.  The  split  within  Labour  actually  worsened The  Ironies  of  New  Labour  121 after  1979.  The  left  effectively  took  over  the  party  and  prompted  secession  by the  right,  which  in  1981  launched  the  Social  Democratic  Party  (SDP)  with  the specific  aim  of  capturing  the  center  ground  of  British  politics.  Labour’s  first response  was  to  hold  firm,  and  it  chose  to  fight  the  general  election  of  1983 on  the  most  left-wing  program  it  had  ever  espoused— what  one  MP  called “the  longest  suicide  note  in  history.”  The  party’s  worst  defeat  since  1931  led to  the  election  of  Neil  Kinnock  as  party  leader.  Kinnock  was  seen  as  a  man of  the  left  and  elected  as  such,  but  he  was  ultimately  to  lead  the  party  back toward  the  center.  However,  he  was  forced  to  spend  his  first  two  years  dealing with  the  miners’  strike  and  the  influence  on  the  so-called  Militant  Tendency (a  small  but  surprisingly  effective  Trotskyist  sect)  within  the  local  parties  in Liverpool  and  parts  of  London.  By  1985  Kinnock  turned  to  an  effort  to  re¬ shape  the  party’s  message  and,  in  effect,  to  compete  for  the  centrist  voters lost  to  the  SDP  and  the  Tories.  To  do  so  he  gathered  around  himself  a  coterie of  “modernizers”  including  Charles  Clarke,  Patricia  Hewitt,  and  Peter  Man- delson.  The  immediate  focus  was  presentation,  but  after  the  defeat  of  1987  it would  include  policy  as  well.  The  Policy  Review  of  1987-89  moved  the  party’s program  decidedly  to  the  center.  By  certain  standards  it  could  be  argued  that Labour  only  became  a  genuinely  social  democratic  party  in  1989,  when  it finally  reconciled  itself  to  working  within  the  “mixed  economy”  and  gave  up its  aspiration,  never  realistic  but  nevertheless  never  relinquished,  for  socialist transformation. Despite  this  major  policy  reorientation,  Labour  failed  again  to  dislodge the  Tories  in  the  election  of  1992.  It  had  seen  off  the  threat  from  the  SDP,  but it  was  still  far  from  being  able  to  beat  the  Conservatives.  This  fourth  succes¬ sive  defeat  was  in  some  respects  even  more  traumatic  than  earlier  ones.  After all,  the  party  had  reformed  itself,  purged  itself,  fashioned  a  new  and  more attractive  message,  and  still  lost.  The  effects  were  mixed  in  the  short  term, profound  and  utterly  decisive  in  the  long  term.  Kinnock  resigned  straight¬ away  and  was  replaced  by  John  Smith,  a  moderate  Scot  whose  selection  sig¬ naled  a  period  of  consolidation  and  whose  supporters  believed  that  with  “one more  shove”  Labour  could  win.  The  modernizers,  who  by  this  time  were  led by  Tony  Blair  and  Gordon  Brown,  were  appalled,  for  they  believed  that  the lesson  of  1992  was  the  need  for  further  reform.  When  Smith  died  in  1994  he was  replaced  by  Blair,  who  chose  to  push  even  harder  on  the  modernizing agenda.  His  first  big  achievement  was  to  convince  the  party  that  it  should  re¬ place  clause  IV,  the  commitment  to  public  ownership,  in  its  constitution.  The move  was  largely  symbolic,  but  it  had  the  right  effect,  for  it  sent  a  message to  voters,  the  press,  and  potential  rivals  that  Labour  had  become  a  quite  new and  different  party. 122  Cronin These  final  moves  toward  modernizing  and  centering  the  party  were  at least  partly  stimulated  by  the  two  other  forces  that  have  recently  constrained center-left  parties  across  Europe:  the  collapse  of  communism  and  the  progress of  globalization.  The  Communist  Party  (CPGB)  was  never  a  major  force  within British  politics,  in  part  because  it  effectively  chose  to  cast  its  fate  with  the Labour  Party  from  the  1930s.  Marxist  ideas  of  various  sorts  had  nevertheless a  fairly  wide  influence  on  the  left.  The  collapse  of  communism  had  an  effect that  was  only  modest  practically,  but  large  symbolically  and  emotionally.  It was  a  signal  that  notions  of  socialist  transformation,  and  hopes  of  transcend¬ ing  capitalism,  really  were  the  stuff  of  nostalgia  and  served  no  useful  purpose even  in  the  rhetoric  of  the  Labour  Party.  To  some,  like  Jack  Straw,  this  meant that  it  was  time  to  alter  the  party’s  image  and  discourse  by  finally  abandon¬ ing  claims  about  socialism  and  in  particular  by  ridding  the  constitution  of clause  IV  (Straw  1993).  Blair,  as  party  leader,  would  agree. Britain’s  place  in  the  world  economy,  and  its  unique  dependence  on  inter¬ national  trade  and  finance,  has  long  been  an  important  factor  in  British  poli¬ tics.  As  the  first  and  most  consistent  of  free  trade  nations,  Britain  has  been much  more  exposed  to  the  opportunities  and  vulnerabilities  that  stem  from that  stance  than  its  rivals  and  competitors  have  been  (Trentmann  2008).  This exposure  was  increased  massively  and  deliberately  after  the  election  of  Mar¬ garet  Thatcher:  the  Tories  quickly  announced  the  abolition  of  exchange  con¬ trols,  for  example,  and  sought  to  make  London  once  again  the  world’s  leading financial  center,  albeit  through  the  activities  of  American  banks  and  invest¬ ment  houses.  The  “big  bang”  of  1986  was  the  key  milestone  in  this  process. The  Conservatives  also  welcomed  foreign  investment  in  industry  and,  per¬ haps  most  important,  were  willing  to  see  British  firms  perish  if  they  could not  effectively  compete  internationally.  Britain  was  also  keen  on  creating  a European  “single  market”  in  the  1980s.  All  of  this  made  globalization  more real  for  Britain  than  for  other  major  economies  and  made  it  easy  and  logical for  the  modernizers  in  the  Labour  Party  to  insist  that  their  policies  were  to a  considerable  extent  dictated  by  the  need  to  compete  in  international  mar¬ kets.  Some  within  the  party  might  be  tempted  to  object,  of  course,  for  there had  been  strong  support  within  the  party  for  policies  that  would  constrain  or counteract  the  world  market  and  protect  industry  and  jobs  from  its  devastat¬ ing  effects.  These  were  in  fact  the  assumptions  and  intentions  of  the  “alterna¬ tive  economic  strategy”  proposed  in  the  late  1970s.  But  the  implementation of  that  strategy  was  effectively  preempted  by  the  decision  to  secure  an  IMF loan  in  1976.  The  need  for  the  loan,  though  disputed  then  and  since,  offered a  choice  between  participating  fully  in  the  world  economy  and  not  doing  so. Once  made,  the  choice  was  difficult  to  reverse;  and  the  modernizers  within The  Ironies  of  New  Labour  123 the  party  insisted  that  opting  out  was  inconceivable  (Burk  and  Cairncross 1982;  Fay  and  Young  1978;  Callaghan  2000). So  party  competition,  shifts  in  the  sociology  of  the  electorate,  and  the  re¬ peated  failures  of  the  Labour  Party  while  in  office  and  the  consequent  dis¬ crediting  of  its  policy  assumptions,  as  well  as  the  more  diffuse  but  no  less important  effects  of  the  end  of  communism  and  the  advance  of  globaliza¬ tion— all  put  enormous  pressure  on  the  Labour  Party  to  become  something very  different.  As  the  modernizers,  Blair  especially,  came  to  understand  this imperative,  they  sought  to  transform  three  of  the  defining  features  of  the party.  First,  they  worked  hard  to  refashion  the  party’s  image  and  rhetoric. This  meant  embracing  modern  campaign  techniques  and  the  instruments  re¬ quired  to  make  them  effective— polls,  focus  groups,  and  the  employment  of public  relations  staff  rather  than  researchers  or  organizers.  It  also  led  to  the selection  of  leaders  and  spokesmen  who  looked,  talked,  and  acted  the  part. The  second  task  was  to  redefine  the  message:  Labour’s  program  during  the 1970s  and  into  the  late  1980s  was  on  the  whole  quite  radical,  but  it  had  by the  1990s  been  rejected  again  and  again.  The  major  work  in  revising  the  pro¬ gram  was  done  in  the  late  1980s  under  Kinnock,  but  the  process  would  con¬ tinue  under  Smith  and  Blair.  With  the  accession  of  Blair  to  the  leadership, moreover,  revision  became  more  intense  and  aggressive.  So  long  as  Kinnock and  Smith  were  leaders,  the  move  to  the  center  was  seen  and  understood  as a  tactical  necessity,  not  something  done  out  of  conviction.  Blair  set  out  to convince  voters  that  he  really  meant  it,  that  he  and  Brown  and  their  allies genuinely  believed  that  the  market  was  a  good  thing  and  not  merely  some¬ thing  to  be  accommodated,  that  New  Labour  could  make  a  market  economy work  better  and  produce  more  humane  outcomes,  and  that  they  embraced the  future  and  the  role  of  the  market  and  of  business  within  it  rather  than merely  acquiescing  in  its  inevitability.  Not  everyone  within  the  party  agreed, and  many  grumbled  privately  and  a  few  openly,  but  the  grumbling  was  much diminished  when  the  party  won  office  in  1997. The  third  and  less  often  noted  set  of  changes  had  to  do  with  organization (Russell  2005).  The  structure  of  the  Labour  Party  differed  qualitatively  from that  of  other  parties  in  Britain  and,  it  would  seem,  from  social  democratic parties  elsewhere.  Labour  in  origin  was  a  projection  of  the  trade  union  inter¬ est  into  politics,  formed  largely  to  protect  that  interest  industrially,  and  the trade  unions  were  built  directly  into  its  organization.  Thus  most  members  of the  party  were  members  by  virtue  of  their  membership  in  trade  unions;  the great  bulk  of  party  finances  came  from  the  unions  rather  than  from  individual subscriptions  or  donations;  at  the  annual  party  conference,  which  defined  the party’s  principles  and  set  out  its  program,  trade  unions  controlled  fully  90% 124  Cronin of  the  votes  until  the  early  1990s;  and  trade  unions  long  had  substantial  built- in  representation  on  the  National  Executive  Committee.  Inevitably  the  con¬ nection  largely  defined  the  underlying  outlook  and  culture  of  the  party  also, even  if  there  was  a  gloss  of  ethical  socialism  and  Marxism  laid  on  top.  And  it served  the  party  well  over  many  years,  providing  financial  support  and  the backbone  of  electoral  mobilization. Over  time,  however,  the  union  link  had  two  further  and  ultimately  un¬ happy  consequences.  During  the  1960s  and  especially  the  1970s  the  party  in government  had  tried  to  do  three  things  simultaneously:  to  generate  as  much growth  and  employment  as  possible;  to  move  the  economy,  or  society,  in  a more  collectivist  and  egalitarian  direction;  and  to  do  these  things  while  keep¬ ing  prices  under  control.  The  problem  was  that  the  first  two  objectives  largely contradicted  the  third.  Labour  governments  in  Britain,  like  governments  else¬ where,  had  very  few  mechanisms  at  hand  for  maintaining  price  stability.  The best  they  could  do  was  ask  the  trade  unions  to  help.  Trade  union  leaders  were willing,  but  their  members  were  not.  The  effect  was  a  series  of  botched  efforts to  get  the  trade  unions’  cooperation  in  controlling  inflation.  In  1968-69,  for example,  the  government  produced  a  white  paper,  “In  Place  of  Strife,”  which proposed  that  union  leaders  be  given  the  power  to  rein  in  unofficial  strikes. In  return  unions  and  their  members  would  be  accorded  an  impressive  array  of rights  and  privileges.  The  effort  got  nowhere,  and  the  government  was  forced into  a  retreat  that  showed  its  impotence  in  the  fact  of  union  resistance.  A  de¬ cade  later  a  still  weaker  Labour  government  tried  to  manage  the  economic crisis  it  faced  by  asking  unions  to  agree  to  another  year  of  wage  restraint. Such  a  policy  had  worked  from  1974  through  1977,  as  the  government  had offered  increases  in  the  “social  wage”— i.e.,  in  pensions  and  social  services  — and  in  the  wages  of  the  poorest  workers  as  part  of  a  broad  “social  contract.” It  finally  failed,  in  the  “winter  of  discontent.” The  effect  was  not  merely  the  election  of  Mrs.  Thatcher.  The  inability  to make  the  trade  union  connection  work  for  Labour  in  power  discredited  the connection  itself  as  well  as  the  trade  unions.  The  fiasco  over  “In  Place  of Strife”  demonstrated  that  trade  union  leaders  wielded  a  de  facto  veto  over Labour  policy;  the  winter  of  discontent  demonstrated  that  the  disaffected rank  and  file  could  veto  what  their  leaders  had  decided  on  high.  The  party was  rendered  doubly  ineffective.  Leaders  like  Wilson  and  Callaghan  and  later Kinnock  found  the  situation  embarrassing;  Blair  regarded  it  as  intolerable, and  his  allies  were  determined  to  overcome  it.  They  were  aided  in  this  by Margaret  Thatcher,  who  beat  the  miners  into  submission,  rewrote  labor  law, and  presided  over  a  decade  of  industrial  transformation  that  left  the  unions The  Ironies  of  New  Labour  125 severely  weakened.  For  their  part  the  Labour  modernizers  were  careful  in opposition  not  to  promise  to  reverse  Tory  industrial  relations  policy;  they also  made  it  clear  that  the  unions  were  not  to  enjoy  special  access  to  a  future Labour  government.  More  important,  they  initiated  a  series  of  alterations  in the  internal  organization  of  the  party  that  reduced  the  influence  of  the  trade unions.  The  aim  was  not  merely  to  distance  themselves  from  the  unions  but to  prevent  the  unions  from  ever  exercising  the  decisive  influence  they  had wielded  during  previous  Labour  regimes. New  Labour  in  Power These  decisions,  the  problems  they  were  meant  to  solve,  and  the  constraints they  were  intended  to  overcome  all  had  a  very  big  impact  on  what  New Labour  did  in  power  after  1997.  So  too  did  the  party’s  promise  not  to  exceed Tory  spending  limits  for  the  first  two  years  and  the  decision,  made  shortly after  the  election,  to  let  the  Bank  of  England  set  interest  rates  outside  the  con¬ trol  of  the  government.  The  effect  of  a  moderate  program,  a  rhetoric  aimed  at consensus,  and  policies  designed  not  to  upset  but  reassure  financial  markets made  for  a  first  term  with  only  modest  achievements.  Gradually,  however, New  Labour  gained  the  confidence  and  experience  to  begin  seriously  to  im¬ plement  its  program.  It  also  profited  from  the  brute  fact  of  economic  success, which  meant  that  the  proceeds  of  growth  could  be  used  to  direct  money  to Labour’s  preferred  objectives.  In  the  election  of  2001,  moreover,  the  govern¬ ment  hinted  at  least  at  the  prospect  of  an  increase  in  national  insurance  con¬ tributions— in  theory  not  a  tax  increase,  but  everyone  understood  it  as  such  — and  another  decisive  victory  led  to  its  adoption.  Labour  now  had  the  money and  the  experience  to  put  its  stamp  upon  policy  and  upon  society. What  did  it  do,  and  how  well?  The  answer  depends  in  part  on  where  one looks,  on  what  area  of  policy  one  chooses  to  emphasize.  Any  list  is  arbitrary, but  any  moderately  comprehensive  one  would  presumably  include:  economic performance  and  employment;  the  funding  and  administration  of  public  ser¬ vices  such  as  health,  education,  and  transport,  and  how  these  translate  into outcomes;  the  constitution  and  distribution  of  power  and  authority;  and  issues of  personal  and  national  security,  from  crime  to  foreign  policy.  What  is  perhaps most  interesting  about  the  experience  of  New  Labour  is  that  in  most  of  these areas  the  government  claimed  to  be  doing  something  new  and  distinctive,  dif¬ ferent  not  only  from  the  Tories  but  also  from  what  past  Labour  governments had  done  or  at  least  tried  to  do.  In  assessing  its  performance,  it  is  therefore useful  to  ask  both  how  New  Labour  did  and  also  whether  success  or  failure  had 126  Cronin anything  to  do  with  the  distinctive  innovations,  if  any,  made  by  New  Labour  in government.  A  thorough  analysis  would  take  volumes,  but  a  brief  inventory  is possible  (Shaw  2007;  Seldon  2007;  Toynbee  and  Walker  2010). The  Economy  and  Employment Labour  had  the  good  fortune  to  inherit  an  economy  in  recovery.  The  party promised,  of  course,  to  manage  growth  better  than  the  Tories,  but  it  offered few  specific  proposals.  Labour  would  essentially  continue  to  provide  a  stable macroeconomic  framework  with  only  minor  alterations.  The  most  visible move  was  the  decision  to  let  the  Bank  of  England  set  interest  rates  free  from detailed  government  involvement.  Did  this  matter  economically?  It  is  difficult to  say  definitively,  but  the  decision  did  send  a  message  to  financial  markets that  Labour  was  committed  to  market  mechanisms  and  to  the  fight  against inflation.  The  message  was  a  welcome  one  to  business  and  certainly  did  much to  reassure  investors  that  they  had  little  to  fear  from  New  Labour.  Whether that  belief  conduced  to  greater  economic  growth  is,  again,  very  hard  to  deter¬ mine.  What  can  be  said  is  that  this  initial  decision,  coupled  with  a  decade  of generally  prudent  fiscal  policy  under  Gordon  Brown’s  supervision,  did  noth¬ ing  to  derail  an  economy  that  was  already  growing  substantially.  In  fact,  the record  of  sustained  economic  growth  compiled  during  the  first  decade  of  New Labour  rule  exceeded  that  of  any  previous  administration.  It  is  of  course  pos¬ sible  that  New  Labour  was  merely  profiting  from  policies  begun  earlier  by its  opponents  and  was  unfairly  given  credit  that  others  deserved,  but  that  is how  politics  works. What  was  new  about  Labour’s  economic  and  employment  policies,  then, was  not  any  departures  from  what  the  Tories  had  put  in  place,  but  rather how  they  differed  from  the  party’s  history.  New  Labour  broke  decisively  from what  was  seen  as  the  pattern  of  previous  Labour  governments,  which  prom¬ ised  to  do  a  great  deal,  to  spend  and  (inevitably)  to  tax,  and  to  make  use  of the  state  to  spur  economic  growth  and  create  jobs.  New  Labour  no  longer believed  this  was  possible,  and  so  did  not  promise  it.  What  it  did  offer  was a  range  of  policies  to  increase  employment  by  making  people  more  employ¬ able  and  giving  them  greater  incentives  to  work.  The  theoretical  underpin¬ nings  of  the  approach  were  found  in  “endogenous  growth  theory,”  which focused  on  skills  and  knowledge.  Practically  speaking,  getting  more  people into  work— insertion,  as  some  would  call  it,  or  labor  market  activation  in another  parlance— would  simultaneously  reduce  the  number  on  welfare  and promote  “social  inclusion.”  A  prominent  initiative,  partly  modeled  on  the welfare  reform  efforts  of  President  Bill  Clinton,  was  the  so-called  New  Deal, The  Ironies  of  New  Labour  127 which  offered  financial  support  as  well  as  childcare  to  those  willing  to  enter approved  training  schemes,  vocational  education,  or  subsidized  work  (King and  Wickham-Jones  1990).  The  first  program  aimed  at  the  young;  subsequent ones  focused  on  single  parents,  the  disabled,  and  the  long-term  unemployed. A  related  set  of  policies  sought  to  reduce  the  disincentives  to  work:  free  or subsidized  childcare,  for  example,  would  eliminate  or  at  least  lower  that  bar¬ rier  to  employment;  a  minimum  wage  would  make  work  pay  better  for  the poorest;  and  the  “Working  Families  Tax  Credit”  together  with  the  Child  Tax Credit  would  allow  a  kind  of  “top-up”  beyond  what  they  ordinarily  earned. The  aim  was  to  escape  the  so-called  poverty  trap  that  rendered  work  less profitable  than  relief.  Alongside  these  “active  labor  market  policies”  was a  broader  interest  in  encouraging  human  capital  development  through  in¬ creased  investment  in  education  and  policies  aimed  at  nurturing  “knowledge- based”  industries  through  more  research  and  development.  Labour  chose  to call  this  mix  of  policies  “supply-side  socialism,”  and  they  did  work  on  the supply  side,  though  to  call  this  socialism  is  rather  a  stretch  (Romano  2006). Whatever  the  label,  the  consensus  is  that  the  New  Deal,  tax  credits,  train¬ ing,  and  improved  daycare  arrangements  have  been  moderately  effective: more  people  were  employed  overall  and  in  the  target  groups,  and  the  wel¬ fare  of  the  poorest  workers  and  their  families  substantially  improved.  It  is of  course  hard  to  say  with  certainty  that  these  shifts  are  long-term  and  that they  will  survive  a  sustained  economic  downturn,  but  the  effects  in  the  short and  medium  term  have  been  largely  positive.  It  also  seems  that  in  certain  re¬ spects  the  quality  of  work  has  improved  and  the  rights  of  workers  have  been marginally  enhanced.  Policies  on  family  leave  and  equal  opportunity,  for  ex¬ ample,  have  been  deemed  largely  successful.  Here  the  key  was  not  so  much new  British  laws  and  programs  as  the  importation  of  European  standards. During  its  long  period  in  opposition  the  Labour  Party  had  faced  a  dilemma over  its  stance  on  the  rights  of  unions  and  of  workers  more  generally.  The Thatcher  government’s  industrial  relations  legislation  was  deeply  resented  by the  trade  unions  but  popular  with  voters.  The  party  therefore  needed  to  do something  for  the  unions  without  alienating  others.  The  solution  was  found in  Europe:  Labour  decided  to  leave  the  Tories’  legislative  framework  intact but  to  accept  the  Social  Charter  first  proposed  by  Jacques  Delors.  The  Tories, by  contrast,  opted  out  of  that  bit  of  the  European  bargain.  The  social  rights outlined  in  the  charter  stood  between  the  minimal  rights  accorded  workers and  unions  in  current  British  law  and  the  much  more  extensive  set  of  protec¬ tions  and  immunities  that  unions  had  enjoyed  in  Britain  up  through  1979.  The party  managed  to  convince  the  trade  unions  that  the  European  package  was the  best  they  could  get;  and  on  assuming  office  in  1997  the  government  opted 128  Cronin in  to  its  provisions.  Unions  and  workers  have  benefited,  more  as  individuals than  collectively,  and  union  membership,  which  declined  precipitously  in  the 1980s  and  1990s,  has  begun  to  recover,  if  only  slightly  (Howell  2004). Public  Services If  Labour  inherited  an  improving  economy  in  1997,  it  also  inherited  a  de¬ teriorating  array  of  public  services.  Nearly  twenty  years  of  Conservative  gov¬ ernment  bequeathed  a  legacy  of  underinvestment  in  education,  health,  and transportation.  Scholars  have  debated  to  what  extent  the  Conservatives  were able  to  roll  back  the  welfare  state,  and  it  is  clear  that  they  were  able  to  make only  modest  cuts  in  the  National  Health  Services  (NHS)  and  for  the  most  part in  education  (Pierson  1994).  It  is  nevertheless  also  widely  agreed  that  rates  of increase  were  cut,  necessary  improvements  and  maintenance  were  delayed, and  pay  and  conditions  for  public  sector  employees  declined  or  improved only  marginally.  There  was  thus  a  historic  deficit  of  expenditures  that  the Labour  government  would  want  to  make  up. That  would  almost  have  to  happen,  though  finding  the  funds  would  not be  simple.  Doing  so,  and  doing  so  with  minimal  tax  increases  or  controversy, was  Gordon  Brown’s  primary  achievement  as  chancellor.  It  took  a  couple  of years  for  the  government  to  begin  increasing  expenditures  on  public  services, but  over  time  it  provided  enormous  sums.  Indeed,  it  has  been  widely  reported that  the  NHS  was  simply  unable  to  spend  all  that  it  was  receiving  from  the government.  And  there  have  been  results:  the  recruitment  of  doctors  and nurses  went  way  up  in  the  health  services,  waiting  times  came  way  down.  Ex¬ penditures  on  health  increased  by  7.4%  per  year  in  real  terms  between  2002 and  2008,  for  example,  and  nearly  as  much  was  spent  on  education.  Spending for  transport  also  increased  substantially. Increased  funding  and  better  outcomes  on  a  wide  range  of  measures  have nevertheless  not  brought  happiness.  Two  reasons  apparently  account  for  this. First,  taking  responsibility  for  social  provision  makes  any  government,  any agency,  responsible  for  what  goes  wrong  as  well  as  for  what  works.  Blair famously  said  that  New  Labour  believes  not  in  dogma  but  in  “what  works,” but  what  works  tends  not  to  be  noticed  and  so  is  taken  for  granted  while failure  attracts  endless  attention.  Every  botched  diagnosis,  every  MRSA  in¬ fection,  every  drop  in  exam  results,  every  train  failure  is  reported  and  some¬ one  is  blamed,  so  it  is  very  hard  for  any  government  to  get  proper  credit  for improved  services.  This  enduring  condition  has  been  exacerbated  by  New Labour’s  approach  to  the  public  sector.  Early  on  New  Labour  decided  that increases  in  funding  had  to  be  accompanied  by  “reform,”  and  reform  was The  Ironies  of  New  Labour  129 typically  defined,  controversially,  as  involving  increases  in  competition  and choice.  The  public  sector,  in  New  Labour’s  view,  should  be  restructured  ac¬ cording  to  the  principles  and  practices  of  the  market.  In  certain  cases  services should  be  provided  directly  by  the  private  sector,  even  if  that  led  to  profit making  at  public  expense.  It  also  meant  a  shift  in  rhetoric,  with  public  sector workers  and  their  unions  cast  as  opponents  of  reform,  as  “producer  interests” that  got  in  the  way  of  the  interests  of  consumers  or  patients  or  clients  or  pas¬ sengers,  and  whose  self-interested  rigidities  effectively  reduced  choice. Why  did  New  Labour  choose  this  approach  to  the  public  sector?  For  some, it  was  because  they  really  believed  in  choice  and  the  superiority  of  market models.  Evidently  Blair  really  did  think  that  competition  and  choice,  whether in  medicine  or  in  education,  would  produce  superior  outcomes.  For  others,  it was  more  a  matter  of  expediency:  getting  the  private  sector  to  help  finance new  schools,  hospitals,  buses,  and  trains  or  to  perform  certain  medical  pro¬ cedures  would  allow  a  more  rapid  expansion  and  improvement.  Critics  have of  course  pointed  out  that  privately  provided  services  and  facilities  are  no cheaper  or  better  than  those  done  by  and  through  public  authorities,  and sometimes  have  higher  cost  and  lower  quality,  but  that  is  not  the  point:  the perceived  need  as  of  1997  was  for  speed.  There  was  also  the  issue  of  politi¬ cal  expediency,  in  both  the  short  and  long  term.  Short-term,  it  was  believed to  be  easier  to  sell  increased  public  expenditure  if  that  was  going  to  pro¬ duce  not  just  more  but  better,  more  “reformed”  services.  Long-term,  many within  New  Labour  reckoned  that  the  viability  of  the  public  sector  depended on  keeping  the  middle  classes  and  the  increasingly  affluent  working  class within  the  system.  The  big  threat  to  the  public  sector,  it  was  argued,  was  the defection  of  people  whose  standards  were  rising  and  who  could  afford  to  go elsewhere.  To  keep  them  happy  meant  providing  higher  standards  and  more choice  within  the  basic  framework  of  public  provision.  This  strategic  argu¬ ment  is  hard  to  prove  or  disprove,  but  it  is  not  for  that  reason  wrong,  disin¬ genuous,  or  unimportant.  Labour’s  policies  toward  the  public  sector  have  as  a result  proved  highly  controversial,  and  disaffection  within  the  ranks  of  public sector  workers  has  prevented  Labour  from  reaping  the  benefits  that  its  record of  increased  expenditures  might  otherwise  merit.  Critics  have  claimed  with some  success  that  New  Labour  has  eroded  the  “public  service  ethos”  and  in that  sense  violated  its  core  principles. This  critique  has  been  reinforced  by  the  lack  of  interest  that  New  Labour has  shown  in  another  core  principle  in  its  tradition:  equality.  The  data  here are  frankly  contradictory.  Under  Labour  the  fate  of  the  poorest  section  of society  has  improved  a  great  deal:  child  poverty  in  particular  was  lessened; the  working  poor  became  much  better  off;  and  the  tax  and  benefit  system  be- 130  Cronin came  more  redistributive.  At  the  same  time,  inequality  has  slightly  increased. How  are  these  developments  reconciled,  in  fact  and  in  theory?  It  is  clear  that recent  economic  trends  have  been  very  regressive  in  their  effects.  Incomes have  grown  much  faster  for  the  middle  and  upper  classes  than  for  others, those  with  property  and  investments  have  fared  much  better  than  those  with¬ out,  and  the  ongoing  shift  away  from  industry  and  toward  services  has  con¬ tinued  to  reduce  the  number  of  high-paying  manual  jobs.  In  that  context— as,  it  should  be  noted,  in  most  other  advanced  countries— inequality  steadily increases.  In  Britain,  supporters  of  New  Labour  will  argue,  inequality  has grown  less  and  has  to  some  extent  been  counteracted  by  government  policy. The  defense  is  compelling  enough,  but  it  is  also  true  that  in  theory  New Labour  is  not  averse  to  increases  in  wealth  or  inequality.  From  the  beginning New  Labour  asserted  that  it  wanted  to  be  pro-business  and  that  it  heartily approved  of  entrepreneurship  and  the  accumulation  of  wealth.  Labour  pro¬ fessed  to  want  “more  millionaires,”  not  fewer.  And  it  is  this  attitude,  particu¬ larly  as  and  when  it  combines  with  the  disparaging  of  the  public  sector  and the  constant  hectoring  to  reform  it,  that  has  convinced  at  least  some  people that  New  Labour  has  truly  “lost  its  soul.” The  Constitution,  Power,  and  Security For  most  of  its  history  the  Labour  Party  has  been  about  “the  social.”  Of  neces¬ sity  it  has  had  to  develop  a  foreign  policy,  policies  toward  crime  and  the  regu¬ lation  of  personal  life,  and  a  philosophy  of  how  government  should  work, but  it  has  typically  not  distinguished  itself  on  these  issues.  The  party  has not  fundamentally  challenged  the  “Westminster  model”  of  government  but has  sought  instead  to  capture  the  model;  it  has  been  moderately  liberal  on matters  of  rights  and  social  questions,  but  hardly  in  the  forefront  on  these matters;  and  its  foreign  policy  has  not  differed  fundamentally  from  that  of its  rivals.  Indeed  before  the  advent  of  New  Labour  the  Labour  Party’s  great¬ est  success  had  been  in  the  1940s,  when  it  could  claim  to  be  the  party  which best  represented  the  national  interest  rather  than  the  interests  of  a  particular class,  and  when  it  managed  to  portray  its  opponents  as  willing  to  sacrifice  the national  interest.  Labour  was  at  that  moment  the  national  party,  not  a  sec¬ tional  interest,  and  as  such  would  do  a  better  job  of  protecting  the  state,  its institutions,  and  the  “British  way  of  life.” It  is  therefore  ironic  that  in  the  decade  after  1997  Labour  brought  into effect  a  series  of  far-reaching  constitutional  changes.  The  most  important were  devolution  in  Scotland  and  Wales,  decisions  with  potentially  transform¬ ing  consequences  for  the  shape  and  definition  of  the  nation;  reform  of  the The  Ironies  of  New  Labour  131 judiciary  and  the  House  of  Lords,  a  process  that  is  far  from  completed;  and the  incorporation  into  British  law  of  the  European  Convention  on  Human Rights  and  other  EU  laws  which  have  in  effect  given  Britain  its  first  written constitution.  In  addition,  there  is  peace  and  the  beginnings  of  reconciliation and  devolved  government  in  Northern  Ireland,  a  success  in  foreign  policy with  major  constitutional  ramifications.  The  full  effects  of  these  innovations will  not  be  clear  for  a  very  long  time,  but  they  are  likely  to  be  profound. Radical  constitutional  change  was  not  something  with  which  Labour  had ever  been  identified,  and  it  was  not  very  high  on  Labour’s  list  of  priorities  in 1997.  It  should  not  be  surprising,  therefore,  that  Labour  has  been  given  little credit  for  these  initiatives.  Instead  it  has  suffered  for  its  ambivalence  toward these  shifts  even  as  it  has  overseen  their  implementation.  It  has  appeared  in¬ consistent  and  illiberal  to  advocates  of  constitutional  reforms  and  so  forfeited its  place  as  the  party  most  strongly  committed  to  typically  liberal  reform. Labour  has  been  vulnerable  to  the  charge  of  illiberalism  on  several  other fronts  as  well.  Blair  declared  that  Labour  would  be  both  “tough  on  crime, [and]  tough  on  the  causes  of  crime.”  The  point  was  to  take  away  the  ability of  the  Tories  to  claim  that  Labour  was  “soft  on  crime”  because  of  its  concern with  getting  at  its  root  “causes”  rather  than  punishing  criminals  and  protect¬ ing  victims.  Labour  actually  managed  to  get  crime  down,  or  at  least  the  main measures  of  crime,  and  it  adopted  policies  like  the  introduction  of  “anti-social behavior  orders,”  or  ASBOs,  that  allow  it  to  claim  to  be  decisively  on  the  side of  the  victims  of  crime.  The  party’s  stances  on  immigration  and  asylum  have been  similar.  Under  Labour,  Britain  has  had  more  generous  policies  on  immi¬ gration  and  asylum  than  most  other  European  countries,  but  the  government has  also  worked  assiduously  to  convince  voters  that  both  are  under  control. It  has  received  little  credit  and  considerable  criticism  for  its  specific  mix  of tough  rhetoric  and  moderately  open  policy  on  these  issues. Assessing  these  policies  is  therefore  especially  difficult,  partly  because  the issues  and  data  are  complex  but  mainly  because  it  is  difficult  to  know  what standard  to  apply.  Over  a  protracted  period  Labour  has  been  a  socially  lib¬ eral  party,  although  the  Liberal  Democrats  (and  the  parties  which  merged  to create  them)  have  occasionally  competed  on  these  grounds.  The  architects of  New  Labour  understood  that  the  party  needed  to  maintain  that  stance while  also  finding  a  way  to  compete  for  voters  who  were  less  socially  lib¬ eral  but  might  respond  to  other  elements  of  the  party’s  appeal.  They  chose in  response  to  move  toward  what  was  regarded  as  the  center  on  such  issues as  crime  and  immigration.  To  some  extent  this  dilemma  reflects  the  shifting social  base  of  Labour.  Like  social  democratic  and  liberal  parties  elsewhere, Labour  now  gets  as  many  votes  from  the  professional  middle  classes,  espe- 132  Cronin dally  in  the  public  sector,  as  from  the  working  class,  and  among  these  newer supporters  social  liberalism  is  quite  important.5  So  too  are  economic  issues like  support  for  spending  on  public  services,  an  area  in  which  these  voters very  often  work.  By  most  accounts,  however,  working-class  voters  are  less liberal  or  progressive  on  social  issues.  New  Labour’s  strategy,  both  in  opposi¬ tion  and  in  government,  has  been  to  try  to  satisfy  both  groups  and  find  ways of  maintaining  the  party’s  traditional  liberalism  while  allaying  voters’  fears about  crime,  immigration,  asylum,  and  most  recently  terrorism.  It  is  a  deli¬ cate  balance,  and  probably  the  best  that  a  party  like  Labour  can  do  is  adopt a  series  of  compromises  that  will,  with  luck,  keep  the  issues  from  becoming salient  enough  to  rupture  the  coalition  required  for  electoral  success.  Still, balancing  of  this  sort  gives  further  ammunition  for  those  who  wish  to  argue that  Labour  has  “lost  its  soul.” Much  the  same  dilemma  confronts  Labour  regarding  foreign  policy, but  on  this  issue  the  party  has  less  control  of  what  is  and  is  not  salient  and when.  Clearly,  Iraq  became  far  more  salient  than  Blair  or  his  colleagues  ever dreamed,  except  perhaps  in  their  worst  nightmares.  Just  what  an  appro¬ priate  Labour  foreign  policy  would  look  like  is  by  no  means  obvious.  After Blair’s  resignation  and  David  Miliband’s  appointment  as  foreign  secretary, the  government  chose  to  put  somewhat  less  emphasis  on  the  “special  rela¬ tionship”  with  the  United  States.  It  was  also  eager  to  be  seen  as  more  multi¬ lateral  and  more  attentive  to  Europe  than  it  seemed  to  be  in  the  first  years after  9/11,  and  to  emphasize  goals  like  development  aid  and  climate  change that  command  wide  if  perhaps  shallow  public  support.  It  is  not  a  distinctly new  foreign  policy,  but  a  more  agreeable  one.  It  still  leaves  open,  however, just  what  Labour’s  orientation  should  be,  or  should  have  been,  toward  the awkward  questions  of  “humanitarian  intervention,”  terrorism,  and  Britain’s long-standing  strategic  posture  as  America’s  closest  ally.  The  reason  these are  open  questions  is  that  despite  Blair’s  activism  and  decisiveness  and  de¬ spite  New  Labour’s  efforts  to  rethink  policy  across  a  wide  range  of  issues,  the party  as  a  whole  has  not  engaged  in  any  fundamental  reassessment  of  foreign policy  over  the  past  quarter-century. The  roots  of  today’s  uncertainties  within  the  Labour  Party  go  back  at least  to  the  election  of  1983,  which  Labour  fought  on  a  program  of  unilateral nuclear  disarmament.  Voters  got  to  choose  between  Labour’s  antinuclear  and implicitly  anti-NATO  stance  and  the  Conservatives’  far  different  policies  — continued  support  for  NATO  and  nuclear  weapons  and  support  for  the  United States  regardless  of  the  scary  rhetoric  of  President  Reagan’s  administration and  the  deployment  of  intermediate-range  (Pershing  and  Cruise)  missiles  in Europe.  Thatcher  won  a  huge  victory,  aided  in  no  small  measure  by  Britain’s The  Ironies  of  New  Labour  133 recent  triumph  in  the  Falklands.  In  the  aftermath  Labour  began  to  back  off its  unilateralist  and  non-nuclear  positions,  but  it  failed  to  do  so  effectively and  the  issue  again  cost  votes  in  1987.  In  the  policy  review  that  followed  the defeat,  one  working  group  was  commissioned  to  look  at  foreign  and  defense policy,  but  its  members  had  great  difficulty  reaching  a  consensus  until  they took  a  trip  to  Moscow.  Mikhail  Gorbachev  met  the  delegation  and  told  them not  to  fret.  The  British  nuclear  deterrent  was  not  a  matter  of  great  concern and  besides,  the  United  States  and  the  USSR  were  in  the  process  of  agreeing to  a  package  of  major  reductions  in  both  intermediate  and  strategic  weapons. The  debate  within  the  party  was  adjourned  rather  than  resolved,  and  the issue  dropped  way  down  the  list  of  party  concerns  as  the  cold  war  ended. The  effect  was  to  bequeath  to  New  Labour  a  heritage  of  ambivalence  in  for¬ eign  and  defense  policy.  Antiwar  and  antinuclear  sentiments  sat  uneasily alongside  the  traditional  Atlanticist  and  anticommunist  record  of  the  post¬ war  Labour  governments. New  Labour  thus  took  office  in  1997  with  virtually  no  experience  in  for¬ eign  and  defense  matters,  with  few  specific  commitments  and  no  clear  vision. Once  in  power  Labour  opted  for  continuity:  it  reaffirmed  support  for  the Atlantic  alliance  and  came  to  share  the  basic  policy  orientation  and  prefer¬ ences  of  President  Clinton  — free  trade,  the  promotion  of  human  rights  and market-based  democracies,  the  enlargement  of  organizations  like  the  EU  and NATO,  and  “engagement”  with  the  UN  and  other  multilateral  institutions. New  Labour  also  shared  with  the  United  States  a  determination  to  maintain Anglo-American  military  power  at  roughly  the  levels  set  at  the  end  of  the cold  war.  Blair  and  the  shadow  foreign  secretary,  Robin  Cook,  thus  differed but  minimally  with  their  Tory  predecessors,  though  in  opposition  they  had sharply  criticized  the  Tories’  apparent  indifference  to  the  tragedy  of  Bosnia.6 The  Labour  government  would  go  on,  largely  at  Blair’s  insistence,  to  emerge as  a  strong  advocate  for  selective  “humanitarian  intervention,”  and  Blair would  personally  push  Clinton  toward  a  more  active  policy  in  Kosovo.  It  was in  the  context  of  the  debate  over  Kosovo  that  in  April  1999  Blair  gave  his  fa¬ mous  speech  in  Chicago  on  the  “Doctrine  of  International  Community”  and made  this  position  explicit  (Blair  1999;  Little  and  Wickham-Jones  eds.  2000; Kampfner  2004;  Rawnsley  2001;  Coates  and  Krieger  2004;  Freedman  2005). That  statement  put  Britain  on  record  in  support  of  aggressive  action  to  re¬ spond  to  “rogue  states”  and  humanitarian  crises,  a  commitment  that  would facilitate  the  subsequent  choice  to  invade  first  Afghanistan  and  then  Iraq  in the  aftermath  of  9/11.  It  was  in  that  respect  an  important  precedent,  but  it  is clear  that  back  in  1999  very  few,  including  Blair,  envisioned  the  world  as  it would  become  after  9/11  or  the  very  different  context  in  which  foreign  policy 134  Cronin would  be  carried  out  in  that  world.  Still,  New  Labour  had  cast  its  fate  with the  United  States  and  the  “special  relationship,”  and  with  the  principle  of humanitarian  intervention,  and  it  would  become  very  difficult  to  turn  back. What  made  it  especially  difficult  was  that  New  Labour  had  no  other  coherent or  convincing  set  of  policies  on  which  to  draw.  Debate  over  foreign  policy  had simply  not  been  a  priority  in  the  party  since  the  end  of  the  cold  war,  and  the New  Labour  project  was  a  largely  domestic  affair:  it  did  not  encompass  an alternative  vision  of  Britain’s  role  in  the  world.  Nor,  frankly,  is  it  likely  that  a lengthy  prior  debate  would  have  done  much  to  prepare  the  party,  or  Britain more  generally,  for  the  difficulties  presented  by  9/11  and  the  rise  of  militant Islam.  Knowing  what  they  know  now,  neither  Brown  nor  Miliband  nor  Jack Straw  nor  Blair  himself  would  have  been  likely  to  argue  for  the  invasion  of Iraq,  but  even  now  the  present  lack  of  a  clear  alternative  suggests  that  getting it  right  would  have  been  very  hard.  And  would  the  Americans  have  listened if  they  had  succeeded? Foreign  policy  matters,  however,  and  Iraq  matters  because  on  this  issue New  Labour  was  seen  very  much  to  have  lost  its  way  and  perhaps  its  very soul.  That  the  Tories  would  undoubtedly  have  done  the  same  thing  as  New Labour,  and  that  the  Liberal  Democrats  would  never  have  had  the  opportu¬ nity  to  decide  on  the  right  or  wrong  strategy,  does  not  make  the  loss  of  sup¬ port,  and  of  legitimacy,  any  less  real  for  New  Labour.  Blair  left  in  2007,  but  his successor  was  not  able  to  recoup  the  support  that  Blair  lost  because  of  Iraq. Again,  that  Brown’s  Conservative  challenger  failed  to  offer  a  fundamentally different  policy  did  Labour  no  good,  for  it  did  not  constitute  a  reason  to  come back  to  Labour.  Nor  was  there  an  obvious  set  of  domestic  issues  with  which to  lure  voters  back,  for  the  Conservatives  under  David  Cameron  had  moved to  the  center  on  most  key  issues  and  effectively  stolen  New  Labour’s  rhetoric (Rentoul  2008).  The  effect  of  this  curious  conjuncture  is  that  not  only  voters but  also  scholars,  political  leaders,  analysts,  and  activists  failed  to  appreciate the  numerous  and  often  quite  successful  innovations  to  which  New  Labour could  rightly  lay  claim.  New  Labour  thus  became  a  model  that  voters  chose  to reject  in  May  2010.  New  Labour’s  history  and  its  record  may  nevertheless  con¬ tain  lessons  critical  for  the  renewal  and  advance  of  the  center-left  everywhere but  in  Britain.  If  it  is  to  play  such  a  role  elsewhere,  or  even  regain  a  purchase on  the  allegiance  of  British  voters,  however,  New  Labour  may  well  require new  labels,  new  rhetoric,  and  new  understandings.  This  will  also  not  be  easy. It  has  been  claimed  again  and  again  that  New  Labour  has  offered  no  distinct vision,  just  clever  rhetoric  (Fairclough  2000).  Perhaps,  but  not  for  lack  of  try¬ ing.  When  New  Labour  was  still  taking  shape  as  a  political  force  in  the  1990s, there  were  in  fact  repeated  efforts  to  outfit  it  with  a  discourse  and  rationale The  Ironies  of  New  Labour  135 that  would  capture  what  was  actually  new  and  different  about  it.  At  least  two big  ideas  were  floated,  along  with  a  more  modest  argument  from  Blair,  be¬ fore  New  Labour  settled  on  the  ultimately  unsatisfactory  “Third  Way.”  The first  idea  was  community,  or  communitarianism.  The  reasoning  was  that  the party  needed  a  phrase  that  pointed  to  the  same  values  or  goals  as  socialism but  avoided  the  assumption  that  the  way  to  achieve  them  was  through  the state.  Talk  of  community  implied  that  citizens  had  duties  as  well  as  rights  and that  to  some  extent  the  two  were  interdependent;  and  it  allowed  the  party  to avoid  charges  that  it  was  too  soft  or  permissive.  It  fit  especially  well  with  the phrase,  coined  by  Brown  but  used  by  Blair,  “tough  on  crime,  tough  on  the causes  of  crime.” The  notion  never  quite  caught  on,  perhaps  because  its  inherent,  and  in¬ tended,  illiberalism  had  little  appeal  within  the  party.  The  second  concept that  was  aired  and  debated  in  the  mid-1990s  was  that  of  “the  stakeholder society”  (Hutton  1995;  Hutton  1997).  Again,  the  purpose  was  to  convey  what was  regarded  as  a  key  principle  of  socialism  without  using  the  word.  All  citi¬ zens  had  a  stake  in  society  and  the  economy,  not  just  the  owners  of  capital, and  their  interests  should  be  taken  into  account  in  policymaking.  It  was  pre¬ cisely  this  meaning,  however,  which  rendered  the  idea  unviable:  it  was  seen  — allegedly  by  Gordon  Brown,  but  surely  by  others  as  well— as  too  threatening to  capital  at  a  moment  when  Labour  sought  to  reassure  business  of  its  inten¬ tions.  The  concept  also  lent  itself  to  particular  appropriation  and  use  by  trade unions,  for  if  anyone  besides  owners  could  reasonably  claim  a  stake  in  a  firm, it  was  surely  the  organized  workers.  This  too  was  a  message  that  New  Labour did  not  wish  to  send. So  both  “community”  and  “the  stakeholder  society”  were  left  to  the  side, as  was  an  argument  that  Blair  began  to  develop  in  his  anniversary  lecture  on the  election  of  1945,  published  as  Let  Us  Face  the  Future  (1995).  In  it  he  made the  controversial  claim  that  what  triumphed  in  1945  was  not  socialism  nor even  social  democracy,  but  a  distinctly  British  type  of  progressive  politics that  combined  socialism  and  liberalism.  The  model  for  Blair  was  thus  less  the Labour  government  elected  in  1945  than  the  New  Liberalism  represented  by the  Liberal  government  elected  in  1906.  Blair  insisted  that  the  Labour  Party should  combine  the  virtues  of  both  traditions.  Once  more,  the  obvious  inten¬ tion  was  to  avoid  the  negative  associations  attached  to  socialism  by  instead proclaiming  allegiance  to  the  inheritance  of  liberalism  in  its  reforming,  so¬ cially  concerned,  and  mildly  collectivist  variety  of  the  early  twentieth  cen¬ tury. This  outpouring  of  argument,  of  theory,  occurred  at  precisely  the  moment when  New  Labour  was  shedding  its  old  image  by  abandoning  clause  IV  of  its 136  Cronin constitution,  and  it  was  obviously  directed  at  creating  an  effective  substitute. None  of  these  ideas  succeeded  in  doing  so,  however,  and  by  the  time  of  the election  of  1997  that  seemed  not  to  matter.  New  Labour  won  a  decisive  vic¬ tory  without  having  settled  upon  a  big  new  idea  or  even  an  animating  slogan. It  was  in  this  context  that  the  party  settled  on  the  relatively  vacuous  notion of  “the  Third  Way.”  As  critics  have  cruelly  pointed  out,  the  Third  Way  has  no intrinsic  meaning  at  all:  it  is  merely  a  way  of  saying  that  the  Labour  Party  was neither  this  nor  that,  neither  the  hard-hearted  Tories  nor  the  dour  and  diri- giste  socialists  of  the  past.  Its  content  was,  at  least  at  the  beginning,  negative and  empty.  Over  time  a  cluster  of  quite  thoughtful  people— Anthony  Giddens most  prominently— would  try  very  hard  to  fill  in  the  vast  conceptual  space inside  the  Third  Way  (Giddens  1998;  Giddens  2000;  Giddens  ed.  2001).  The exercise  was  not  without  merit,  for  it  provided  the  rubric  under  which  quite useful  debates  were  conducted  on  policy  and  on  more  fundamental  questions about  the  relationship  between  markets  and  states,  the  individual  and  society, justice  and  equality,  and  the  environment  and  the  global  economy.  The  work would  continue  in  think  tanks  like  the  Policy  Network,  the  Institute  for  Public Policy  Research,  the  Foreign  Policy  Center,  Demos,  and  others,  and  with  con¬ siderable  sophistication.  Yet  it  was  and  still  is  an  elite  discourse— the  Policy Network,  for  example,  began  as  the  Progressive  Governance  Network  and  in¬ cluded  only  the  leaders  of  center-left  governments  — and  its  focus  on  policy did  not  and  still  does  not  easily  translate  into  marketable  slogans.  There  was probably  never  any  real  possibility  that  the  concept  of  the  Third  Way  could have  inspired  the  kind  of  enthusiasm  and  loyalty  which  other  terms— social¬ ism,  social  democracy,  or,  in  their  own  way,  community  or  stakeholding— had done,  or  might  have  done,  whatever  the  venue  and  style.  In  the  event,  talk  of the  Third  Way  inevitably  died  down  and  Labour  in  office  was  unable  to  come up  with  anything  to  take  its  place. So  long  as  the  party  kept  winning  elections,  the  absence  of  a  big  idea probably  did  not  matter  greatly.  As  the  party’s  fortunes  declined,  gradu¬ ally  under  Blair  and  then  more  seriously  under  Brown,  the  lack  of  a  major unifying  theme  or  vision  came  to  be  more  acutely  missed.  Will  Labour  find one  in  opposition?  Does  it  actually  need  any  particular  animating  vision? There  has  recently  been  some  renewed  attention  devoted  to  the  possibility of  combining  the  best  of  liberalism  and  of  social  democracy  by  crafting  a new  definition  of  citizenship  which  in  one  version  would  be  anchored  in  a new  constitution  for  Britain.  There  are  also  those  who,  in  response  to  the weakening  of  New  Labour,  would  prefer  to  revert  to  the  old  and  reconnect with  an  older  social  democratic  tradition  emphasizing  redistribution  and an  expanded  role  for  the  state.  The  issue  is  unlikely  to  be  settled  at  the  level The  Ironies  of  New  Labour  137 of  theory  and  will  effectively  be  decided  by  the  choices  made  by  Gordon Brown’s  successors. It  was  clear  by  early  2010  that  the  future  of  the  Labour  Party  would  hinge largely  on  the  choice  of  leader,  but  also  on  the  electoral  performance  of  the party  under  Brown,  on  the  manner  and  context  of  Brown’s  leaving,  and  on the  character  of  the  opposition  that  the  party  would  face  once  Brown  was  re¬ placed.  The  election  of  6  May  produced  unexpected  results  on  all  three  fronts. To  begin,  Labour  performed  better  than  predicted.  During  the  election  cam¬ paign  the  rapid  rise  of  Nick  Clegg  and  the  Liberal  Democrats— attributed most  plausibly  to  the  impact  of  television  debates  staged  for  the  first  time ever— raised  the  possibility  that  Labour  would  be  pushed  into  third  place  be¬ hind  the  Tories  and  the  Liberal  Democrats.  That  did  not  happen:  by  election day  “Cleggmania,”  as  it  was  called,  had  faded  and  the  party  secured  23%  of the  votes  and  lost  five  seats  in  the  House  of  Commons,  for  a  modest  total  of  57; the  Tories  had  failed  to  break  through,  getting  just  over  36%  of  the  vote  and  a plurality  (306)  but  not  a  majority  of  seats;  and  Labour  had  rallied  to  win  29% of  the  vote  and  258  seats.  The  result  was,  or  so  it  seemed,  a  hung  parliament; and  then,  to  the  surprise  of  many,  the  Conservatives  and  the  Liberal  Demo¬ crats  formed  a  coalition.  In  the  process  Gordon  Brown  made  a  dignified  and gracious  exit. Critics  of  Labour,  and  especially  of  “New  Labour,”  had  anticipated  a  his¬ toric  collapse,  and  the  circumstances  in  which  the  election  was  fought  were about  as  bad  as  one  could  imagine.  Labour  had  been  in  power  for  thirteen years,  and  the  enthusiasm  generated  way  back  in  1997  had  long  since  dissi¬ pated.  The  party’s  achievements,  which  were  many  and  substantial,  were  for¬ gotten  or  taken  for  granted;  its  style— the  tendency  to  “spin,”  its  preference for  increasing  taxes  and  spending  by  “stealth,”  its  sometimes  vacuous  rheto¬ ric-had  begun  to  grate;  and  many  had  never  forgiven  the  party  for  the  de¬ bacle  in  Iraq.  Even  more  important,  according  to  exit  polls,  was  the  state  of the  economy,  for  which  Labour  was  forced  to  bear  responsibility.  Brown  and his  chancellor,  Alastair  Darling,  had  by  all  accounts  responded  effectively  to the  financial  crisis,  but  the  economy  remained  in  terrible  shape  and  the  loom¬ ing  budget  deficit  seemed  to  guarantee  an  era  of  austerity  which  would  erode much  that  Labour  in  power  had  wrought.  In  addition,  there  was  the  utter  dis¬ aster  of  the  expenses  scandal,  a  phenomenon  that  affected  both  the  major parties  (and  the  Liberal  Democrats  rather  less)  and  heightened  the  sense  that something  had  to  change.  And  finally  there  was  Brown  himself,  with  a  “face made  for  radio”  and  an  affect  and  personality  that  did  not  come  across  well  in any  medium,  who  was  forced  to  compete  on  television  with  two  younger  and much  better  performers.  Back  in  1994,  when  Blair  had  persuaded  Brown  to 138  Cronin step  aside  in  the  leadership  contest,  a  key  consideration  was  how  much  better Blair  performed  on  television  and  in  Parliament.  Little  had  changed  on  that score  by  2010. Add  these  adverse  conditions  together  and  it  is  hard  to  imagine  a  party  in power  not  losing  many  votes  and  seats.  The  party  did  lose  on  both  measures in  2010,  but  no  more  and  perhaps  even  less  than  they  could  and  should  have lost.  Why?  The  short  answer  is  that  the  architects  of  New  Labour  got  it  right and  Labour’s  policies  were  more  or  less  where  they  ought  to  have  been.  The Blairite  embrace  of  the  market  may  have  been  excessive,  but  only  marginally so,  and  it  was  probably  more  effective  than  the  alternative;  the  party  may  also have  been  too  quick  to  “spin”  rather  than  to  explain,  but  in  a  world  of  instant communication  and  in  a  country  with  a  press  that  feeds  on  controversy  and scandal,  to  err  in  that  way  was  surely  better  than  to  have  erred  in  the  direc¬ tion  of  greater  candor;  constant  talk  of  “reforming”  public  services  and  in¬ creasing  choice  may  have  alienated  some  of  Labour’s  supporters  in  the  trade unions  and  the  public  sector,  but  not  enough  to  prevent  the  unions  from  bank¬ rolling  the  party’s  election  campaign;  and  in  the  desire  to  appear  tough  on crime  and  immigration  and  terrorism,  the  party  may  well  have  veered  too  far from  its  socially  and  politically  liberal  traditions,  although  its  policies  were less  illiberal  in  practice  than  its  rhetoric  might  have  implied.  And  of  course the  Labour  government’s  willingness  to  lend  its  support  to  the  United  States and  its  adventures  was  also  profoundly  controversial,  but  again,  would  the alternative  have  been  more  successful?  The  attack  of  9/11  was  truly  an  excep¬ tional  moment,  and  a  reluctance  to  back  the  United  States  then  would  have been  unthinkable.  Once  that  backing  was  offered  the  options  were  limited; and  New  Labour  had  extremely  bad  luck  in  having  to  deal  not  with  Bill  Clin¬ ton  or  Barack  Obama  but  with  George  W.  Bush. The  argument  that  Labour,  in  its  New  Labour  incarnation,  had  been  sen¬ sible  and  effective  gains  at  least  some  support,  if  not  confirmation,  by  what has  come  to  replace  it.  The  Tories,  it  would  seem,  made  gains  by  moving to  the  center  and  toward  the  mix  of  policies  on  welfare  and  the  public  sec¬ tor  favored  by  Labour  (Bale  2010).  If  the  heart  of  the  Conservative  Party  re¬ mained  Thatcherite,  its  head  led  Cameron  and  his  allies  to  speak  a  different rhetoric,  write  a  different  manifesto,  and  run  a  different  campaign.  It  may also  be  that  the  party  did  not  do  even  better  in  the  election  because  voters perceived  this  split  between  head  and  heart  and  feared  a  return  to  Thatcher¬ ism  or  something  like  it.  If  so,  then  the  coalition  with  the  Liberal  Democrats was  a  brilliant  move,  for  it  allowed  the  Conservatives  to  ditch  those  policies that  were  most  attractive  to  its  Thatcherite  wing  and  move  much  closer  to  the sort  of  centrist  and  socially  liberal  policies  that  can  help  them  win  elections. The  Ironies  of  New  Labour  139 If  the  coalition  lasts— and  the  commitment  by  the  two  parties  to  stay  together in  government  for  a  full  five  years  should  not  be  discounted  — it  will  ironi¬ cally  represent  the  triumph  of  Labour’s  efforts  to  move  Britain  away  from the  Thatcherite  settlement  and  toward  the  political  center,  toward  something more  humane  and  stable.  It  will  also  confront  Labour  with  the  need  to  differ¬ entiate  itself  from  a  discourse,  a  reality  and  a  set  of  policies  that  it  did  much to  create. There  is  great  irony,  of  course,  in  the  fact  that  as  the  coalition  speaks  in the  language  of  fairness,  it  has  adopted  a  policy  of  extreme  fiscal  austerity and  begun  to  blame  Labour  for  running  up  deficits  and  leaving  the  country in  dire  straits.  The  cuts  proposed  by  George  Osborne  seem  to  many  to  be  the equivalent  of  the  measures  taken  by  Thatcher  (McKibbin  2010).  And  yet  both the  total  of  cuts  proposed,  and  many  of  the  details,  differ  only  marginally from  what  Labour  had  proposed  or  was  prepared  to  do  if  it  been  reelected. This  is  surely  why  the  initial  resistance  to  the  coalition’s  austerity  measures was  modest  and  restrained.  That  may  change  as  the  more  controversial  and draconian  policies  come  into  effect— especially  if  the  protests  over  tuition fees  are  an  indicator— but  will  Labour  be  able  to  offer  a  credible  vision  that is  radically  different?  Will  the  new  leader,  Ed  Miliband,  succeed  in  crafting  a credible  Labour  response?  His  politics  are  slightly  less  Blairite  than  those  of his  brother  David,  whom  he  defeated  in  the  leadership  election.  Will  that  help or  hurt  in  this  process? It  seems  unlikely,  and  the  situation  in  which  Labour  finds  itself  would seem  to  argue  more  for  continuity  than  for  change,  especially  if  change  is conceived  as  a  reversion  to  something  that  looks  and  sounds  like  “old  Labour” and  feels  like  the  “winter  of  discontent.”  It  would  be  foolish  to  keep  talking about  “New  Labour”  so  long  after  its  invention  and  so  long  after  the  phrase did  its  work  in  separating  the  party  from  those  aspects  of  its  past  that  were no  longer  popular.  New  slogans  will  by  necessity  emerge,  and  they  ought  to embody  substantive  new  thinking  about  issues  on  which  New  Labour  was most  vulnerable.  Still,  a  more  fundamental  break  seems  unlikely  and  indeed unwise,  fora  rejection  of  Labour’s  recent  past  would  mean  turning  one’s  back on  a  record  marked  by  considerable  success  and  on  a  brand  of  politics  that may  well  represent  a  viable  future  for  center-left  parties  and  movements  in Britain  and  elsewhere. Notes 1.  For  greater  detail  and  more  extensive  documentation  of  this  historical  process see  Cronin  2004. 140  Cronin 2.  Deciding  who  was  the  left,  who  was  the  center,  and  who  was  the  right  of  the party  was  often  tricky.  A  clear  “right”  had  emerged  in  the  late  1950s  and  early  1960s around  the  party  leader,  Hugh  Gaitskell,  and  his  ally,  Tony  Crosland,  the  main  theo¬ retician  among  the  “revisionists.”  Leaders  such  as  Callaghan  were  intellectually  quite close  to  this  camp,  but  their  strong  ties  to  the  trade  unions,  or  at  least  Callaghan’s strong  ties,  were  probably  more  important  in  determining  his  policies.  He  is  probably better  regarded  as  being  in  the  center  of  the  party.  Harold  Wilson’s  achievement  was of  course  to  bridge  the  factions,  but  at  considerable  cost;  Tony  Benn’s  later  failure  was to  divide  them  and  drive  the  right  completely  out  of  the  party.  Tracking  the  disputes and  arguments  within  the  party  is  entertaining;  somewhat  harder  is  figuring  out  the basis  of  coexistence.  The  best  answer  to  the  puzzle,  I  have  argued,  focuses  on  the  term “labourism,”  an  outlook  that  was  genuinely  shared  and  served  to  distinguish  the  party from  its  competitors  in  the  United  Kingdom  and  also  from  its  sister  parties  on  the  con¬ tinent.  For  an  explanation  see  Cronin  2004,  7-10. 3.  See  the  vigorous  and  engaging  debate  between  Mark  Wickham-Jones  (1995)  and Colin  Hay  (1997). 4.  Stephen  Gill  (1995)  used  the  phrase  “disciplinary  neoliberalism”  to  describe  the Thatcher  era  and  neoliberalism  more  broadly;  it  was  revised  to  “compensatory  neolib¬ eralism”  by  Perry  Anderson  (2007). 5.  See  the  essays  by  Gerassimos  Moschonas  and  Ruy  Teixeira  in  this  volume. 6.  Determining  the  right  response  to  the  post-cold  war  crisis  in  the  former  Yugo¬ slavia  was  clearly  not  easy,  but  some  people  were  demonstrably  wrong.  For  a  compel¬ ling  argument  on  the  deficiencies  of  the  British  response  see  Simms  2002. Reluctantly  Center-Left? The  French  Case Arthur  Goldhammer  and  George  Ross Structuring  the  Puzzle France  today  is  often  portrayed  as  a  country  uniquely  refractory  to  reform. This  is  highly  misleading.  In  the  decades  following  the  Second  World  War, which  Jean  Fourastie  has  referred  to  as  les  Trente  Glorieuses,  deep  struc¬ tural  reform  enabled  France  to  achieve  a  rate  of  growth  in  per  capita  GDP that  was  among  the  highest  in  Europe.1  The  resources  that  made  this  remark¬ able  performance  possible  — technologically  advanced  firms,  superbly  trained elites,  highly  productive  workers,  and  a  political  will  to  remain  competitive  — remain  in  place.  In  recent  times,  however,  France  has  been  slow  to  respond to  the  challenges  of  the  increasingly  globalized  economy.  One  reason  for  this has  been  that  the  French  left  has  had  serious  difficulties  functioning  in  this new  environment. Why  has  the  French  left  had  such  difficulties?  To  answer  this  question  we begin  by  underlining  three  persistent  elements  of  the  French  political  system that  mark  the  period  from  the  1960s  to  the  present.  The  first  is  chronic  divi¬ sion.  Unlike  some  other  lefts,  the  French  left  has  always  been  divided.2  Com¬ munists  and  Socialists  coexisted,  often  with  smaller  groups  around  them  and frequently  in  conflict,  for  much  of  the  twentieth  century.  The  competitive games  that  these  divisions  created  have  complicated  the  tasks  of  devising  the left’s  goals,  programs,  and  policies,  with  powerful  consequences  for  its  iden¬ tities  and  prospects.  Next,  partly  because  of  these  divisions,  the  left  has  been fixated  on  preserving  a  French  social  model.  At  the  end  of  the  Second  World War  elites  agreed  on  the  need  for  rapid  economic  modernization  led  by  the state,  together  with  an  extensive  welfare  system  under  “paritary  manage¬ ment,”  according  to  which  social  insurance  programs  (health,  pension,  unem¬ ployment)  were  administered  not  by  the  state  but  by  employer  associations, unions,  and  other  organized  “stakeholders.”  The  left  has  increasingly  defined itself  as  the  defender  of  this  distinctive  “French  model.”  The  third  element  is 142  Goldhammer  and  Ross presidentialism.  The  Constitution  of  the  Fifth  Republic  endowed  the  presi¬ dency  with  vast  powers,  making  it  the  linchpin  of  French  political  life,  and diminishing  the  power  of  Parliament.  Accompanying  this,  a  two-round  elec¬ toral  system,  intended  to  transform  a  multiparty  system  into  a  bipolar  one, meant  that  a  successful  presidential  candidate  had  to  be  able  not  only  to  unite his  own  party  but  also  to  appeal  to  centrist  voters  in  the  second  round.  These three  structural  elements  have  shaped  the  left’s  response  to  the  challenges  of the  post-Keynesian  era. Francois  Mitterrand  Climbs  the  Summit Since  all  power  flowed  from  the  presidency,  the  Socialists  had  to  find  a  way to  defy  the  old  adage  that  “you  can’t  win  with  the  Communists  and  can’t  win without  them.”  Mitterrand,  leader  of  the  Parti  Socialiste  (PS)  since  its  re¬ organization  in  1969-71,  therefore  struck  a  deal  with  the  Parti  Communiste Frangais  (PCF),  set  out  in  the  landmark  “Common  Program  for  a  Government of  the  Left”  (1972).  The  program,  biased  toward  the  PCF’s  reform  proposals, advocated  extensive  new  nationalizations,  planning,  energetic  Keynesianism, expanded  welfare  programs,  enhanced  powers  for  unions  and  workers,  and decentralization.  With  this  compact  Mitterrand  came  very  close  to  defeating Valery  Giscard  d’Estaing  in  1974. Giscard,  intent  upon  building  a  new  hegemonic  center-right  party,  favored liberalizing  social  and  economic  reforms  of  which  many  Gaullists  disap¬ proved.  The  left  began  to  argue  that  “liberalism,”  as  practiced  by  Giscard and  Raymond  Barre,  prime  minister  after  1976,  marked  a  repudiation  of  the French  postwar  model  and  promised  a  “return  to  the  model”  if  elected.  The international  situation  had  changed,  however.  In  the  English-speaking  coun¬ tries  monetarism  was  becoming  the  new  orthodoxy;  price  stability,  even  at the  expense  of  employment,  replaced  Keynesian  stimulus  policies.  In  line with  these  trends  Giscard  and  Chancellor  Helmut  Schmidt  of  Germany  agreed to  create  a  European  Monetary  System  to  limit  the  damage  from  floating  ex¬ change  rates.  Over  time  this  system  was  likely  to  impose  rigorous  German monetary  standards  on  the  traditionally  more  lax  French.3 The  stage  was  thus  set  for  the  presidential  elections  in  the  spring  of  1981, the  critical  moment  for  the  French  left.  In  the  first  round  Mitterrand  stood  for the  Socialists,  Georges  Marchais,  secretary  general  of  the  PCF,  for  the  Com¬ munists.  On  the  right  Giscard  d’Estaing,  the  incumbent,  faced  a  determined Jacques  Chirac,  the  neo-Gaullist.  Mitterrand  (with  25.85%)  decisively  de¬ feated  Marchais  (15.34%,  down  6%  from  Jacques  Duclos’s  share  of  the  vote  in 1979)  and  then  Giscard  in  the  second  round.  The  PS  also  captured  an  absolute Reluctantly  Center-Left?  143 majority  of  seats  in  the  National  Assembly,  leaving  the  Communists  no  choice but  to  join  a  left  unity  government  under  the  new  prime  minister,  Pierre  Mau- roy.4  For  a  brief  period  the  left’s  persistent  division  was  overcome,  therefore, and  the  first  eighteen  months  of  Mitterrand’s  experiment  demonstrated  that he  was  serious  about  restoring  the  French  postwar  model,  with  the  state  in a  leading  economic  role.  The  government  nationalized  several  key  industrial firms  and  most  banks.5  Other  key  reforms  included  political  decentralization, enhanced  representation  in  the  workplace,  and  stronger  legal  foundations  for local  unions,  which  led  to  greater  flexibility  in  collective  bargaining.  The  left also  introduced  a  wealth  tax  on  large  fortunes  (the  Impot  de  Solidarity  sur  la Fortune,  or  ISF),  abolished  the  death  penalty,  and  privatized  television  and radio  networks. The  more  immediate  problem  was  high  unemployment.  To  combat  this, 170,000  new  public  sector  jobs  were  created  in  1981-82.  The  left  also  tried to  stimulate  consumption  by  raising  the  minimum  wage,  pensions,  family allowances,  and  housing  subsidies.  A  fifth  week  of  vacation  was  added,  the retirement  age  was  reduced  to  sixty,  and  negotiations  were  begun  to  shorten the  legal  work  week  to  thirty-nine  hours.  The  effort  failed,  however.  Unem¬ ployment  rose  by  300-400,000  in  the  first  year,  and  high  inflation  led  to exchange  difficulties.  Because  France  had  attempted  to  reflate  while  other countries  deflated,  much  of  France’s  additional  demand  went  to  purchase cheaper  foreign  goods,  creating  the  largest  balance-of-payments  deficit  in French  history.  The  franc  came  under  pressure  within  the  European  Mone¬ tary  System,  and  a  first  devaluation  in  the  fall  of  1981  failed  to  alleviate  the problem.  More  generally,  combining  supply-side  “progressive”  technocratic statism  with  strong  Keynesianism  clearly  did  not  work. The  U-Turn The  bills  began  to  come  due  around  June  1982,  when  the  government  re¬ trenched  with  tough  austerity  measures,  including  a  wage  and  price  freeze, new  restrictions  on  capital  movements,  de-indexing  of  wages,  high  interest rates,  and  draconian  budget  cuts.  The  new  policies  proved  to  be  effective  but not  sufficient,  and  by  the  spring  of  1983  the  left  faced  a  critical  choice:  either leave  the  EMS  and  float  the  franc,  or  stay  and  make  basic  domestic  economic policy  changes.  After  hesitating  Mitterrand  favored  the  second  option,  which led  to  the  so-called  U-turn.  The  government  abruptly  stopped  using  the  pub¬ lic  sector  to  maintain  employment  and  turned  instead  to  harsh  industrial  re¬ structuring. The  shift  affected  diplomatic  as  well  as  economic  policy.  To  Mitterrand,  a 144  Goldhammer  and  Ross staunch  European,  staying  in  the  EMS  meant  renewed  engagement  with  Euro¬ pean  integration.  Austerity  was  unpopular,  and  Mitterrand  needed  a  justifica¬ tion  for  his  choice.  Belt-tightening  could  be  presented  as  a  means  to  achieve noble  European  goals.  The  idea  was  to  use  European  integration,  which France  strongly  favored,  to  apply  outside  pressure  in  support  of  needed  do¬ mestic  policy  changes  in  France.  One  result  was  the  appointment  of  Jacques Delors  as  president  of  the  European  Commission. In  January  1985  Delors,  Mitterrand’s  first  finance  minister  and  an  architect of  the  policy  shifts  of  1982-83,  launched  a  vast  program  to  liberalize  and  de¬ regulate  the  EC  internal  market.  He  would  subsequently  propose  a  new  Eco¬ nomic  and  Monetary  Union  (emu).6  The  French  hoped  thereby  to  seize  some control  over  monetary  policy  from  the  German  Bundesbank  and  thus  reduce the  bias  toward  price  stability,  at  the  cost  of  ceding  French  monetary  policy prerogatives  to  European  control. The  turn  to  austerity,  the  abandonment  of  key  instruments  of  statist  eco¬ nomic  control,  and  the  new  European  initiatives  meant  that  important  fea¬ tures  of  the  French  postwar  model  would  be  jettisoned.  What  remained  was a  French  social  model,  without  the  full  range  of  economic  policy  prerogatives that  had  kept  it  on  track  during  les  Trente  Glorieuses.  In  the  medium  term there  was  perhaps  vague  hope  that  liberalization  and  Europeanization  would rekindle  growth  and  reduce  unemployment.  In  the  short  run,  however,  the left  needed  to  satisfy  its  electorate.  The  Socialist-governmental  left  had  suc¬ cessfully  coopted  a  part  of  the  Communist-extragovernmental  left’s  base,  be¬ ginning  the  long,  slow  decline  of  the  PCF.  Yet  without  policies  to  satisfy  the hopes  that  had  been  aroused  in  1981,  the  PS  could  easily  lose  the  new  voters it  had  gained— voters  who  saw  themselves  as  constituting  a  distinct  left  wing of  the  party,  not  always  in  solidarity  with  the  increasingly  center-left  leader¬ ship  and  its  very  different  social  base. Mitterrand  won  reelection  in  1988,  but  the  economic  situation  had  wors¬ ened.  Unemployment,  6%  when  the  left  won  in  1981,  had  risen  to  over  11% by  1987.  Earlier  reforms,  enacted  in  a  more  hopeful  time,  were  now  incorpo¬ rated  into  a  set  of  policies  that  have  been  described  as  the  “social  treatment  of unemployment.”  A  shorter  work  week,  a  fifth  vacation  week,  and  a  reduced retirement  age  kept  unemployment  levels  from  rising  even  higher,  albeit  at the  cost  of  lowering  labor  force  participation  rates.  An  ordinance  in  1982  gave workers  strong  incentives  to  “pre-retire,”  or  go  half-time  at  fifty-five  or  even fifty  (many  were  obliged  to  do  so).  In  1984  the  government  instituted  further early  retirement  incentives  to  encourage  industrial  restructuring.  New  youth employment  programs,  usually  involving  temporary  training  positions,  were added  to  the  mix.  More  spending  on  education  pushed  a  higher  percentage of  each  age  cohort  into  university  and  technical  training,  to  similar  effect. Reluctantly  Center-Left?  145 Left  governments  were  loath  to  change  the  standard  labor  contract  (the CDI,  or  contrat  a  duree  indetermin.ee) .  In  contrast  to  countries  with  “flexi- curity”  arrangements— where  law  and  social  policy  protect  workers  rather than  jobs  — the  CDI  protected  particular  jobs  rather  than  workers.  The  CDI had  been  an  important  working-class  victory,  to  be  tampered  with  by  left  gov¬ ernments  at  great  risk.  But  in  a  period  of  increasing  economic  uncertainty  its persistence  led  French  employers  to  avoid  new  CDI  hires  except  in  the  most buoyant  of  economic  circumstances.  When  the  left  tried  to  encourage  new hiring,  it  therefore  generally  resorted  to  new,  temporary,  often  heavily  subsi¬ dized  employment  contracts.  This  made  those  who  already  had  CDls  more  de¬ fensive  and  those  who  did  not  more  insecure.  Older  workers  were  likely  to  be better  protected  than  younger  ones.  Younger  workers  with  fewer  educational credentials  were  worst  off.  Universalist  republican  rhetoric  notwithstanding, differences  between  insider  and  outsider  thus  grew  rapidly. France’s  workforce  and  labor  market  changed  dramatically  in  these  years.7 French  society  was  becoming  more  “dualized”:  a  part  of  the  population  held steady  jobs  at  reasonable  pay  and  enjoyed  social  protections;  others  lived more  precarious  lives.  In  the  presidential  campaign  of  1988  Mitterrand  re¬ sponded  to  growing  public  concern  about  social  exclusion  by  proposing  the RMI  ( revenu  minimum  d’ insertion). 8  In  time,  despite  tight  eligibility  control, the  “insertion”  part  of  the  RMI  became  less  important  than  the  “revenu,” owing  to  the  chronic  absence  of  jobs. The  cost  of  French  social  policy  therefore  increased  rapidly  (from  19.2%  of GDP  in  1970,  to  26%  in  1981  and  nearly  30%  in  1995).  Since  payroll  taxes  paid for  key  welfare  provisions,  rising  tax  levels  pushed  France  out  of  line  with  its European  competitors.  This  prompted  the  creation  of  the  contribution  sociale generalisee  (CSG)  in  December  1990.  The  CSG  was  a  new  flat  tax  on  incomes dedicated  to  financing  social  programs,  set  initially  at  1.1%.  The  idea  was  to broaden  the  tax  base  sustaining  the  French  social  model,  a  change  justified in  the  name  of  “solidarity.” For  the  two  most  expensive  social  programs,  pensions  and  healthcare, cost  pressures  increased.  Pension  costs  rose  in  part  because  of  changing demographics  but  also  because  the  “social  treatment  of  unemployment”  re¬ moved  older  workers  from  the  labor  force  by  encouraging  early  retirement. In  healthcare  costs  rose  for  the  same  reasons  as  everywhere  else,  including changing  demographics  and  expensive  technological  progress.  The  French welfare  state  model  contributed  to  these  cost  pressures.  The  model,  it  will be  recalled,  was  built  primarily  on  social  insurance  programs  managed  in  a “paritary”  way.  Immediate  stakeholders  shaped  policy  decisions,  with  a  ten¬ dency  to  offload  costs  on  others.  Yet  paritary  management  and  maintaining the  stakeholders’  voice  were  untouchable.  Governments  that  pushed  too  hard 146  Goldhammer  and  Ross to  lower  costs  faced  strikes  and  protests.  Pension  reform,  for  example,  be¬ came  a  political  third  rail,  while  government  efforts  to  reduce  hospital  costs (the  one  area  of  healthcare  that  it  did  control)  prompted  walkouts  by  nurses and  physicians. The  government  of  Michel  Rocard  (1988-91)  was  as  close  to  being  “center- left”  as  French  Socialists  in  the  Mitterrand  era  came.  Rocard  benefited  from the  first  serious  upturn  in  the  European  and  international  economy  since  the 1970s,  with  GDP  growth  jumping  to  nearly  4%  in  1988  and  1989.  But  France’s structural  economic  problems  remained.  The  economy  was  sluggish,  the  so¬ cial  treatment  of  unemployment  was  very  expensive  and  compounded  labor market  rigidities,  and  chronic  budgetary  deficits  obliged  a  constant  chipping away  at  social  costs. The  end  of  the  Mitterrand  years  was  also  troublesome  for  the  PS.  The  party was  racked  by  scandal.  With  Mitterrand’s  second  term  expiring  in  1995  and the  president  himself  dying,  struggles  over  leadership  and  potential  presi¬ dential  candidacies  revived  bitter  factional  disputes.  One  flashpoint  occurred during  the  referendum  campaign  on  the  Maastricht  Treaty  in  1992.  The  PS and  the  Union  pour  la  Democratic  Franqaise  (UDF),  Giscard’s  center-right party,  formed  a  united  front  to  promote  a  “yes”  vote,  and  they  eventually prevailed,  though  barely.  But  parts  of  the  PS,  including  the  Centre  d’Etudes et  d’Education  Socialistes  (CERES)  faction  around  Jean-Pierre  Chevenement, campaigned  for  a  “no.”  The  episode  showed  that  the  decline  of  the  pcf  had not  ended  division  on  the  left.  Other  “extragovernmental”  political  forces  and social  movements  sought  to  occupy  the  spaces  that  the  PCF  had  vacated.  It was  at  this  point,  for  example,  that  nationalist  anti-globalization  sentiment emerged,  led  by  new  groups,  including  the  Association  pour  la  Taxation  des Transactions  Financieres  et  l’Aide  aux  Citoyens  (ATTAC).  These  developments inevitably  had  repercussions  inside  the  PS.  Cowed  by  the  renewed  hard-left sentiment,  all  but  a  few  center-left  PS  reformers  muted  their  rhetoric. The  EMU  that  emerged  from  Maastricht  was  decisively  “monetarist,”  de¬ spite  the  French  aim  of  weakening  German  influence  over  European  mone¬ tary  policy.  The  new  European  Central  Bank  would  be  completely  committed to  price  stability,  while  the  treaty  contained  only  vague  language  about  co¬ ordinating  macroeconomic  policy  and  promoting  growth.  Maastricht  also established  strict  convergence  criteria  for  potential  EMU  members,  includ¬ ing  targets  on  national  budget  deficits  (less  than  3%  of  GDP),  debt  levels  (less than  60%  of  GDP),  interest,  and  inflation.  In  1991  France  was  well  placed  to meet  these  targets,  but  this  soon  changed. German  post-unification  policies  helped  fuel  a  European  boomlet  in  1991- 92.  When  the  Bundesbank  tried  to  correct,  it  overshot,  instigating  a  recession that  hit  France  hard.  Failing  to  meet  convergence  targets  was  not  an  option: Reluctantly  Center-Left?  147 without  France  there  could  be  no  EMU,  which  would  have  been  a  disastrous defeat  for  the  European  integration  that  French  statesmen  had  worked  to  pro¬ mote.  Yet  the  new  policy  constraints  inevitably  meant  austerity,  slow  growth, and  higher  unemployment.  The  structural  problems  that  had  emerged  in  the 1980s  would  grow  more  serious  over  time.  In  the  twilight  of  the  Mitterrand years  it  fell  to  the  right  to  deal  with  the  consequences. The  Post-Mitterrand  Era The  era  of  “historic  compromise”  a  la  frangaise,  which  began  with  the  Con¬ gress  of  Epinay  in  1971,  had  thus  reached  its  end.  Mitterrand,  the  inscrutable master  strategist  and  tactician  (known  by  the  sobriquet  “Le  Florentin,”  a  trib¬ ute  to  his  Machiavellian  cunning),  had  been  too  clever  by  half.  His  seduction of  the  Communist  Party  ultimately  sapped  its  sinews,  leaving  a  large  bloc  of voters  no  longer  firmly  moored  a  gauche.  Mitterrand  had  also  taken  various steps  (such  as  the  introduction  of  proportional  representation  for  the  legis¬ lative  elections  of  1986)  to  ensure  that  the  Front  National  would  emerge  as  a serious  competitor  to  the  “legitimate  republican  right,”  but  had  failed  to  fore¬ see  that  the  party  of  Le  Pen  would  attract  some  of  these  now  drifting  voters (or  their  children).  Alternative  parties  of  the  left— Trotskyites  and  Greens  — competed  for  these  votes  as  well,  and  after  fourteen  years  of  Mitterrrandist rule  and  innumerable  scandals,  these  groups  were  even  less  susceptible  to the  blandishments  of  power  than  they  had  been  previously  (doubts  about  the wisdom  of  becoming  “parties  of  government”  had  never  been  extinguished  in these  quarters,  even  in  the  heyday  of  the  Common  Program).  For  these  extra- governmental  leftists,  along  with  parts  of  the  union  movement,  defending  a French  model  that  the  Mitterrand  years  had  undermined  became  a  stock  in trade. As  for  the  Socialists,  with  the  president  in  decline  no  single  voice  could adequately  represent  the  increasingly  cacophonous  party,  once  again  divided into  rival  factions  openly  contending  for  the  post-Mitterrandist  succession. Although  Lionel  Jospin  emerged  as  the  dominant  figure  among  the  cohort  of politico-technocrats  with  whom  Mitterrand  had  surrounded  himself,  he  had no  shortage  of  rivals.  All  were  experienced  in  a  variety  of  ministerial  and  po¬ litical  roles,  but  none  could  claim  Mitterrand’s  mastery  of  the  art  of  politics. Hence  small  technocratic  reforms  took  priority  over  more  ambitious  transfor¬ mations.  More  and  more  voters  came  to  feel  alienated  from  political  life  and unrepresented  at  the  national  level. In  the  wake  of  Maastricht  the  issue  of  whether  to  embrace  or  resist  integra¬ tion  with  the  global  economy  loomed  increasingly  large.  A  deep  fissure  had developed  in  the  Socialist  Party.  Internationalists  — Delors,  Rocard,  Strauss- 148  Goldhammer  and  Ross Kahn— continued  to  support  the  transfer  of  many  economic  decision-making powers  to  the  European  level,  but  a  distinct  left  wing  of  the  party  became  in¬ creasingly  skeptical  of  both  Europe  and  reform.  In  this  the  Socialist  left  wing converged  with  the  Gaullist  right  wing,  although  the  issues  were  framed  in rather  different  terms.  If  the  goal  of  the  socialist  left  was  to  protect  the  French social  model  by  preserving  the  economic  prerogatives  of  the  French  state, on  the  right  it  was  to  preserve  French  sovereignty  and  independence,  which were  seen  as  threatened  not  only  by  rival  states  but  also  by  multinational  cor¬ porations.9 Jacques  Chirac,  head  of  the  Rassemblement  pour  la  Republique  (RPR), the  largest  party  on  the  right,  established  his  claim  to  become  the  right’s  pre¬ sumptive  presidential  candidate  in  1995  after  leading  his  party  to  an  over¬ whelming  victory  in  the  legislative  elections  of  1993.  Meditating  on  his  own experience  under  Mitterrand,  who  had  persuaded  him  to  become  the  first “cohabitation”  prime  minister  in  1986  and  then  defeated  him  in  the  presi¬ dential  election  in  1988,  Chirac  prevailed  on  Edouard  Bahadur  to  accept  the prime  ministership.  On  the  strength  of  strong  opinion  polls  Bahadur  then decided  to  betray  “his  friend  of  thirty  years”  and  challenge  Chirac’s  claim.10 The  unions  subsequently  staged  a  series  of  actions  to  defend  the  social  secu¬ rity  system,  in  protest  against  Bahadur’s  efforts  to  control  the  budget  deficit through  tax  hikes  and  benefit  reductions.  Chirac,  ever  the  political  chame¬ leon,  entered  the  presidential  arena  armed  with  a  new  slogan:  to  “heal  the social  fracture.”11  He  argued  that  the  real  “social  fracture”  was  not  between workers  and  employers  but  rather  between  insiders  and  outsiders  and  prom¬ ised  to  reduce  it  as  president.  This  was  in  part  a  ploy  to  finesse  the  divisions  in his  party  and  bridge  the  gap  between  pro-European  neoliberals,  indifferent, he  implied,  to  the  plight  of  the  excluded,  and  anti-European  “sovereignists,” who  scornfully  dismissed  the  neoliberal  “social  Munich”  but  had  nothing  to offer  insiders  that  would  match  the  benefits  accruing  from  participation  in  an increasingly  globalized  economy. In  effect  the  presidential  election  of  1995  endorsed  a  continuation  of  Mit¬ terrand’s  equivocal  economic  policies:  neither  full  liberalization  and  open¬ ness  nor  outright  decoupling  from  Europe  and  the  global  economy.  After Jacques  Delors  withdrew  from  the  presidential  race,  Lionel  Jospin  easily disposed  of  the  Socialist  secretary  general  Henri  Emmanuelli.  The  Social¬ ist  center-left  thus  gained  ascendancy  over  the  party’s  left.  Chirac  defeated Jospin  in  the  second  round,  drawing  votes  from  his  right,  which  had  nowhere else  to  go,  as  well  as  from  the  center.  Chirac  was  elected  with  just  under  53% of  the  vote. Observers  believed  that  Chirac  came  into  office  in  a  position  of  strength. Reluctantly  Center-Left?  149 He  had  supplanted  a  tired  Socialist  regime,  defeated  a  serious  rival  in  his  own camp,  and  enjoyed  a  majority  of  80%  in  the  National  Assembly  (as  a  result  of the  right’s  impressive  victory  in  the  legislative  elections  in  1993).  He  also  con¬ trolled  the  Senate  and  most  regional  and  departmental  councils.  Neverthe¬ less  Chirac,  whose  instinct  was  to  err  by  excess  of  caution,  had  to  be  dragged into  reform  by  his  prime  minister  Alain  Juppe,  who  forcefully  pointed  out that  the  problems  Bahadur  had  been  trying  to  solve  remained  as  obdurate  as ever.  In  order  to  meet  the  requirements  imposed  by  the  EMU,  Chirac  would have  to  reduce  the  budget  deficit.  The  problem  had  indeed  grown  to  serious proportions:  between  1990  and  1995  the  social  security  deficit  had  more  than quintupled,  doubling  as  a  share  of  the  total  deficit.  Bahadur  had  attempted  to reduce  the  shortfall  through  privatizations,  but  one-time  proceeds  from  the sale  of  national  enterprises  could  do  little  to  halt  the  rapid  increase  in  out¬ lays  for  medical  care  and  retirement  benefits.  A  more  drastic  overhaul  was inevitable. In  short  order  Juppe  had  a  plan.  Its  thoroughness,  professionalism,  and impeccable  arithmetic  drew  wide  admiration  from  intellectuals,  editorialists, and  much  of  the  political  class,  including  followers  of  the  Socialist  Michel Rocard  and  the  CFDT  trade  union,  eager  to  establish  its  reformist  bona  fides as  a  “modern”  union  that  understood  the  trade-off  between  short-term  wage restraint  and  long-term  growth.  The  plan  included  a  provision  to  require  the parliament  to  vote  each  year  on  a  social  security  financing  plan  (this  was  in¬ corporated  into  the  Constitution  in  February  1996).  There  were  other  signifi¬ cant  innovations  as  well,  such  as  the  Contribution  for  the  Reimbursement of  the  Social  Debt  (CRDS),  a  new  tax  set  at  0.5%  of  revenue  to  pay  off  the accumulated  social  security  deficit;  a  1%  increase  in  the  Generalized  Social Contribution,  or  CSG  (described  earlier);  a  1.2%  increase  in  health  insurance payments  by  retired  and  unemployed  workers;  a  one-time  tax  on  the  pharma¬ ceutical  industry;  reduction  of  maternity  benefits;  a  structural  reform  of  the hospital  system;  and  a  host  of  lesser  measures.12 The  plan  may  have  been  technically  seductive,  but  since  it  had  been  elabo¬ rated  in  secret  and  announced  as  a  fait  accompli,  it  proved  politically  dis¬ astrous.  A  perceived  attack  on  railway  workers,  who  enjoyed  an  especially favorable  special  retirement  regime,  led  to  a  strike  that  brought  the  country to  a  standstill  for  several  weeks,  and  many  other  categories  of  workers  in both  the  public  and  private  sectors  supported  the  strikers  because  they  felt that  their  own  pensions  were  threatened.13  Juppe,  seriously  weakened  by  the strikes,  was  forced  to  withdraw  much  of  his  reform  program,  although  he hung  onto  his  job  for  more  than  a  year. The  social  fracture  rhetoric  that  had  got  Chirac  elected  thus  found  little 150  Goldhammer  and  Ross translation  into  concrete  policy.  To  be  sure,  modest  health  insurance  reform was  enacted,  and  “urban  development  zones”  were  established  in  the  hope of  reducing  unemployment  in  the  suburbs.  In  addition,  the  Contrat  Initia¬ tives  Emploi  (CIE)  did  create  fifty  thousand  new  jobs,  but  it  cost  twelve  bil¬ lion  francs.  Here  was  yet  another  stab  at  what  had  come  to  be  called  “social treatment  of  unemployment,”  by  now  a  venerable  tradition.  The  unemploy¬ ment  rate  did  begin  to  decline  slowly,  although  critics  claimed  that  the  offi¬ cial  statistics  understated  the  real  scope  of  the  problem.  By  subsidizing  entry- level  jobs  and  protecting  workers  in  uncompetitive  firms,  government  policy discouraged  long-term  hires  and  the  kind  of  deeper  structural  reform  being tried  elsewhere.  Firms  were  encouraged  to  supply  temporary  labor  needs with  subsidized  interim  workers  rather  than  invest  in  productivity-enhancing technology. Chirac’s  master  counterstroke,  in  reserve  since  the  election,  was  to  dissolve parliament  in  the  spring  of  1997.  In  his  mind  this  maneuver  would  relegiti¬ mate  his  presidency  and  revive  his  mandate.  The  right-wing  majority  in  the National  Assembly,  in  place  since  1993,  had  grown  restive,  and  Chirac  hoped that  the  maneuver  would  reestablish  his  control  over  his  own  party’s  depu¬ ties.  Polls  indicated  that  although  the  prime  minister  was  unpopular,  so  was the  left,  and  Chirac  expected  a  new  and  reinforced  majority  to  emerge  from the  early  election  (the  next  scheduled  parliamentary  election  was  not  until 1998).  He  was  wrong.  Jospin,  the  last  avatar  of  the  Mitterrandist  “Socialo- Communist”  coalition  scored  43%  in  the  first  round  of  voting,  easily  outstrip¬ ping  the  RPR  with  36.5  and  the  Front  National  with  15. Thus  Lionel  Jospin  became  prime  minister,  and  for  the  next  five  years Chirac  would  be  obliged  to  “cohabit”  with  the  man  he  had  defeated  for  the presidency  only  two  years  before.  Yet  this  stroke  of  good  luck  for  the  Social¬ ists  also  inaugurated  a  period  in  which  they  sought  to  appease  the  extra- governmental  left  and  their  own  left  wing  with  policies  in  which  they  did not  fully  believe  while  at  the  same  time  hoping  that  the  expanded  European market,  which  they  did  not  wholeheartedly  embrace,  would  bring  sufficient economic  improvement  to  carry  them  through  the  next  presidential  election. It  was  not  an  unreasonable  hope,  because  French  growth  had  shown  signs  of recovery,  with  new  jobs  created  and  unemployment  declining.  Yet  this  tem¬ porary  good  news  only  allowed  the  party  to  postpone  reconsideration  of  its core  principles. French  Socialists  had  not  been  obliged  to  conquer  power  by  adapting  to a  political  landscape  fundamentally  reshaped  by  powerful  conservative  pre¬ decessors  like  Thatcher  or  Reagan.  Instead  they  had  power  handed  to  them by  the  blunders  of  Chirac  and  Juppe.  Once  in  power,  the  party  therefore Reluctantly  Center-Left?  151 found  itself  saddled  with  a  program  even  more  incoherent  than  political  pro¬ grams  generally  are.  The  party  platform  for  1997  included  a  plank  calling  for a  thirty-five-hour  week.  Dominique  Strauss-Kahn,  who  had  put  it  there,  later said  that  he  would  not  have  done  so  if  he  had  foreseen  that  the  left  might  win. Unanticipated  victory  forced  the  government  to  make  good  on  its  promise. The  chief  burden  of  the  change  fell  on  smaller  firms,  which  found  the  “flexi¬ bility”  envisioned  by  the  law  difficult  to  achieve.  This  difficulty  durably  alien¬ ated  a  segment  of  the  centrist  electorate,  especially  middle  managers  and small  business  owners,  whose  support  the  Socialists  would  desperately  need in  future  presidential  elections.  Some  blue-collar  workers  also  resented  the loss  of  overtime  opportunities. The  left  also  enacted  the  so-called  Emploi-Jeunes  or  Youth  Employment Act  in  1997,  creating  a  new  type  of  state-subsidized  five-year  labor  contract. The  jobs  were  often  with  local  government  or  charitable  service  agencies, and  while  the  intention  was  to  equip  otherwise  unemployable  youths  with “employment  skills,”  again  there  was  no  stimulus  to  subsequent  hiring  by  the private  sector.  Employment  did  increase  toward  the  end  of  the  1990s,  raising false  hopes  that  these  modest  employment  measures,  together  with  continu¬ ing  social  security  reforms  similar  to  those  already  undertaken  by  the  right, would  soon  set  things  right. In  more  Eurocentric  Socialist  circles,  there  was  considerable  hope— and a  certain  naivete— about  the  anticipated  benefits  from  the  post-Maastricht European  Union.  In  an  interview  in  1997,  Jean-Pierre  Jouyet,  Jacques  Delors’s chief  of  staff  in  Brussels  before  assuming  responsibility  for  European  affairs as  a  member  of  Jospin’s  staff,14  envisioned  the  “political  union  of  Europe through  economic  harmonization  within  ten  years.”15  Optimism  was  buoy¬ ant  and  at  first  seemed  justified,  as  temporary  economic  improvement  led  to Socialist  success  in  the  European  Parliament  elections  of  1999,  while  Nicolas Sarkozy,  who  led  the  right-wing  slate  on  a  neoliberal  platform,  was  beaten badly.  But  the  incoherence  of  the  left’s  program  soon  began  to  take  its  toll. Annual  hours  worked  per  capita  dropped  to  one  of  the  lowest  levels  in  the OECD  as  the  thirty-five-hour  week  took  hold,  social  policy  expenses  grew,  and subsidized  low-end  jobs  weighed  on  the  budget  without  increasing  aggregate demand.  The  average  retirement  age  fell.  Workforce  participation  declined, especially  for  youths  and  seniors.  All  of  this  magnified  the  budget  deficit,  and when  the  economy  turned  downward  after  2001,  divisions  within  the  left  and the  PS  about  the  wisdom  of  “deepening”  the  European  Union  were  exacer¬ bated. Jospin’s  government  also  moved  on  a  second  social  front.  In  addition  to shortening  the  work  week  it  expanded  and  reformed  medical  insurance  with 152  Goldhammer  and  Ross the  couverture  maladie  universelle  (CMU,  or  universal  health  coverage),  which was  adopted  on  27  July  1999.16  The  CMU  not  only  expanded  coverage  but  also made  supplementary  private  insurance  available  to  some  five  million  people who  could  not  otherwise  afford  it. As  the  presidential  election  of  2002  approached,  the  disaffection  from what  the  French  call  la  classe  politique— the  established  party  leaderships  of both  the  left  and  the  right— was  glaringly  apparent  despite  extensive  reform¬ ing  since  Chirac’s  election.  In  1995  the  abstention  rate  had  been  20%,  the highest  in  any  presidential  election  in  the  Fifth  Republic,  and  after  seven years  of  confusion,  in  which  the  left  and  right  had  “cohabited”  to  pursue reforms  that  seemed  to  mirror  one  another,  a  substantial  number  of  voters concluded  that  it  hardly  mattered  who  won.  The  smaller  parties  of  the  left, convinced  that  the  Socialist  Party  had  been  taken  over  by  technocrats,  saw no  particular  utility  in  attempting  to  achieve  unity  in  the  pre-election  period, and  all  contested  Jospin’s  claim  to  represent  the  undivided  opposition. Lionel  Jospin,  on  the  other  hand,  had  little  taste  for  the  hard-left  rheto¬ ric  that  Socialist  leaders  habitually  mobilized  to  try  to  cement  a  coalition  of the  left  in  anticipation  of  an  electoral  test  of  strength  with  the  right.  As  un¬ employment  continued  unabated,  immigration  and  security  became  major issues.  Inflation  and  stagnant  wages  (with  a  compressed  wage  spectrum owing  to  a  high  minimum  wage  and  subsidized  entry-level  jobs)  persuaded many  workers  that  their  standard  of  living  was  falling  because  of  the  EU  and globalization.  To  top  it  all  off,  Jospin  waged  a  singularly  passionless  and  lack¬ luster  campaign.  Disaster  followed.  Jean-Marie  Le  Pen  narrowly  outpolled Jospin  in  the  first  round  of  the  election,  16.9%  to  16.2.  An  anti-Le  Pen  coali¬ tion  then  gave  Chirac  more  than  80%  of  the  vote  in  the  second  round. The  verdict  of  the  polls  was  harsh  but  not  incomprehensible.  The  Social¬ ists  had  demonstrated  that  they  were  no  worse,  and  indeed  probably  better, at  managing  the  market  economy  than  their  opponents.  They  had  promised their  voters  something  more,  but  had  been  unable  to  define  clearly  what  this was  or  whether  it  aimed  at  success  in  the  globalized  economy  or  at  some vaguely  adumbrated  “social  market”  alternative.  They  were  at  pains  to  deny that  their  approach  to  globalized  capitalism  had  anything  in  common  with any  sort  of  “third  way”  compromise.  Yet  the  policy  package  on  offer  from  the left  was  similar  to  that  on  offer  from  the  right:  adjustment  of  the  fiscal  sys¬ tem  to  maintain  social  spending  at  a  steady  level  while  shifting  the  burden from  payrolls  to  a  broader  citizen  base;  a  variety  of  labor-market  activation policies  (job  search  assistance,  job  retraining,  continuing  education,  benefit reform);  and  social  security  reform  to  take  account  of  demographic  changes. This  policy  convergence  reduced  the  electoral  contest  to  a  battle  over  tech- Reluctantly  Center-Left?  153 nical  details:  modifications  to  the  legal  work  week  (such  as  haggling  over  de¬ tails  of  compensatory  time,  overtime  pay,  etc.),  the  precise  package  of  retire¬ ment  reforms,  the  mix  of  broad-based  versus  payroll  taxes. The  left’s  policy  package  satisfied  no  one.  Adherents  of  the  “second  left”  — mainly  university- educated  “knowledge  workers”  whose  politics  had  been forged  in  the  anticolonial  and  cultural  struggles  of  the  1960s  and  1970s— were  put  off  by  what  they  saw  as  band-aid  measures  and  rhetorical  appease¬ ment:  subsidized  McJobs  (such  as  the  Emplois-Jeunes),  protectionism,  and “economic  patriotism”  (denunciation  of  plant  closings  and  investments  by “Anglo-Saxon  pension  funds,”  predatory  hedge  funds,  etc.).  Workers  and  mili¬ tant  schoolteachers  (who  made  up  the  rank  and  file  in  more  than  one  Socialist Party  federation)  preferred  the  old  class-against-class  rhetoric  and  resented the  dominance  in  the  party  leadership  of  graduates  of  elite  schools  such  as Sciences  Po  and  the  Ecole  Nationale  d’Administration  (ENA).  Much  of  the policy  effort  of  this  elite  went  into  devising  strategies  to  preserve  the  insti¬ tutions  of  the  French  welfare  state  through  small-scale  reforms  rather  than understanding  the  profound  transformation  of  the  global  economy.  The  idea that  competition  might  require  radical  restructuring  of  the  production  pro¬ cess,  quick  response  to  exploit  niche  markets,  and  investment  in  productivity¬ enhancing  high-technology  back-office  systems  was  too  politically  challeng¬ ing  to  take  on.  Despite  fitful  efforts  to  revamp  universities  and  promote  closer cooperation  between  academic  research  and  industrial  R&D,  the  deepening fiscal  crisis  limited  what  might  have  been  done  even  if  more  attention  had been  devoted  to  growth-enhancement  policies. From  his  peculiar  if  lopsided  victory  Chirac  concluded  that  he  could  con¬ tinue  to  muddle  through,  provided  that  he  did  nothing  energetic  enough  to upset  the  applecart.  In  a  conciliatory  gesture  that  confirmed  this  strategy, he  appointed  Jean-Pierre  Raffarin,  a  lackluster  Giscardian  centrist,  as  prime minister.  The  one  undeniable  success  of  his  presidency— eight  years  after  the debacle  of  the  Juppe  plan— was  a  partial  overhaul  of  the  retirement  system for  which  his  minister  of  social  affairs,  Franqois  Fillon,  working  closely  with CFDT  head  Frangois  Chereque,  was  chiefly  responsible.  By  leaving  the  so- called  special  retirement  regimes  intact,  Fillon  and  Chirac  avoided  a  repeti¬ tion  of  the  paralysis  of  1995,  because  transport  workers  remained  untouched. In  2003  nature  turned  against  Chirac,  as  a  terrible  heat  wave  led  to  fifteen hundred  deaths,  mainly  of  the  elderly.  The  loss  of  life  was  probably  com¬ pounded  by  shortages  of  personnel  in  hospital  emergency  rooms,  due  in  part to  cutbacks  in  the  medical  care  budget,  as  well  as  by  staff  management  prob¬ lems  that  arose  after  reduction  of  the  workweek. If  Europe  and  the  EMU  had  been  the  undoing  of  Chirac’s  first  term,  it  was 154  Goldhammer  and  Ross again  Europe  that  undid  his  second.  Progress  toward  a  European  constitu¬ tional  treaty,  responsibility  for  which  Chirac  had  assigned  to  his  old  nemesis Giscard,  led  the  president,  perhaps  concerned  as  much  with  dividing  the  left as  with  the  EU,  to  seek  approval  in  a  referendum  in  May  2005.  Once  again polls  had  indicated  initially  that  the  referendum  course  would  be  safe;  ma¬ jorities  of  up  to  70%  were  predicted.  In  the  event,  however,  the  referendum went  down  to  defeat  by  a  margin  of  55  to  45%.  The  Socialist  Party  remained split  on  the  issue,  while  opposition  within  the  UMP,  though  not  inconsid¬ erable,  was  tamped  down  by  Nicolas  Sarkozy,  the  erstwhile  protege  first  of Chirac  and  then  of  Bahadur,  who  remained  strongly  pro-Europe. Sacrificing  Raffarin  to  atone  for  this  gaffe,  Chirac  then  made  his  second  big blunder,  appointing  the  impetuous  Dominique  de  Villepin,  his  only  remain¬ ing  confidant  and  the  architect  of  the  ill-fated  dissolution  of  parliament  in 1997,  to  head  the  government.  Villepin,  who  entertained  presidential  ambi¬ tions  for  2007,  had  hoped  to  upstage  his  rival  Sarkozy,  but  events  intervened. In  late  2005  riots  erupted  in  a  suburb  of  Paris  after  two  youths  died  while attempting  to  evade  the  police.  Then  early  in  2006  Villepin  launched  a  new attack  on  the  unemployment  problem  by  proposing  a  “first  hire  contract”  to encourage  the  employment  of  young  workers  — yet  another  half-measure  in lieu  of  a  comprehensive  reform  of  labor  laws.  Students  took  to  the  streets  in protest,  universities  were  shut  down  by  strikes,  and  there  was  sporadic  vio¬ lence.  Villepin  dug  in  and  refused  to  withdraw  the  bill.  The  episode  came  to a  comic  conclusion  when  Chirac,  bafflingly  silent  throughout  the  mounting unrest,  finally  decided  to  allow  the  bill  to  become  law  while  promising  at  the same  time  that  it  would  not  be  “promulgated,”  meaning  that  it  would  remain a  dead  letter.  This  effectively  ended  his  presidency,  though  he  would  remain in  office  for  another  year,  and  it  reduced  Villepin’s  presidential  aspirations  to ashes.  Sarkozy  remained  the  only  viable  candidate  on  the  right. Meanwhile,  the  Socialist  Party  under  the  leadership  of  Frangois  Hollande had  made  no  progress  toward  resolving  its  internal  divisions.  The  center-left had  its  champion  in  Dominique  Strauss-Kahn;  Laurent  Fabius,  a  centrist  at heart  who  had  opportunistically  become  a  leader  of  the  “no”  camp  in  the  EU constitutional  referendum  of  2005,  proposed  himself  to  lead  the  party’s  left wing.  Hollande  hoped  to  paper  over  the  division  between  left  and  center- left  with  a  new  procedure  to  designate  the  presidential  candidate,  which  he hoped  would  lead  to  a  compromise  candidate,  perhaps  himself.  Membership of  the  party  was  thus  opened  up  to  anyone  willing  to  pay  a  membership  fee of  20  euros,  with  no  obligation  to  attend  meetings,  serve  the  party,  or  par¬ ticipate  in  internal  debates.  All  members  could  then  vote  in  an  internal  party primary  to  name  the  candidate.  In  preparation  there  was  unprecedented Reluctantly  Center-Left?  155 televised  debate  among  the  contenders,  whose  chances  of  success  against Sarkozy  were  constantly  monitored  through  opinion  polls.  Although  many long-standing  party  members  preferred  one  of  the  so-called  elephants— party  stalwarts  and  courant  leaders  such  as  Dominique  Strauss-Kahn,  Lau¬ rent  Fabius,  or  Jack  Lang— it  was  ultimately  not  Hollande  but  his  longtime companion  and  mother  of  his  children,  Segolene  Royal,  who  won.  President of  the  Poitou-Charentes  region,  Royal  was  popular,  telegenic,  and  well  known because  of  service  in  Jospin’s  government  as  minister  of  the  environment, among  other  roles.  She  routed  her  opponents,  drawing  over  60%  in  the  party primary. Yet  Sarkozy,  who  in  2004  had  assumed  leadership  of  the  Union  pour  un Mouvement  Populaire  (UMP),  had  a  considerable  head  start,  having  had  time to  reshape  the  party  into  a  support  vehicle  for  his  presidential  ambitions. Though  Sarkozy  was  a  bitter  foe  of  Chirac,  the  president  had  been  unable to  avoid  appointing  his  popular  young  rival  to  various  ministerial  posts,  and while  at  Interior,  for  example,  Sarkozy  had  used  his  media  skills  to  put  vari¬ ous  hot-button  issues  such  as  crime,  immigration,  and  religion  at  the  fore¬ front  of  the  political  agenda.  His  strategy  was  clear:  to  woo  Front  National voters  by  taking  a  strong  line  on  these  divisive  social  issues  while  pushing for  neoliberal  reforms  such  as  reduction  of  the  wealth  tax  and  estate  tax,  de¬ taxation  of  overtime  hours  and  other  revisions  of  the  thirty-five-hour  week, reform  of  the  special  retirement  regimes,  labor-market  activation,  and  em¬ ployment  contract  reform  that  might  appeal  to  a  broad  swath  of  center-right and  even  center-left  voters  disappointed  with  the  Socialists’  lack  of  clarity  on economic  policy.  Although  Francois  Bayrou,  the  independent  centrist  candi¬ date,  made  a  strong  showing  in  the  first  round,  Royal  survived  only  to  be  de¬ feated  by  Sarkozy,  who  took  53%  of  the  vote. Sarkozy’s  approval  rating  immediately  after  the  election  rose  to  above 70%,  a  level  scarcely  seen  in  the  history  of  the  Fifth  Republic,  and  the  stage seemed  set  for  quick  enactment  of  his  program.  Although  he  did  manage  to enact  reforms  on  a  wide  front  with  less  opposition  than  might  have  been  ex¬ pected,  by  the  end  of  2007  his  popularity  had  begun  to  plummet,  and  by  Feb¬ ruary  2008  it  had  dropped  below  that  of  Chirac  after  the  strikes  of  1995.  Wide¬ spread  criticism  of  Sarkozy’s  presidential  style  and  exposure  of  his  turbulent private  life  contributed  to  this.  With  the  increasingly  unfavorable  economic conjuncture  in  the  wake  of  the  American  subprime  debacle  and  subsequent global  credit  squeeze,  anxiety  about  the  future  of  the  French  social  model  re¬ surfaced.  Sarkozy,  like  Chirac  before  him,  had  been  elected  not  to  dismantle the  welfare  state  but  to  introduce  sufficient  modifications  to  preserve  it.  What had  seemed  bold  in  May  2007  seemed  a  year  later  not  to  be  enough,  while 156  Goldhammer  and  Ross Sarkozy  had  apparently  lost  the  ability  to  persuade  his  countrymen  that  con¬ fidence  and  energy  alone  are  enough  to  overcome  all  obstacles.  Any  final judgment  on  his  presidency,  however,  would  be  premature. WE  BEGAN  BY  claiming  that  the  story  of  the  French  left  since  1970  could  best be  understood  by  examining  the  lasting  effects  of  three  factors:  persistent division  on  the  left,  firm  adherence  to  the  “French  social  model,”  and  the  cen¬ tral  role  of  the  presidency.  These  persistent  influences  continue  to  shape  the French  left  today,  but  their  surface  manifestations  have  evolved  considerably. The  fundamental  cleavage  on  the  left  is  no  longer  that  which  once  sepa¬ rated  the  Socialist  Party  from  the  Communist  Party.  The  PCF  was  never exactly  a  revolutionary  party,  despite  unstinting  support  for  Soviet  interests, but  its  vocation  had  never  really  been  to  govern  either.  The  Common  Pro¬ gram  of  the  1970s  transformed  it  into  a  party  interested  in  governing  but  did not  entirely  dissipate  the  conviction  of  a  part  of  the  population  (and  of  the PCF  itself)  that  the  best  way  to  protect  the  interests  of  the  “people  of  the  left” was  less  to  influence  government  policy  than  to  oppose  it.  This  sentiment, though  less  powerful  than  it  once  was,  continues  to  motivate  perhaps  10-15% of  voters,  who  cast  their  votes  for  the  parties  of  the  extreme  left,  the  extreme right,  the  Communist  rump,  and  even  the  Greens,  in  the  hope  of  demonstrat¬ ing  a  disruptive  potential  sufficient  to  inhibit  governments  from  pursuing  re¬ forms  deemed  to  be  aimed  at  dismantling  the  French  social  model. The  Socialist  Party  itself  is  divided  internally,  although  the  divisions  were temporarily  damped  down  by  Mitterrand’s  leadership  and  success.  Both  had worn  out  by  1995,  however,  and  since  that  date  the  PS’s  internal  cleavages have  become  more  important  than  those  that  divide  the  left  more  gener¬ ally.  In  recent  years  these  divisions  have  crystallized  most  visibly  around  the question  of  Europe.  The  referendum  of  2005  on  the  European  Constitutional Treaty  made  it  clear  that  despite  a  substantial  pro-Europe  majority  within  the party,  considerable  anti-Europe  sentiment  persisted:  41%  of  militants  wanted the  party  to  oppose  the  proposed  European  constitution;  26  of  102  party  fed¬ erations  turned  out  majorities  in  favor  of  a  “no”  vote. The  basis  of  this  opposition  is  quite  different  from  the  negativism  of  the extra-governmental  left.  For  the  latter,  which  also  opposed  a  strengthened “Europe,”  the  French  state,  no  matter  who  controls  it,  is  helpless  in  the  face of  Europeanization  and  global  capitalism.  True  political  action  can  then  take only  two  forms:  using  the  electoral  process  as  a  “forum”  to  give  voice  to  those hurt  by  neoliberal  globalism,  and  resorting  to  extra-governmental  activity (mobilization  on  the  picket  line,  on  the  shop  floor,  and  in  the  streets).  Its aim  must  be  defensive:  to  protect  what  remains  of  the  French  social  model by  blocking  reform  efforts  decried  as  camouflaged  destruction.  For  the  left Reluctantly  Center-Left?  157 wing  of  the  Socialist  Party,  by  contrast,  the  political  objective  is  rather  to strengthen  the  state  against  supranational  and  transnational  institutions  be¬ lieved  to  be  intent  on  eroding  the  French  social  model.  The  state  is  supposed to  stand  between  labor  and  capital,  just  as  the  king  once  stood  (symbolically if  not  in  reality)  between  the  people  and  the  nobility. All  Socialists  thus  see  their  part  as  very  much  a  party  of  government,  one whose  raison  d’etre,  unlike  that  of  extra-governmental  leftists,  is  to  win  elec¬ tions  and  exercise  power.  Their  version  of  the  socialist  project  takes  the  form of  policy  prescriptions  applicable  to  things  as  they  are,  not  things  as  they might  be  if  the  rapport  des  forces  were  somehow  different.  Yet  a  division  re¬ mains  between  those  who  have  deeply  internalized  the  U-turn  of  1981-83  as a  step  in  the  right  direction  and  those  who  look  back  on  it  as  a  mistake.  The former  like  to  describe  themselves  as  modernizers,  and  since  1995  they  have been  touting  the  need  for  a  “renovated”  party.  “Modernization”  is  of  course a  capacious  word,  invoked  to  justify  political  programs  of  both  right  and  left since  the  Franco-Prussian  War.  In  the  present  context,  however,  the  central claim  of  center-left  modernizers  is  that  the  scale  of  the  capitalist  system  has changed;  production,  finance,  and  the  supply  of  labor  have  all  become  global¬ ized  to  a  much  greater  degree  since  1970  and  especially  since  the  mid-1980s. To  maintain  social  protections,  therefore,  political  and  social  actors  must  see the  state  that  they  wish  to  influence  as  part  of  a  supranational  institutional network.  The  political  game  therefore  becomes  multilevel  and  far  more  com¬ plex  than  in  earlier  periods. The  Socialist  modernizers  thus  emphasize  the  international  dimension  of policy  and  especially  the  constraints  imposed  on  domestic  economic  policy  by France’s  implication  in  a  global  system.  Acceptance  of  what  might  be  called “center-left”  outlooks  — the  importance  of  price  stability,  fiscal  self-control, economic  flexibility,  and  the  need  to  innovate  constantly— follows  from  this. Their  opponents  focus  rather  on  the  internal  politics  of  the  nation-state.  For them  the  central  problem  is  less  to  find  optimal  economic  policies  than  to change  the  rapport  des  forces  to  give  greater  weight  to  the  preferences  of left-wing  voters  generally  rather  than  those  of  left  policy  elites,  which  are often  quite  similar  to  the  preferences  of  right  policy  elites.  In  sum,  the  left is  now  effectively  tripartite:  the  extra-governmental  left  opposes  both  (stat¬ ist)  nationalists  and  (internationalist)  modernizers.  All  three  factions  invoke preservation  of  the  French  social  model,  our  second  persistent  influence,  as the  primary  objective  of  politics.  The  problem  is  that  their  definitions  of  the core  of  the  social  model  vary.  In  addition,  each  faction  of  the  left  believes  that the  others’  preferred  means  of  achieving  the  common  goal  will  lead  to  disas¬ ter  in  the  future  as  it  has  done  in  the  past. To  win  big  elections,  especially  the  all-important  presidency,  some  kind 158  Goldhammer  and  Ross Table  1.  Fragmentation  of  the  French  Left Extragovernmental Left Socialist  Left Socialist  Center Strategic  orientation Obstructive National-statist International- multilevel Policy  preference Defend  social  gains Defend  social  gains, make  governing institutions  more representative, decentralize Maintain productivity, reform  universities, fund  R&D Europe Oppose Oppose Support Tactical  orientation Streets,  shop  floor, picket  lines Institutional  reform Economic governance of  political  unity  must  be  engineered  out  of  division.  Although  the  elements have  changed,  unity  is  no  easier  to  achieve  now  than  it  was  in  the  1970s (table  1).  Socialist  modernizers  have  to  conciliate  nationalists  and  seduce extra-governmental  parties  and  movements  to  have  a  chance  of  winning. Lionel  Jospin  refused  to  do  this  in  2002,  instead  campaigning  as  if  only  the second  round  runoff  counted,  and  he  failed  disastrously.  It  is  very  likely  that when  modernizers  do  try  to  broaden  their  political  base  they  will  end  up being  bound  to  programmatic  concessions  and  promises  that  they  will  have difficulty  redeeming  without  sacrificing  “modernizing”  realism. This  reconfiguration  of  the  left  political  contest  parallels  underlying  eco¬ nomic  and  social  changes.  With  the  relative  decline  of  heavy  industry  and mass  production,  the  old  armies  of  blue-clad  factory  workers  have  dimin¬ ished  in  size  and  militancy.  The  unionization  rate  in  France  has  fallen  to  the lowest  level  in  Europe  (7%).  The  workforce  has  become  increasingly  differen¬ tiated  and  better  educated.  Service  and  support  workers  outnumber  skilled and  semiskilled  industrial  workers.  The  patron  of  old  — be  he  paternalistic guardian  or  Zolaesque  taskmaster— is  now  buffered  by  squadrons  of  well- educated  cadres  versed  in  the  techniques  of  human  resource  management. Older  images  of  social  conflict  have  partly  given  way  to  new  images.  Yet  the older  images  sometimes  resurface  in  misleading  ways,  as  in  the  demonstra¬ tions  against  the  first  hire  contract  in  2006. Again,  the  centrality  of  the  presidency— and  of  Mitterrand’s  strategy  for winning  it,  the  only  successful  left  strategy  to  date— cannot  be  ignored.  The triumphant  Common  Program  sustained  an  unnatural  hybrid  of  a  workers’ party  with  a  clientelist  party  built  on  the  representation  of  a  variety  of  local Reluctantly  Center-Left?  159 interests  (including  workers’  interests)  and  competition  among  internal  fac¬ tions  and  grouplets.  Neither  party  to  the  coalition  had  a  clear  agenda  for  na¬ tional  rule  or  a  deep  comprehension  of  the  priorities  that  would  need  to  be addressed  after  capturing  the  presidency.  Mitterrand  therefore  called  upon a  cohort  of  technocrats  to  fill  key  positions  in  the  government  and  adminis¬ tration.  These  people,  creatures  of  Mitterrand  and  entirely  beholden  to  him for  their  political  careers,  have  dominated  the  party  in  the  first  decade  of  the twenty-first  century:  witness  the  contest  to  become  the  presidential  candi¬ date  in  2007,  which  pitted  Segolene  Royal  against  Dominique  Strauss-Kahn and  Laurent  Fabius  — all  three  enarques  (graduates  of  ENA),  all  three  former ministers,  all  three  deeply  imbued  with  a  top-down,  presidentialist  vision  of the  political  process. Presidentialism  has  created  a  problem  of  credibility  for  the  Socialists  as the  society  has  changed  under  them.  A  presidential  campaign,  if  it  is  not  to sink  beneath  a  welter  of  tedious  prescriptions  for  improvement  tous  azimuts, must  articulate  a  clear  and  comprehensible  transformative  vision.  For  Mitter¬ rand  it  was  enough  to  give  voice  to  the  democratic  desire  for  alternance.  By 1981  voters  who  had  never  recognized  themselves  in  Gaullism  could  be  satis¬ fied  with  the  prospect  of  wielding  power  for  the  first  time.  But  in  the  nearly thirty  years  since  the  Socialists’  U-turn  of  1983,  the  Socialists  have  become  an established  party  of  government.  Like  their  opponents  on  the  right  they  have pursued  piecemeal  reforms  designed  to  shore  up  the  welfare  state,  some  of which  have  actually  helped  France  face  the  future.  Yet  unlike  the  right,  they have  not  been  able  to  articulate  a  new  transformative  message  to  embellish their  skillful  technocratic  management. The  center-left  core  of  the  Socialist  Party  has  been  struggling  since  1995 to  define  what  a  “modernized  and  renovated”  socialist  program  should  look like.  The  result  has  been  to  cement  old  divisions  and  heighten  mutual  sus¬ picion  among  party  factions,  albeit  with  new  faces  to  represent  them.  In keeping  with  the  training,  predilections,  and  government  experience  of  its key  leaders,  the  center-left  has  emphasized  the  need  for  economic  reform  to maintain  (insofar  as  possible)  the  productivity  and  competitiveness  on  which the  welfare  state  depends.  In  many  respects  the  reforms  that  it  advocates  re¬ semble  those  favored  by  the  center-right.  The  center-left’s  appeal  to  the  me¬ dian  voter  thus  relies  on  trust:  we  advocate  reforms  similar  to  those  proposed by  the  center-right,  but  we  promise  you  a  more  favorable  distribution  of  the expected  fruits  of  growth.  It  is  a  vision  predicated  on  centralized  power,  be¬ nevolent  expertise,  and  a  not-too-restive  base.  By  contrast,  the  Socialist  left wing  is  more  responsive  to  the  fears  of  its  base  that  economic  reforms  rep¬ resent  a  camouflaged  attack  on  hard-won  popular  victories  of  the  past.  The i6o  Goldhammer  and  Ross quarrel  is  really  over  what  constitutes  the  core  of  the  French  social  model.  Is it  basically  a  bargain  over  the  distribution  of  gains  from  economic  growth, in  which  case  the  maintenance  of  growth  is  crucial?  Or  is  it  rather  compa¬ rable  to  a  military  campaign,  in  which  social  gains  are  objectives  which,  once seized,  must  be  held  at  all  cost,  to  limit  the  strategic  options  of  “the  enemy?” To  counter  the  institutional  power  of  “the  economists,”  the  left  wing  advo¬ cates  institutional  change  that  would  shift  power  away  from  the  central  ad¬ ministration  and  toward  parliament,  regions,  and  cities.  Decentralization,  it is  hoped,  will  both  multiply  the  range  of  voices  in  governing  councils  and  de¬ finitively  alter  the  priorities  of  policymaking. The  presidential  candidacy  of  Segolene  Royal  in  2007  can  be  viewed  as  an attempt  to  bridge  these  gaps.  Some  of  her  key  advisors  were  from  the  Social¬ ist  left,  and  the  candidate’s  emphasis  on  “citizen  juries”  and  elimination  of the  cumul  des  mandats  (holding  of  multiple  offices)  directly  translated  some of  the  left’s  platform  planks  for  institutional  reform.  Yet  she  also  signaled  a readiness  to  accommodate  the  “economists”  of  the  center-left  by  associating herself  with  Blairism,  a  conveniently  vague  portmanteau  word  standing  for “Anglo-Saxon  neoliberalism  with  a  human  face.”  More  substantively,  she  sig¬ naled  flexibility  on  reform  of  the  thirty-five-hour  week,  labor  contracts,  and retirement  benefits.  Like  others  before  it,  this  attempted  reconciliation  foun¬ dered  on  incomprehension  and  lack  of  trust.  In  this  case,  though,  it  was  not the  rank  and  file  that  feared  betrayal  by  elite  economists;  it  was  rather  the economists  who  feared  that  Royal,  having  spent  her  career  without  passing by  way  of  the  central  posts  of  economic  policymaking,  could  not  be  trusted to  execute  or  even  understand  the  nature  of  the  necessary  economic  reforms. Hostility  to  Royal  was  again  evident  in  the  selection  of  a  new  leader  of  the Socialist  Party.  The  process  of  “renovation”  launched  immediately  after  the party’s  failure  to  capture  the  presidency  in  2007  proved  to  be  a  muddled  affair that  ended  in  stalemate.  Three  challenges  to  Royal  emerged  from  the  center of  the  party,  one  led  by  Mayor  Bertrand  Delanoe  of  Paris,  another  by  Pierre Moscovici,  widely  seen  as  a  stalking  horse  for  Dominique  Strauss-Kahn,  and a  third  by  the  mayor  of  Lille,  Martine  Aubry.  A  fourth  challenge  came  from the  left  wing  of  the  party,  led  by  Benoit  Hamon.  Ultimately  the  three  centrist factions  united  behind  Aubry.  In  a  first  round  Hamon  took  nearly  20%  of  the votes.  In  the  runoff  Aubry  and  Royal  split  the  party  down  the  middle.  Aubry won  with  a  plurality  of  102  votes  out  of  nearly  175,000  cast,  but  her  victori¬ ous  coalition  was  united  by  only  one  thing:  hostility  to  Royal. And  there,  for  the  time  being,  the  French  left  remains  stuck:  divided  into mutually  suspicious  factions,  none  capable  by  itself  of  putting  forward  the kind  of  comprehensible  and  comprehensive  recipe  for  transformation  that Reluctantly  Center-Left?  161 is  needed  to  capture  the  presidency.  The  impasse  is  unlikely  to  be  resolved by  internal  debate,  which  for  twenty  years  has  been  largely  a  dialogue  of  the deaf.  More  likely  it  will  take  an  external  shock  to  push  the  factions  together, or  else  to  tear  the  left  apart  once  and  for  all,  as  has  begun  to  happen  in  a  num¬ ber  of  other  EU  countries  (for  example  by  the  appearance  of  die  Linke  to  the left  of  the  German  SPD).  There  might  conceivably  be  a  recomposition  of  the center,  in  which  center-right  and  center-left  join  forces  against  radicalized extremes.  But  the  presidentialist  regime  — our  third  persistent  structural  in¬ fluence— tends  to  make  this  prospect  unlikely. Notes The  authors  would  like  to  thank  James  Cronin,  Michael  Lowy,  and  James  Shoch  for perceptive  comments  on  an  earlier  draft. 1.  See  Fourastie  1979;  Eichengreen  2007,  too. 2.  This  pattern  of  divisions  also  existed  in  trade  union  and  mass  organizational spheres. 3.  Heisenberg  1999,  chapter  3;  Ludlow  1982. 4.  Favier  and  Martin-Roland  1990,  part  I. 5.  Becker  1998,  263-66. 6.  Quatremer  and  Klau  1997. 7.  CERC  2002,  chapters  3,  4. 8.  Becker  1998,  part  II,  chapter  2.  RMI  was  a  means-tested  guaranteed  minimum “citizen’s  income,”  administered  departmentally  and  tied  to  commitments  to  seek  “in¬ sertion”— usually  meaning  training  or  work,  a  compromise  between  a  guaranteed minimum  income  and  “welfare  to  work.” 9.  Philippe  Seguin  and  Charles  Pasqua  were  the  principal  leaders  of  the  Gaullist nationalists. 10.  Chirac  sought  advice  in  a  group  named  Phares  et  Balises,  which  was  organized by  the  dissident  Mitterrandist  Regis  Debray  and  the  journalist  Jean-Claude  Guillebaud. 11.  Palier  2002, 193. 12.  Palier  2002, 195,  417. 13.  The  CFDT  leadership’s  reluctance  to  endorse  this  popular  uprising  led  eventually to  the  defection  of  a  substantial  portion  of  its  membership,  which  joined  the  dissident union  SUD. 14.  In  2007  Jouyet  joined  Sarkozy’s  government  as  secretary  of  state  for  European affairs. 15.  Victor  1999, 170. 16.  Palier  2002,  252. The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition Prospects  and  Problems Ruy  Teixeira After  the  presidential  election  of  2004,  many  on  the  center-left  in  the  United States  were  strikingly  pessimistic  about  the  Democratic  Party’s  future  pros¬ pects.  Retaking  control  of  the  Congress  seemed  out  of  reach  given  the  advan¬ tages  of  incumbency  and  a  Republican  mobilization  machine  that  was  widely viewed  as  both  more  effective  and  more  ruthless  than  that  of  the  Democrats. Perhaps  if  the  Democrats  built  up  their  strength  and  fought  hard  in  the  next round  of  reapportionment,  retaking  Congress  might  be  possible  in  the  next decade.  But  it  was  foolish  to  expect  success  much  sooner  than  that. As  for  the  presidency,  that  seemed  more  possible,  but  Democrats  worried that  Republicans  had  a  lock  not  just  on  the  South  but  on  a  wide  swath  of culturally  conservative  states  in  the  Plains,  Southwest,  Mountain  West,  and Midwest.  The  GOP’s  demonstrated  ability  to  mobilize  voters  in  these  states with  a  conservatism  that  melded  national  security  and  cultural  concerns  was thought  to  offer  the  Democrats  little  chance  of  expanding  the  electoral  map  in their  favor.  The  most  that  Democrats  could  hope  for  was  to  refight  the  battle of  Ohio  again  in  2008  and  hope  that  this  time  they  would  win. But  even  at  the  time  there  were  strong  arguments  to  be  made  that  this take  on  the  Democrats’  prospects  was  unduly  pessimistic.  An  alternative  line of  analysis  suggested  that  the  Republicans’  strength  was  vastly  exaggerated, tied  to  an  event  (September  11,  2001)  whose  political  salience  would  decline over  time.  This  decline  would  eventually  expose  their  weakness  as  a  political party  with  a  philosophy  and  program  that  were  remarkably  out  of  step  with demographic  and  geographic  shifts  that  had  been  transforming  the  American electorate. The  results  of  the  midterm  elections  of  2006,  in  which  the  Democrats  re¬ took  Congress  and  made  significant  gains  in  a  wide  range  of  swing  and  GOP- leaning  states,  seemed  to  suggest  that  the  second  line  of  analysis  was  more The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  163 plausible  and  that  the  GOP  was  a  party  on  the  ropes  while  the  Democrats were  a  party  in  ascendance.  In  the  next  election,  of  course,  the  political  situa¬ tion  only  worsened  for  the  GOP  and  improved  even  more  for  the  Democrats, as  Barack  Obama  was  decisively  elected  president  and  the  Democrats  ex¬ panded  their  majorities  in  both  houses  of  Congress.  However,  the  midterm elections  of  2010,  in  which  the  Republicans  regained  control  of  the  House  of Representatives  and  picked  up  six  Senate  seats,  restored  at  least  temporary parity  to  the  party  system  in  Congress  and  clouded  the  immediate  future  of American  politics. In  what  follows,  written  mainly  before  the  2010  midterms,  I  describe  the various  trends  that  drove  the  Democrats’  ascendance  through  2008.  I  also much  more  briefly  explain  the  contrasting  2010  results. The  Once  and  Future  Democratic  Majority Racial  and  ethnic  minorities  are  probably  the  single  strongest  element  of  the emerging  Democratic  coalition.  In  2000  A1  Gore  carried  the  minority  vote  by 75-23,  and  even  in  John  Kerry’s  losing  effort  in  2004  he  still  carried  the  mi¬ nority  vote  by  71  to  27.  In  that  election,  according  to  the  exit  polls,  minorities made  up  23%  of  the  overall  vote.  That  compares  to  around  15%  of  voters  in the  early  1990s  when  Bill  Clinton  was  first  elected.1 And  in  2006  and  2008  the  Democrats  did  even  better.  In  2006  they  carried the  minority  congressional  vote  by  77-22 .2  In  2008  the  minority  share  of voters  in  the  national  exit  poll  reached  26%  and  the  minority  vote  was  an impressive  80-18  for  Obama,  a  62-point  margin,  significantly  greater  than Kerry’s  44-point  margin  in  2004. These  minority  gains  figured  greatly  in  many  key  states  carried  by  the Democrats  in  2008.  In  Ohio,  for  example,  the  minority  share  of  voters  rose from  14%  to  17%  and  black  voters  supported  Obama  by  a  stunning  95-point margin  (97  to  2),  compared  to  Kerry’s  68-point  margin  (84-16).  In  Nevada the  minority  share  of  voters  rose  by  a  full  8  points,  from  23%  to  31%  of  voters, with  95-4  black  support  for  Obama  (up  from  86-13  in  2004)  and  76-22  His¬ panic  support  (up  from  60-39  in  2004).  And  in  Florida,  while  the  minority share  of  voters  did  not  increase,  blacks  supported  Obama  by  the  overwhelm¬ ing  margin  of  96-4  compared  to  86-13  support  for  Kerry,  while  Hispanics, whom  Kerry  had  lost  by  56-43,  supported  Obama  by  57-42.  The  latter  is  truly a  sign  of  change  in  Florida,  as  Hispanic  voters,  spearheaded  by  relatively  con¬ servative  Cuban-Americans,  have  long  been  a  key  segment  of  the  GOP  coali¬ tion  in  the  state. It  is  worth  stressing  that  the  advantage  accruing  to  Democrats  from  mi- 164  Teixeira nority  voters  is  going  to  continue  growing.  As  mentioned,  from  1988  to  2008 the  proportion  of  minority  voters  increased  from  15  to  26%.  But  that  is  just the  beginning.  People  tend  to  think  of  2050  as  the  year  when  America  will become  “majority  minority.”  But  the  dates  are  closer  than  that:  the  latest  cen¬ sus  projections  put  them  at  2042  for  the  entire  population  and  at  2023  for  the population  under  eighteen.3  By  2050  the  United  States  will  actually  be  54% minority:  30%  Hispanic,  9%  Asian,  13%  black,  and  2%  other  race. Of  course  the  minority  community  is  not  monolithic  nor  all  growing  at  the same  rate,  so  it  is  worth  rehearsing  some  of  the  specifics  of  the  black,  His¬ panic,  and  Asian  vote. Black  voters  are  the  most  reliable  Democratic  constituency.  In  2004  Kerry had  a  margin  of  88  to  11  among  blacks,  down  only  slightly  from  the  margin of  90  to  9  for  Gore  in  2000.  In  2006  Democrats  carried  the  black  congres¬ sional  vote  by  89  to  10.  Then  in  2008  blacks  voted  by  an  amazing  95%-4% margin  for  Obama.  Also  in  2008  the  share  of  black  voters  rose  from  11%  to 13%,  hugely  impressive  for  a  group  whose  share  of  the  overall  population  is growing  very  slowly. Hispanic  voters,  while  strong  for  Democrats,  are  not  nearly  as  strong  as blacks,  and  have  famously  been  more  volatile  in  their  support.  In  2004  it was  initially  reported  that  they  gave  Bush  44%  of  their  vote.  However,  that initial  exit  poll  figure  is  now  widely  acknowledged  to  have  been  flawed,  and the  generally  accepted  estimate  is  that  Kerry  carried  Hispanics  by  58  to  40.4 Still,  that  represented  a  significant  improvement  of  5  points  in  Bush’s  support among  Hispanics  over  2000  and  a  substantial  compression  of  the  Democratic margin  among  this  group. There  was  much  debate  about  the  causes  of  this  shift.  Probably  the  best treatment  of  the  issue  was  done  by  the  political  scientists  Marisa  Abrajano, Michael  Alvarez,  and  Jonathan  Nagler  (2005),  whose  thorough  analysis  of exit  poll  data  from  2004  indicates  that  for  an  unusually  large  proportion  of Hispanic  voters  the  pull  of  national  security  and  moral  values  toward  the GOP  outweighed  that  of  the  economy,  healthcare,  and  education  toward  the Democrats.  This  can  be  illustrated  by  the  fact  that  Bush  had  an  advantage  of 13  points  among  Hispanics  on  being  trusted  to  handle  terrorism,  while  Kerry’s advantage  among  Hispanics  on  being  trusted  to  handle  the  economy  was  a more  modest  5  points.5  These  figures  underscore  the  extent  to  which  Demo¬ cratic  appeals  to  Hispanics  fell  short  in  that  election. There  was  even  more  debate  about  the  long-term  significance  of  Bush’s winning  40%  of  the  vote  among  Hispanics.  Abrajano,  Alvarez,  and  Nagler found  no  evidence  that  a  specific  cultural  issue  like  abortion  was  realigning Hispanics,  nor  did  they  find  evidence  for  the  “economic  advancement”  hy- The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  165 pothesis:  that  Hispanics,  particularly  second-  and  third-generation  Hispanics, are  moving  toward  the  GOP  as  they  are  becoming  richer  as  a  group. It  is  also  worth  noting  that  the  average  level  of  Hispanic  support  for  the Democrats  was  slightly  higher  in  the  two  Bush  elections  of  2000  and  2004 than  in  the  two  Reagan  elections  of  1980  and  1984.6  And  in  the  next  election following  Reagan’s  relatively  good  performances  among  Hispanics— 1988  — the  Hispanic  presidential  vote  moved  sharply  Democratic,  to  69%-30%. Interestingly,  the  latter  figures  exactly  match  the  Democrats’  support among  Hispanics  in  the  congressional  elections  of  2006.  And  in  2008  His¬ panics  voted  67-31  for  Obama,  a  36-point  margin  that  was  double  Kerry’s margin  in  2004.  Though  some  observers  speculated  that  racial  frictions  be¬ tween  Hispanics  and  blacks  would  prevent  Hispanics  from  giving  Obama wholehearted  support,  that  most  emphatically  was  not  the  case. If  Democrats  can  hold  this  group’s  support,  demographic  trends  assure them  of  greater  electoral  benefits  in  years  to  come.  The  Hispanic  population is  growing  rapidly,  both  in  terms  of  absolute  numbers  and  as  a  share  of  the United  States  population.  Before  1980  the  census  did  not  even  record  His¬ panic  origin  when  it  surveyed  the  country’s  residents.  Today  Hispanics  have surpassed  blacks  as  the  nation’s  largest  minority  group,  and  census  estimates indicate  that  there  are  about  forty-five  million  Hispanics  in  the  United  States, 15%  of  the  nation’s  population  (Frey  2008). This  rapid  increase  in  demographic  importance  will  continue  for  decades. The  Hispanic  population  has  grown  by  32%  since  2000  and  has  accounted for  about  half  of  United  States  population  growth  in  that  period  (Frey  2008). And  as  mentioned,  census  projections  indicate  that  by  about  mid-century Hispanics  will  account  for  30%  of  the  United  States  population. Of  course  it  is  true  that  the  population  strength  of  Hispanics  is  not  cur¬ rently  matched  by  its  voting  strength,  because  of  the  large  proportion  of  His¬ panics  who  are  not  citizens  and  therefore  cannot  vote  or  are  simply  too  young to  vote.  For  example,  of  the  5.7  million  Hispanics  added  to  the  United  States population  between  2000  and  2004, 1.7  million  were  under  eighteen  and  1.9 million  were  noncitizens.  As  a  result,  only  42%  of  Hispanics  overall  are  eli¬ gible  to  vote,  compared  to  77%  of  non-Hispanic  whites  and  66%  of  African Americans  (Suro,  Fry,  and  Passel  2005;  Frey  2009).  Still,  the  proportion  of Hispanics  among  the  voting  electorate  has  grown  steadily  and  will  continue to  grow.  Having  made  up  only  2%  of  voters  in  the  early  1990s,  they  rose  to 9%  in  2008  and  within  ten  years  will  likely  surpass  the  level  of  blacks  as  a proportion  of  actual  voters.7 Asians  over  the  last  fifteen  years  or  so  have  become  a  fairly  solid  Demo¬ cratic  constituency.  In  2004  they  supported  Kerry  over  Bush  by  a  margin  of 166  Teixeira 56-44,  similar  to  the  margin  they  had  given  to  Gore  over  Bush  (55-41)  in 2000.  And  in  the  Congressional  election  of  2002,  when  much  of  the  elec¬ torate  was  going  in  the  opposite  direction,  Asians  increased  their  support dramatically  for  House  Democrats,  from  56-44  in  1998  to  66-34  in  2002. In  2006  Asians  remained  strong  for  the  Democrats  at  62-37.®  And  in  2008 Asians  supported  Obama  by  62-35. Asians’  rate  of  growth  was  slightly  higher  than  that  of  Hispanics  in  the 1990s.  And  since  2000  they  have  not  been  far  behind  (26%,  versus  32%  for Hispanics).  Right  now  they  account  for  5%  of  the  population  and  about  2%  of voters.9  Both  figures  will  increase  in  the  next  ten  years  owing  to  this  group’s fast  rate  of  growth,  but  because  they  start  from  a  much  smaller  base  than Hispanics,  their  impact  on  the  population  and  voting  pool  will  be  far  more limited. Single,  Working,  and  Highly  Educated  Women As  is  well  known,  Democrats  typically  do  better  among  women  than  men.  But women  voters  are  a  vast  group,  and  the  true  areas  of  strength  for  Democrats are  among  three  subgroups:  single,  working,  and  highly  educated  women. In  2004  Kerry  carried  single  women  by  62-37,  college-educated  women  by 54-45  (60-38  among  those  with  a  postgraduate  education),  and  working women  by  51-48.10 All  of  these  margins,  however,  were  smaller  than  they  had  been  in  2000, particularly  for  working  women,  who  gave  Kerry  a  margin  no  greater  than his  margin  among  women  as  a  whole.  This  was  primarily  attributable  to  his poor  performance  among  married  working  women,  part  of  the  Democrats’ general  problem  with  married  women  voters  in  that  election.  Single  work¬ ing  women,  however,  remained  a  very  strong  progressive  constituency,  with Democrats  dominating  by  65-35. 11  In  2006  Democrats  generally  did  better among  these  constituencies,  carrying  single  women  by  66-33  and  college- educated  women  by  57-42.12  It  is  likely  they  also  did  better  among  working women,  but  since  the  exit  polls  did  not  ask  respondents  for  their  work  status, this  possibility  could  not  be  tested  directly. In  2008  single  women  voted  Democratic  by  70-29,  a  substantially  larger margin  than  in  2004.  And  working  women,  who  had  voted  Democratic  by only  3  points  in  2004,  voted  Democratic  this  time  by  an  impressive  margin  of 60-39.  Even  married  women  with  children,  traditionally  a  difficult  group  for Democrats,  supported  Obama  by  52-47. While  the  balance  of  women  relative  to  men  is  changing  little,  of  course, trends  within  the  female  population  are  quite  favorable  to  Democrats.  Single The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  167 women  now  make  up  almost  half  of  adult  women:  47%,  up  from  38%  in 1970.13  Their  current  size  in  the  voter  pool— more  than  a  quarter  of  eligible voters— closely  approximates  the  size  of  white  evangelicals,  the  GOP’s  largest base  group.  And  since  the  current  growth  rate  of  single  women  is  so  great— double  that  of  married  women— the  proportion  of  single  women  in  the  voting pool  will  continue  to  increase  (Greenberg  Quinlan  Rosner  Research  2007). And  there  is  every  expectation  that  this  burgeoning  population  of  single women  will  continue  to  be  resolutely  Democratic  in  its  politics.  Survey  data consistently  show  this  group  to  be  unusually  populist  on  economic  issues  and generally  opposed  to  the  conservative  agenda  on  foreign  policy  and  social issues  (Women’s  Voices,  Women  Vote  2007). Single  working  women  tend  to  be  a  particularly  progressive  group  among single  women,  as  indicated  by  data  cited  earlier.  They  are  also  a  rapidly  grow¬ ing  group,  increasing  their  share  of  the  adult  female  population  from  19%  in 1970  to  29%  today.14  That  is  even  faster  than  the  growth  rate  among  single women  as  a  whole. Finally,  college-educated  women  are  also  a  rapidly  growing  population group.  Their  share  of  the  female  population  twenty-five  and  older  has  more than  tripled  since  1970,  from  just  8%  to  28%  today.15 Professionals In  the  last  fifteen  to  twenty  years  professionals  have  become  a  very  strong Democratic  constituency,  something  they  decidedly  were  not  in  earlier  eras. In  the  presidential  election  of  i960,  for  example,  professionals  supported Nixon  over  Kennedy  by  61  to  38.  But  in  presidential  elections  from  1988  to 2000,  professionals  supported  the  Democratic  candidate  by  an  average  of 52  to  40.  And  in  2004  they  moved  still  further  in  this  direction,  supporting Kerry  over  Bush  by  63-37.16  In  2006  exit  poll  data— using  postgraduates  as a  proxy  for  professionals— suggest  that  professionals’  support  for  Democrats was  once  again  at  record  high  levels.17  And  in  2008  Obama  received  58-40 support  from  postgraduates.  That  figure  included  54-44  support  among  white postgraduates. Strong  support  from  professionals  is  especially  good  for  progressives  be¬ cause  professionals  are  a  rising  group  in  American  politics  and  society.  In  the 1950s  they  made  up  about  7%  of  the  workforce.  But  as  the  United  States  has moved  from  a  blue-collar,  industrial  economy  toward  a  postindustrial  one that  produces  ideas  and  services,  the  professional  class  has  expanded.  Today it  constitutes  just  under  17%  of  the  workforce.  In  another  ten  years  they  will be  18%  to  19%  of  the  workforce.18 168  Teixeira Moreover,  reflecting  their  very  high  turnout  rates,  they  are  an  even  larger percentage  of  voters  — and  not  just  of  employed  voters,  but  of  voters  as  a whole.  Nationally  they  account  for  about  21%  of  voters;  in  many  Northeast¬ ern  and  Far  Western  states  they  form  probably  one-quarter  of  the  electorate.19 The  Millennial  Generation The  Millennial  generation  is  even  larger  than  the  Baby  Boom  generation.  This is  true  no  matter  what  definition  we  use.  (A  young  generation  often  does  not have  a  common  name  and  clear  start  and  end  dates  until  a  consensus  emerges among  demographers  and  social  commentators  over  time.)  For  example,  if  we start  Millennial  in  birth  year  1978,  after  the  “baby  bust”  (to  which  Genera¬ tion  X  is  typically  linked)  had  ended  and  an  era  of  steadily  rising  births  had begun,  and  continue  to  2000  — as  is  common  in  market  research  — the  size of  this  generation  is  truly  staggering:  95  million  (though  only  about  half  are adults)  out  of  a  population  of  300  million,  compared  to  78  million  Boomers. By  2018  Millennials,  by  this  definition,  will  be  100  million  strong  and  will  all be  old  enough  to  vote.  Even  if  we  exclude  noncitizens,  there  will  still  be  90 million  citizen-eligible  Millennial  voters.20 And  even  if  we  use  1996  as  the  last  birth  year  for  the  Millennials,  so  that the  span  of  birth  years  covered  by  this  generation  (1978-96)  is  of  the  same length  as  that  covered  by  the  Baby  Boom  (1946-64),  this  generation  is  still larger  than  the  Boomers:  80  million  today  and  83  million  by  2016,  when  the members  of  the  tail  end  of  the  generation  vote  in  their  first  presidential  elec¬ tion. The  Millennial  generation  is  so  large  partly  because  many  of  its  members are  children  of  the  Boomers  (and  make  up  the  “echo  boom”),  while  others  are the  children  of  immigrants,  who  settled  in  the  United  States  in  unprecedented numbers  in  the  last  several  decades.  The  Millennials  are  the  most  diverse  gen¬ eration  by  far.  According  to  census  data  published  in  March  2006,  only  61% of  Millennial  adults  were  non-Hispanic  whites,  18%  were  Hispanic,  14%  were black,  and  5%  were  Asian. Like  the  Boomers,  the  Millennials  are  poised  to  have  an  impact  on  the country  at  every  life  stage  and  in  myriad  ways  — but  particularly  in  politics. By  2008  the  number  of  citizen-eligible  Millennial  voters  had  neared  fifty million.  By  the  presidential  election  of  2016  Millennials  will  be  36%  of  the citizen-eligible  electorate,  and  about  a  third  of  actual  voters21— and  this  is making  no  assumptions  about  possible  increased  turnout  rates  among  Mil¬ lennials  in  the  future,  which  could  make  their  weight  among  actual  voters higher.  In  addition,  from  that  point  on  the  Millennials’  share  of  the  electorate The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  169 will  rise  steadily  for  several  decades  as  more  and  more  of  the  generation  enter middle  age. On  the  level  of  sheer  partisan  politics,  the  increased  number  of  Millennials in  the  voting  pool  is  having  substantial  effects,  since  they  have  voted  more heavily  Democratic  than  other  generations  in  their  first  few  elections.  For example,  in  2006  voters  aged  eighteen  to  twenty-nine  voted  60-38  Demo¬ cratic  for  Congress,  with  the  subgroup  of  voters  aged  eighteen  to  twenty- four  going  58-37  Democratic  (note  how  similar  the  strength  of  Democratic support  is  between  the  smaller  group  of  Millennials  and  the  larger  group, implying  that  transition  Millennials— those  twenty-five  to  twenty-nine  — did not  vote  much  differently  from  their  early  Millennial  counterparts).  In  2004 voters  aged  eighteen  to  twenty-nine  (dominated  by  the  subgroup  aged  eigh¬ teen  to  twenty-six,  who  qualify  as  Millennials)  voted  54-45  Democratic  for president  (55-44  for  the  House).  But  note  here  that  the  subgroup  aged  eigh¬ teen  to  twenty-four— Millennials  all— voted  56-43  Democratic  for  president, while  the  older  subgroup,  twenty-five  to  twenty-nine— mostly  not  Millen¬ nials— voted  only  51-48  Democratic.  Even  in  2002,  a  terrible  Democratic year,  voters  aged  eighteen  to  twenty-four  (the  first  time  Millennials  consti¬ tuted  this  group)  still  voted  Democratic  49-47.22 But  it  was  in  2008  that  the  Millennial  vote  had  its  largest  effect.  This  is  the first  year  that  voters  aged  eighteen  to  twenty-nine  belonged  exclusively  to the  millennial  generation  (those  born  1978  or  later),  and  they  gave  Obama  a 34-point  margin,  66-32.  This  compares  to  only  a  9-point  margin  for  Kerry  in 2004.  The  youth  share  of  voters  also  increased  across  the  two  elections,  from 17  to  18. Obama’s  support  among  voters  aged  eighteen  to  twenty-nine  was  remark¬ ably  broad,  extending  across  racial  barriers.  In  that  age  group  he  carried not  just  Hispanics  (76%-i9%)  and  blacks  (95-4)  but  also  whites  (54-44), a  10-point  advantage  that  contrasts  starkly  with  Obama’s  15-point  deficit among  older  whites. Obama’s  huge  overall  margin  among  Millennials  contributed  mightily  to his  strong  victory.  Without  voters  aged  eighteen  to  twenty-nine,  Obama’s popular  vote  margin  would  have  been  slightly  under  one  percentage  point. That  figure  means  that  87%  of  Obama’s  popular  vote  victory  was  attributable to  the  support  of  Millennials  between  eighteen  and  twenty-nine.  Indeed  with¬ out  these  Millennial  voters  Obama  would  have  been  hard-pressed  to  claim much  of  a  mandate  from  his  election  victory. These  results  could  hardly  be  more  positive  for  the  Democrats.  And  Mil¬ lennials’  influence  on  the  electorate  is  certain  to  grow  for  the  next  several elections.  There  were  about  48  million  eligible  Millennial  voters  in  2008,  a 170  Teixeira figure  that  will  rise  to  64  million  in  2012  and  81  million  in  2016.  That  is  a  huge number  of  potential  Democrats,  given  how  this  generation  is  leaning.  In  a Pew  survey  in  early  2007,  48%  of  Millennials  between  eighteen  and  twenty- five  identified  with  or  leaned  toward  the  Democratic  Party,  compared  to  just 35%  who  identified  with  or  leaned  toward  the  Republicans.  The  latter  figure represents  a  huge  crash  in  support  for  the  Republicans  among  this  age  group: in  the  early  1990s  voters  in  this  age  group,  members  of  “Gen  X,”  were  identi¬ fying  at  a  55%  rate  with  Republicans. Gen  Xers  continue  to  be  the  most  Republican  generation  today,  while  the Millennials  are  emerging  as  the  most  Democratic  generation  by  a  substan¬ tial  margin.  Other  polls  of  Millennials  and  Millennial-dominated  age  groups confirm  this  solid  Democratic  lead  in  party  identification.  On  election  day  in 2006  the  exit  polls  showed  the  Democrats  with  a  12-point  lead  on  party  iden¬ tification  among  voters  aged  eighteen  to  twenty-five.23  And  polls  taken  since then  have  continued  to  give  the  Democrats  strong  double-digit  leads  on  party identification  among  this  age  group  — Pew  had  the  Democratic  advantage  at an  astonishing  25  points  in  data  covering  the  period  from  October  2007  to March  2008.  Numerous  political  science  studies  confirm  that  party  identifi¬ cation,  once  formed  in  a  generation’s  twenties,  tend  to  persist  over  a  lifetime. The  Secular,  the  Less  Observant,  and  the  Non-Christian It  is  a  commonplace  in  American  politics  today  that  the  highly  observant— especially  evangelical  Christians— are  a  bedrock  conservative  constituency. Less  well  appreciated  is  the  extent  to  which  the  secular,  the  less  observant, and  the  non-Christian  are  a  bedrock  Democratic  constituency.  In  2004  Kerry carried  those  who  attend  religious  services  a  few  times  a  year  by  54-45  and those  who  never  attend  by  62-36.  And  he  carried  all  non-Christian  groups  by very  wide  margins:  Jews  (77-22),  Muslims  (74-25),  those  who  profess  some other  religion  (72-25),  and  those  who  profess  no  religion  (67-31).24  Demo¬ cratic  support  among  these  groups  was  even  stronger  in  2006:  those  who attend  religious  services  a  few  times  a  year  (60-38),  those  who  never  attend (67-30),  Jews  (87-12),  those  who  profess  some  other  religion  (71-25),  and those  who  profess  no  religion  (74-22).25 According  to  exit  polls,  the  less  observant  made  up  43%  of  voters  in  2004 (the  latter  figure,  incidentally,  is  exactly  equal  to  the  percentage  of  voters who  were  highly  observant).  That  figure  is  likely  to  go  up  in  the  future.  In  the University  of  Chicago’s  General  Social  Survey  (GSS),  those  who  attend  church only  once  a  year  or  less  is  now  42%  of  adults,  up  from  29%  in  1972. Data  from  exit  polls  in  2008  suggest  that  attempts  to  inflame  cultural The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  171 issues  in  the  election  campaign  were  not  successful.  Democrats  gained  sup¬ port  throughout  the  religious  spectrum.  Consider  first  the  vote  broken  down by  how  often  people  attend  religious  services.  In  the  United  States  over  the last  couple  of  decades  there  has  been  a  strong  relationship  between  how  often you  attend  services  and  how  you  vote,  with  those  who  attend  most  frequently being  much  more  conservative  than  those  who  attend  least  often.  This  rela¬ tionship  was  not  broken  in  2008,  but  it  did  become  less  strong. For  example,  Obama  ran  the  same  relatively  modest  12-point  deficit  among those  who  attend  services  more  than  once  a  week  as  he  did  among  those  who attend  weekly.  In  fact,  Obama’s  17-point  improvement  from  a  35-64  Demo¬ cratic  deficit  among  the  most  frequent  attenders  in  2004  to  a  43-55  deficit  in 2008  was  his  largest  improvement  among  the  different  attendance  groups  in 2008.  He  also  improved  the  Democratic  margin  by  8  points  among  those  who attend  a  few  times  a  month,  by  10  points  among  those  who  attend  a  few  times a  year,  and  by  11  points  among  those  who  never  attend. In  terms  of  religious  affiliation,  Obama  improved  the  Democratic  margin among  Catholics  by  14  points,  from  a  5-point  deficit  in  2004  to  a  9-point  ad¬ vantage  in  2008.  He  also  reduced  the  Democratic  deficit  among  Protestant and  other  Christian  voters  by  10  points,  from  19  to  9.  And  he  achieved  enor¬ mous  margins  among  Jews  (78-21),  members  of  other  religions  (73-22),  and unaffiliated  voters  (75-23). Speaking  of  unaffiliated— secular— voters,  it  is  this  group,  not  white  evan¬ gelicals,  who  are  the  fastest-growing  religious  group  in  the  United  States. This,  combined  with  racial  and  ethnic  trends,  will  ensure  that  in  very  short order  we  will  no  longer  be  a  white  Christian  nation.  Even  today  only  about 55%  of  adults  are  white  Christians.  By  2024  that  figure  will  be  down  to  45%. This  means  that  by  the  election  of  2016  (or  2020  at  the  outside)  white  Chris¬ tians  will  be  in  the  minority.  That  will  provide  another  long-range  boost  to Democratic  prospects. Union  Household  Voters Union  household  voters  have  been  a  consistently  strong  constituency  for  pro¬ gressives,  and  the  election  of  2004  was  no  exception.  These  voters  supported Kerry  by  59-40  and  made  up  an  impressive  24%  of  the  voting  pool.26  In  2006 union  households  did  even  better  for  the  Democrats,  supporting  them  by 64-34,  while  making  up  a  similarly  high  share  (23%)  of  voters.27  And  in  2008 these  voters  supported  Obama  by  59  to  40,  a  margin  essentially  identical  to Kerry’s  in  2004.  Yet  their  representation  among  voters  (21%)  was  3  points less  than  in  2004.  Even  this  21%  figure  is  impressive,  however,  given  that 172  Teixeira union  membership  in  the  United  States  now  stands  at  only  12%  of  workers. Clearly  the  union  vote  has  little  potential  for  growth  and  considerable  poten¬ tial  for  further  decline  without  significant  changes  in  labor  law  such  as  those proposed  in  the  Employee  Free  Choice  Act,  which  would  make  it  easier  for unions  to  organize  workers.  Given  the  progressive  proclivities  of  union  house¬ hold  voters,  that  would  be  of  great  benefit  to  the  Democrats. The  White  Working-Class  Challenge The  key  weakness  of  the  emerging  Democratic  coalition  can  be  summarized easily:  very  weak  support  among  white  working-class  voters  (defined  here as  whites  without  a  four-year  college  degree).  These  voters,  who  are  over¬ whelmingly  of  moderate  to  low  income  and,  by  definition,  of  modest  cre¬ dentials,  should  see  their  aspirations  linked  tightly  to  the  political  fate  of  the Democratic  Party.  But  they  do  not.  Instead  the  white  working  class,  as  it  has declined  in  numbers,  has  shifted  its  allegiance  from  largely  Democratic  to largely  Republican.  Here  is  the  story  of  that  decline  and  political  shift. Let  us  start  with  basic  numbers:  the  size  of  the  white  working  class  about the  time  of  the  the  Second  World  War  and  today.  Using  the  broad  education- based  definition  above,  America  in  1940  was  an  overwhelmingly  white working-class  country.  In  that  year  86%  of  adults  twenty-five  and  over  were whites  without  a  four-year  college  degree.  By  2007,  with  the  dramatic  rise in  educational  attainment  and  the  decline  in  the  white  population,  that  pro¬ portion  was  down  to  48%.28  A  similar  trend  can  be  seen  if  one  uses  a  narrow education-based  definition.  In  1940  82%  of  adults  twenty-five  and  over  were whites  with  a  high  school  diploma  or  less.  By  2007  that  figure  was  down  to 29%.  Or,  using  a  broad  occupation-based  definition,  in  1940  74%  of  employed workers  were  whites  without  professional  or  managerial  jobs.  By  2006  the steady  climb  in  professional  and  managerial  jobs,  combined  with  the  decline in  the  white  population,  had  brought  that  proportion  down  to  43%.29  A  nar¬ row  occupation-based  definition  yields  a  decline  of  similar  magnitude.  In 1940  58%  of  workers  were  whites  without  professional,  managerial,  or  cleri¬ cal  and  sales  jobs  (or,  looked  at  another  way,  whites  who  held  manual,  ser¬ vice,  or  farm  jobs).  By  2006  that  figure  had  fallen  to  25%. The  final  class  indicator  to  look  at  is  income.  Using  a  broad  income-based definition  of  the  white  working  class,  86%  of  American  families  in  1947  were white  families  with  less  than  $60,000  in  income  (2005  dollars).  With  rising affluence  — especially  rapid  in  the  period  from  1947  to  1973— and  the  decline in  the  white  population,  that  figure  had  declined  to  33%  by  2005.30  Using  a narrow  income-based  definition,  60%  of  families  in  1947  were  white  families with  less  than  $30,000  in  income.  That  figure  had  dropped  to  14%  by  2005. The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  173 So  each  indicator  that  can  be  used  to  define  the  white  working  class, whether  applied  broadly  or  narrowly,  shows  huge  declines  from  the  Second World  War  era  to  today— declines  roughly  in  the  range  of  30-50  percent¬ age  points.  The  income-based  definitions  show  the  sharpest  declines  and  the occupation-based  definitions  the  least,  with  the  education-based  definitions somewhere  in  between.  And  in  each  case  these  shifts  have  moved  the  white working  class  from  being  the  solid  and  sometimes  overwhelming  majority  of United  States  adults  (or  workers  or  families)  to  being  a  minority. But  the  story  of  the  white  working  class  in  the  years  following  the  Second World  War  is  one  of  not  just  one  sharp  decline  but  also  profound  transforma¬ tion.  This  is  true  no  matter  what  indicator  one  uses  to  define  the  white  work¬ ing  class.  That  is,  whether  one  looks  at  white  families  with  less  than  $60,000 income,  whites  who  do  not  hold  professional  and  managerial  jobs,  or  whites without  a  four-year  college  degree,  there  have  been  dramatic  shifts  in  the character  and  composition  of  the  white  working  class. Consider  the  following  shifts  among  whites  without  a  four-year  college degree.  In  1940  86%  of  these  working-class  whites  had  never  graduated  from high  school  (or  even  reached  high  school).  But  today  just  14%  of  the  white working  class  consists  of  high  school  dropouts.  About  two-fifths  have  some education  beyond  high  school,  with  13%  having  achieved  an  associate  de¬ gree.31  Note,  however,  that  the  economic  situation  of  those  with  an  associate degree  is  very  similar  to  those  with  some  college  but  no  degree:  the  median household  income  of  whites  with  an  associate  degree  is  only  a  few  thousand dollars  more  than  those  with  some  college  only  (Teixeira  and  Rogers  2000, 16). While  the  unavailability  of  data  precludes  a  precise  estimate,  the  economic situation  of  the  white  working  class  has  altered  dramatically.  A  reasonable guess  is  that  median  family  income  among  the  white  working  class  rose  from around  $20,000  to  $50,000  between  1947  and  2005,  a  150%  increase.  And the  jobs  that  the  white  working  class  holds  have  also  altered  dramatically. Today  most  white  working-class  jobs  are  not  manual  or  blue-collar  but  low- level  white-collar  (technical,  sales,  clerical)  and  service  occupations.  And the  blue-collar  jobs  that  remain  are  increasingly  likely  to  be  skilled  positions: only  about  a  sixth  of  the  white  working  class  holds  unskilled  blue-collar  jobs (even  among  white  working-class  men,  the  figure  is  less  than  one-quarter).32 Today  only  about  a  sixth  of  the  white  working  class  holds  manufacturing jobs  (even  among  men,  the  proportion  is  still  less  than  one-quarter).  In  fact the  entire  goods-producing  sector,  which  includes  construction,  mining,  and agriculture  as  well  as  manufacturing,  provides  less  than  three  in  ten  white working-class  jobs.  The  remaining  seven  in  ten  are  in  the  service  sector,  in¬ cluding  government.  There  are  about  as  many  members  of  the  white  work- 174  Teixeira ing  class  working  in  trade  alone  (especially  retail)  as  there  are  in  all  goods- producing  jobs. Accompanying  the  decline  and  transformation  of  the  white  working  class was  a  very  significant  shift  in  its  political  orientation,  from  pro-Democratic in  most  respects  to  pro-Republican,  especially  at  the  presidential  level.  The story  of  this  shift  away  from  the  Democratic  Party  starts  with  the  New  Deal Democrats  and  their  close  relationship  with  the  white  working  class.  The New  Deal  Democratic  worldview  was  based  on  a  combination  of  the  Demo¬ crats’  historic  populist  commitment  to  the  average  working  American  and their  experience  in  battling  the  Great  Depression  (and  building  their  political coalition)  through  increased  government  spending  and  regulation  and  the promotion  of  labor  unions.  It  was  really  a  rather  simple  philosophy,  even  if the  application  of  it  was  complex.  Government  should  help  the  average  per¬ son  through  vigorous  government  spending.  Capitalism  needs  regulation  to work  properly.  Labor  unions  are  good.  Putting  money  in  the  average  person’s pocket  is  more  important  than  rarefied  worries  about  the  quality  of  life.  Tra¬ ditional  morality  is  to  be  respected,  not  challenged.  Racism  and  the  like  are bad,  but  not  so  bad  that  the  party  should  depart  from  its  main  mission  of  ma¬ terial  uplift  for  the  average  American. That  worldview  had  deep  roots  in  an  economy  dominated  by  mass  produc¬ tion  industries  and  was  politically  based  among  the  workers,  overwhelmingly white,  in  those  industries.  And  it  helped  make  the  Democrats  the  undisputed party  of  the  white  working  class.  Their  dominance  among  these  voters  was the  key  to  their  political  success.  To  be  sure,  there  were  important  divisions among  these  voters  — by  country  of  origin  (German,  Scandinavian,  Eastern European,  English,  Irish,  Italian),  religion  (Protestants,  Catholics),  and  re¬ gion  (South,  North)— that  greatly  complicated  the  politics  of  this  group,  but New  Deal  Democrats  mastered  the  complications  and  maintained  a  deep  base among  these  voters. Of  course  the  New  Deal  coalition  as  originally  forged  did  include  most blacks  and  was  certainly  cross-class,  especially  among  groups  like  Jews  and southerners.  But  the  prototypical  member  of  the  coalition  was  indeed  an ethnic  white  worker— commonly  visualized  as  working  in  a  unionized  fac¬ tory,  but  in  some  cases  not  belonging  to  a  union  and  in  some  cases  work¬ ing  in  a  non-manufacturing  blue-collar  sector  such  as  construction  or  trans¬ portation.  It  was  these  voters  who  provided  the  numbers  for  five  consecutive Democratic  election  victories— four  by  FDR  and  one  narrow  one  by  Harry Truman  in  1948  — as  well  as  political  support  for  the  emerging  United  States welfare  state,  its  implicit  social  contract,  and  a  greatly  expanded  role  for  gov¬ ernment. The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  175 Even  in  the  1950s,  with  the  Republican  Dwight  Eisenhower  as  president, the  white  working  class  continued  to  put  Democrats  in  Congress  and  support the  expansion  of  the  welfare  state,  as  a  roaring  United  States  economy  deliv¬ ered  the  goods  and  as  government  poured  money  into  roads,  science,  schools, and  whatever  else  seemed  necessary  to  build  up  the  country.  This  era,  stretch¬ ing  back  into  the  late  1940s  and  forward  to  the  mid-1960s,  created  the  first mass  middle  class  in  the  world— a  middle  class  that  even  factory  workers could  enter,  since  they  could  earn  relatively  comfortable  livings  even  without high  levels  of  education  or  professional  skills— a  middle  class,  in  other  words, that  members  of  the  white  working  class  could  reasonably  aspire  to  join  and frequently  did. So  New  Deal  Democrats  depended  on  the  white  working  class  for  politi¬ cal  support,  and  the  white  working  class  depended  on  the  Democrats  to  run government  and  the  economy  in  a  way  that  kept  that  upward  escalator  to  the middle  class  moving.  Social  and  cultural  issues  were  not  particularly  impor¬ tant  to  this  mutually  beneficial  relationship;  they  had  only  a  peripheral  role in  the  uncomplicated  progressivism  that  animated  the  Democratic  Party  of the  1930s,  1940s,  and  1950s.  But  that  arrangement  and  that  uncomplicated progressivism  could  not  and  did  not  survive  the  decline  of  mass  production industries  and  the  rise  of  postindustrial  capitalism. First,  there  was  the  transformation  of  the  white  working  class  itself,  dis¬ cussed  in  detail  previously.  The  white  working  class  became  richer,  better educated,  more  white-collar,  and  less  unionized.  To  get  a  sense  of  how  impor¬ tant  unionization  was,  consider  that  in  the  late  1940s  unions  claimed  around 60%  or  more  of  the  northern  blue-collar  workforce  (Judis  and  Teixeira  2002, 63).  Second,  as  this  great  transformation  was  changing  the  character  of  the white  working  class,  reducing  the  size  and  influence  of  the  Democrats’  tra¬ ditional  blue-collar  constituencies,  the  evolution  of  postindustrial  capitalism was  creating  new  constituencies  and  movements  with  new  demands.  These new  constituencies  and  movements  wanted  more  out  of  the  welfare  state  than steady  economic  growth,  copious  infrastructure  spending,  and  the  opportu¬ nity  to  raise  a  family  in  the  traditional  manner. During  the  1960s  these  new  demands  on  the  welfare  state  came  to  a  head. Americans’  concern  about  their  quality  of  life  overflowed  and  their  expecta¬ tions  increased:  from  a  two-car  garage  to  clean  air  and  water  and  safe  auto¬ mobiles;  from  higher  wages  to  government-guaranteed  healthcare  in  old  age; from  access  to  jobs  to  equal  opportunities  for  men  and  women  and  blacks and  whites.  Out  of  these  concerns  came  the  environmental,  consumer,  civil rights,  and  feminist  movements  of  the  1960s.  As  Americans  abandoned  the older  ideal  of  self-denial  and  the  taboos  that  accompanied  it,  they  embraced  a 176  Teixeira libertarian  ethic  of  personal  life.  Women  asserted  their  sexual  independence through  the  use  of  birth  control  pills  and  the  right  to  have  an  abortion.  Ado¬ lescents  experimented  with  sex  and  courtship.  Homosexuals  “came  out”  and openly  congregated  in  bars  and  neighborhoods. Of  these  changes  the  one  with  most  far-reaching  political  effects  was  the civil  rights  movement  and  its  demands  for  equality  and  economic  progress for  black  America.  Democrats,  both  because  of  their  traditional,  if  usually downplayed,  antiracist  ideology  and  their  political  relationship  to  the  black community,  had  no  choice  but  to  respond  to  those  demands.  The  result  was  a great  victory  for  social  justice,  but  one  that  created  huge  political  difficulties for  the  Democrats  among  their  white  working-class  supporters.  Kevin  Phillips captured  these  developments  well  in  his  book,  The  Emerging  Republican  Ma¬ jority  (1969):  “The  principal  force  which  broke  up  the  Democratic  (New  Deal) coalition  is  the  Negro  socioeconomic  revolution  and  liberal  Democratic  ideo¬ logical  inability  to  cope  with  it.  Democratic  ‘Great  Society’  programs  aligned that  party  with  many  Negro  demands,  but  the  party  was  unable  to  defuse  the racial  tension  sundering  the  nation.  The  South,  the  West,  and  the  Catholic sidewalks  of  New  York  were  the  focus  points  of  conservative  opposition  to  the welfare  liberalism  of  the  federal  government;  however,  the  general  opposi¬ tion  . . .  came  in  large  part  from  prospering  Democrats  who  objected  to  Wash¬ ington  dissipating  their  tax  dollars  on  programs  which  did  them  no  good.  The Democratic  Party  fell  victim  to  the  ideological  impetus  of  a  liberalism  which had  carried  it  beyond  programs  taxing  the  few  for  the  benefit  of  the  many  . . . to  programs  taxing  the  many  on  behalf  of  the  few.” But  if  race  was  the  chief  vehicle  by  which  the  New  Deal  coalition  was  torn apart,  it  was  by  no  means  the  only  one.  White  working-class  voters  also  re¬ acted  poorly  to  the  extremes  with  which  the  rest  of  the  new  social  movements became  identified.  Feminism  became  identified  with  “bra  burners,”  lesbians, and  hostility  to  the  nuclear  family;  the  antiwar  movement  with  appeasement of  third  world  radicals  and  the  Soviet  Union;  the  environmental  movement with  a  Luddite  opposition  to  economic  growth;  and  the  move  toward  more personal  freedom  with  a  complete  abdication  of  personal  responsibility. Thus  the  New  Deal  mainstream  that  dominated  the  Democratic  Party  was confronted  with  a  challenge.  The  uncomplicated  commitments  to  govern¬ ment  spending,  economic  regulation,  and  labor  unions  that  had  defined  the Democrats’  progressivism  for  over  thirty  years  suddenly  provided  little  guid¬ ance  for  contending  with  an  explosion  of  potential  new  constituencies  for  the party.  Their  demands  for  equality,  and  for  a  better  as  opposed  to  merely  richer life,  were  starting  to  redefine  what  progressivism  meant,  and  the  Democrats had  to  struggle  to  catch  up. The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  177 Initially  Democratic  politicians  responded  to  these  changes  in  the  fashion of  politicians  since  time  immemorial:  they  sought  to  co-opt  the  new  move¬ ments  by  absorbing  many  of  their  demands,  while  holding  on  to  the  party’s basic  ideology  and  style  of  governing.  Thus  Democratic  politicians  did  not change  their  fundamental  commitment  to  the  New  Deal  welfare  state,  but grafted  onto  it  support  for  all  the  various  new  constituencies  and  their  key demands.  After  Lyndon  Johnson  signed  the  Civil  Rights  Act  in  1964,  the  party moved  over  the  next  eight  years  to  give  prominent  places  within  the  party  to the  women’s,  antiwar,  consumer,  and  environmental  movements.  This  stance reflected  both  the  politician’s  standard  interest  in  capturing  the  votes  of  new constituencies  and  the  broadening  definition  of  what  it  meant  to  be  a  Demo¬ crat,  particularly  a  progressive  one. But  of  course  there  was  no  guarantee  that  gains  among  these  new  con¬ stituencies  would  not  be  offset  by  losses  among  the  older  constituency— the white  working  class— which  had  little  interest  in  revising  what  it  meant  to be  a  progressive  and  a  Democrat.  The  conflict  was  brought  to  the  fore  in  1972 with  the  nomination  and  disastrous  defeat  of  George  McGovern,  who  enthu¬ siastically  embraced  the  new  direction  taken  by  the  party.  McGovern’s  com¬ mitment  to  the  traditional  Democratic  welfare  state  was  unmistakable.  But so  was  his  commitment  to  the  various  social  movements  and  constituencies that  were  reshaping  the  party,  whose  demands  were  enshrined  in  McGovern’s campaign  platform.  That  made  it  easy  for  his  Republican  opponent,  President Richard  Nixon,  to  typecast  McGovern  as  the  candidate  of  “acid,  amnesty  and abortion.”  The  white  working  class  reacted  accordingly  and  gave  Nixon  70% of  its  votes  (Judis  and  Teixeira  2002,  63). Just  how  far  the  Democrats  fell  in  the  white  working  class’s  eyes  over  this period  can  be  seen  by  comparing  the  average  vote  for  Democrats  of  the  white working  class  (whites  without  a  four-year  college  degree)  in  1960-64  (55%) to  its  average  vote  for  Democrats  in  1968-72  (35%)  (Teixeira  and  Rogers 2000,  32).  The  Democrats  were  the  party  of  the  white  working  class  no  longer. With  the  sharp  economic  recession  and  Nixon’s  scandals  of  1973-74,  the Democrats  were  able  to  develop  enough  political  momentum  to  retake  the White  House  in  1976,  with  Jimmy  Carter’s  narrow  defeat  of  Gerald  Ford.  But their  political  revival  did  not  last  long. Carter  did  little  to  defuse  white  working-class  hostility  to  the  new  social movements,  especially  the  black  liberation  movement,  and  economic  condi¬ tions  in  the  late  1970s  conspired  to  make  that  hostility  even  sharper.  Stagfla¬ tion— a  vexing  combination  of  high  inflation  and  high  unemployment  with slow  economic  growth,  including,  critically,  slow  wage  and  income  growth  — had  first  appeared  during  the  recession  of  1973-75,  but  it  persisted  under 178  Teixeira Carter  and  was  peaking  on  the  eve  of  the  election  of  1980.  As  the  economy  slid once  more  into  recession,  the  inflation  rate  stood  at  12.5%.  Combined  with  an unemployment  rate  of  7.1%,  it  produced  a  “misery  index”  of  nearly  20%.  By that  time  white  working-class  voters  had  entered  an  economic  world  radically different  from  the  one  enjoyed  by  the  preceding  generation.  Slow  growth,  de¬ clining  wages,  stagnating  living  standards,  high  inflation,  and  high  interest rates  were  really  battering  them  economically.  The  great  postwar  escalator  to the  middle  class  had  drastically  slowed  down  and  for  some  even  stopped. These  economic  developments  fed  resentments  about  race  — about  high taxes  for  welfare  (which  were  assumed  to  go  primarily  to  minorities)  and about  affirmative  action.  But  they  also  sowed  doubts  about  Democrats’  ability to  manage  the  economy  and  made  Republican  and  business  explanations  of stagflation— blaming  it  on  government  regulation,  high  taxes,  and  spend¬ ing— more  plausible.  In  1978  white  backlash  and  doubts  about  Democratic economic  policies  had  helped  to  fuel  a  nationwide  tax  revolt.  In  1980  these forces  reinforced  the  massive  exodus  of  white  working-class  voters  from  the Democratic  tickets  first  seen  in  1968  and  1972.  In  the  presidential  elections  of 1980  and  1984  Ronald  Reagan  averaged  61%  support  among  the  white  work¬ ing  class,  compared  to  an  average  of  35%  support  for  his  Democratic  oppo¬ nents,  Jimmy  Carter  and  Walter  Mondale  (Judis  and  Teixeira  2002,  63;  Tei¬ xeira  and  Rogers  2000,  32). Such  a  thrashing,  coming  not  that  long  after  the  debacle  of  the  McGovern campaign,  led  many  Democrats  to  form  a  new  organization,  the  Democratic Leadership  Council  (DLC),  to  propose  a  reconfiguration  of  the  Democratic approach.  These  “New  Democrats”  argued  that  in  the  late  1960s  the  liberal¬ ism  of  the  New  Deal  had  degenerated  into  a  liberal  fundamentalism,  which, in  the  words  of  William  Galston  and  Elaine  Kamarck  (1989),  the  public  had “come  to  associate  with  tax  and  spending  policies  that  contradict  the  inter¬ ests  of  average  families;  with  welfare  policies  that  foster  dependence  rather than  self-reliance;  with  softness  toward  the  perpetrators  of  crime  and  indif¬ ference  toward  its  victims;  with  ambivalence  toward  the  assertion  of  Ameri¬ can  values  and  interests  abroad;  and  with  an  adversarial  stance  toward  main¬ stream  moral  and  cultural  values.” Galston,  Kamarck,  and  the  DLC  advocated  fiscal  conservatism,  welfare  re¬ form,  increased  spending  on  crime  through  the  development  of  a  police  corps, tougher  mandatory  sentences,  support  for  capital  punishment,  and  policies that  encouraged  traditional  families.  This  new  approach  did  not  really  take off  until  it  was  embraced  by  the  Democratic  presidential  candidate  Bill  Clin¬ ton  in  1992,  who  synthesized  these  views  with  a  moderate  version  of  New Deal  economic  populism.  It  proved  to  be  an  electorally  successful  approach The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  179 for  Clinton  both  in  1992  and,  thanks  to  some  good  economic  times,  in  1996 as  well.  But  despite  Clinton’s  electoral  success,  he  did  not  receive  a  great  deal of  white  working-class  support:  he  averaged  only  41%  across  his  two  elec¬ tion  victories.  But  he  did  at  least  prevent  these  voters  from  siding  with  his Republican  opponents  in  large  numbers,  eking  out  l-point  pluralities  among the  white  working  class  in  both  elections  (in  each  election  a  third-party  can¬ didacy  was  mounted  by  Ross  Perot).33 Clinton’s  designated  successor,  Al  Gore,  was  not  so  successful.  He  lost white  working-class  voters  in  the  2000  election  by  17  points.  And  the  next Democratic  presidential  candidate,  John  Kerry,  did  even  worse,  losing  these voters  by  23  points  in  2004.34  One  could  reasonably  ascribe  the  worsening deficit  for  Democrats  in  2004  to  concerns  about  national  security  and  terror¬ ism  after  9/11,  but  not  so  for  the  very  sizable  deficit  in  2000.  Apparently  the successes  of  the  Clinton  years,  which  included  a  strong  economy  that  deliv¬ ered  solid  real  wage  growth  for  the  first  time  since  1973,  did  not  succeed  in  re¬ storing  the  historic  bond  between  the  white  working  class  and  the  Democrats. Exit  polls  typically  do  not  classify  respondents  by  occupation,  but  they  do classify  by  income  as  well  as  education.  If  one  looks  specifically  at  voters  who seem  to  correspond  most  closely  to  one’s  intuitive  sense  of  the  heart  of  the white  working  class— white  voters  of  moderate  income  who  are  not  college- educated— one  finds  that  these  are  precisely  the  voters  among  whom  Demo¬ crats  did  most  poorly.  For  example,  among  non-college-educated  whites  with a  household  income  of  $30,000-850,000,  Bush  beat  Kerry  by  24  points  (62- 38);  among  college-educated  whites  at  the  same  income  level  Kerry  man¬ aged  a  49-49  tie.  And  among  non-college-educated  whites  with  $50,000- $75,000  in  household  income,  Bush  beat  Kerry  by  41  points  (70-29),  while leading  by  only  5  points  (52-47)  among  college-educated  whites  at  the  same income  level.35  Thus  the  more  voters  looked  like  hardcore  members  of  the white  working  class,  the  less  likely  they  were  to  vote  for  Kerry  in  2004. Clearly  Democrats  need  to  do  better  among  white  working-class  voters  if they  are  to  capitalize  on  their  burgeoning  advantage  among  the  constituen¬ cies  enumerated  earlier.  And  in  2006  and  2008  they  were  able  to  do  so.  In 2006  the  Democrats  dramatically  improved  their  performance  among  white working-class  voters,  running  only  a  10-point  deficit,  down  from  a  20-point deficit  in  congressional  voting  in  2004.  The  Democrats  also  reduced  their  defi¬ cit  from  32  to  21  points  among  non-college-educated  whites  with  $50,000  to $75,000  in  household  income  and  completely  eliminated  their  deficit  among non-college-educated  whites  with  $30,000-850,000  in  household  income, going  from  22  points  down  in  2004  to  dead  even.36  In  the  election  of  2008 the  Democrats  lost  the  white  working  class  by  18  points,  also  an  improve- i8o  Teixeira ment  over  2004  when  they  had  lost  them  by  23  points,  but  worse  than  pre¬ election  polls  indicated  they  would  do.  As  it  turned  out,  Democrats  were able  to  achieve  a  solid  victory  even  with  this  large  white  working-class  defi¬ cit.  This  is  because  minority  turnout  and  support  were  at  record  highs  and white  college  graduate  support  for  the  Democrats  increased  smartly  as  well. So  an  18-point  white  working-class  deficit  was  in  the  end  adequate  to  produce a  solid  victory  for  the  Democrats,  rather  than  the  squeaker  that  many,  in¬ cluding  myself,  had  expected.  Indeed,  if  Obama  had  achieved  a  significantly lower  deficit  among  these  voters— say  in  the  10-  to  12-point  range— he  would have  won  in  a  true  landslide,  given  his  support  among  other  demographic groups.  But  Obama  did  not  attain  that:  his  white  working-class  deficit  (18 points)  was  very  similar  to  A1  Gore’s  (17  points).  It  is  also  interesting  to  com¬ pare  Michael  Dukakis’s  performance  in  1988  among  white  working-class  and white  college  graduates  to  Obama’s  performance.  In  1988  the  Democratic deficit  among  these  two  groups  was  identical:  20  points.  In  2008  the  white working-class  deficit  was  only  a  slight  improvement  (down  2  points),  but  the white  college  graduate  deficit  was  just  4  points,  a  16-point  Democratic  swing since  1988.  This  stubbornly  high  deficit  for  Democrats  among  white  working- class  voters  is  mitigated  by  the  greatly  diminished  share  of  the  voting  pool. According  to  the  exit  polls,  the  proportion  of  white  working-class  voters  is down  15  points  since  1988,  while  the  proportion  of  white  college  graduates  is up  4  points  and  of  minority  voters  up  11  points. On  the  state  level  Obama  did  stunningly  well  among  white  working-class voters  in  four  of  the  five  highly  competitive  states  that  the  Democrats  won in  2000  and  2004  (Michigan,  Minnesota,  Oregon,  and  Wisconsin).  The  aver¬ age  white  working-class  deficit  for  Kerry  in  these  states  in  2004  was  8  points. In  2008  Obama  had  an  average  advantage  in  these  states  of  6  points,  a  pro- Democratic  swing  of  14  points.  In  Pennsylvania,  however,  the  other  highly competitive  state  that  the  Democrats  won  in  2000  and  2004,  Obama  did worse  than  Kerry,  losing  the  white  working  class  by  15  points  as  opposed to  Kerry’s  10  points.  But  college-educated  whites  in  Pennsylvania  swung Obama’s  way  by  17  points,  turning  a  12-point  deficit  in  2004  into  a  5-point advantage  in  2008.  The  Democrats  were  also  helped  in  Pennsylvania  by  the rapidly  shifting  distribution  of  voters.  Since  1988  the  share  of  white  working- class  voters  has  declined  by  25  points,  while  the  share  of  white  college  gradu¬ ates  has  gone  up  16  points  and  the  minority  share  by  8  points. In  the  highly  competitive  states  that  the  Democrats  lost  in  both  2000  and 2004  (Florida,  Missouri,  Nevada,  and  Ohio)  the  pattern  was  different.  In  2004 the  average  Democratic  white  working-class  deficit  in  these  states  was  13 points;  in  2008  the  average  deficit  was  actually  slightly  worse  (14  points). The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  181 But  Obama  made  progress  in  other  ways.  Among  white  college  graduates  the Democrats  improved  their  average  margin  by  9  points.  And  minority  support went  up  substantially  and  in  some  cases  spectacularly.  Further,  in  each  of these  states  one  sees  the  same  long-term  trends  in  the  distribution  of  voters: fewer  white  working-class  voters,  more  white  college-educated  voters,  and more  minorities. One  factor  that  should  favor  the  Democrats,  albeit  over  the  longer  term, is  that  the  decline  of  the  white  working  class  is  likely  to  continue.  First,  there will  be  a  continuing  decline  in  the  white  population  as  a  whole.  By  the  presi¬ dential  election  of  2020,  the  Census  Bureau  projects  that  non-Hispanic  whites will  be  down  to  around  60%  of  the  population.  By  2050  that  share  will  have dropped  to  about  46%.  Educational  upgrading  is  also  likely  to  continue, though  it  may  slow.  A  working  paper  published  by  the  Census  Bureau  (Day and  Bauman  2000)  predicts  a  4-7  point  increase  in  the  high  school  comple¬ tion  rate,  a  7-12  point  increase  in  the  college  attendance  rate  (some  college or  higher),  and  a  4-5  point  increase  in  the  four-year- college  completion  rate by  2028. Occupational  upgrading  will  continue,  though  here  too  the  rate  may  slow. According  to  occupational  projections  to  2016  by  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statis¬ tics,  while  professional  (and  service)  jobs  will  grow  at  the  fastest  rate  among major  occupational  groups,  professional  occupations  will  increase  their  share of  jobs  by  only  about  a  percentage  point,  a  slowdown  from  the  rate  of  share increase  from  1950  to  2000  (changes  in  occupation  coding  make  the  compari¬ son  inexact).  In  addition,  managerial  occupations  will  grow  at  the  second- fastest  rate  (though  their  share  will  remain  flat). Income  upgrading  should  also  continue,  though  the  rate  is  very  difficult to  assess.  Recall  that  median  family  income  increased  about  150%  from  1947 to  2005.  But  most  of  that  increase  was  in  the  twenty-six-year  period  between 1947  and  1973,  when  family  income  more  than  doubled,  with  an  annual growth  rate  of  2.8%.  In  the  thirty-two  years  between  1973  and  2005,  income only  went  up  23%,  an  annual  growth  rate  of  o.6%.37  So  how  much  income goes  up  in  the  future  will  depend  very  much  on  whether  income  growth  fol¬ lows  the  pre-1973  or  post-1973  pattern,  or  something  in  between. Since  we  do  not  know  the  answer  to  this  question  and  recent  history  is inconclusive  — there  was  a  period  of  rapid  growth  in  median  family  income from  1995  to  2000  (up  11%),  followed  by  negative  growth  from  2000  to  2005 (down  2%)  — one  approach  is  to  use  the  growth  rate  over  the  entire  period 1947-2005  period  (1.6%),  which  in  effect  averages  the  growth  rates  in  the “good”  (1947-73)  and  “bad”  (1973-2005)  periods.  Applying  this  rate  to  me¬ dian  family  income  produces  an  estimate  of  $83,000  for  the  year  2030  (in 182  Teixeira 2005  dollars).  Moreover,  if  one  applies  this  rate  to  the  fortieth  percentile of  the  family  income  distribution,  the  fortieth  percentile  would  move  up  to around  $67,000  by  2030,  meaning  that  roughly  65%  of  families  in  that  year would  have  more  than  $60,000  in  income.  In  2005  the  corresponding  figure was  about  47%. The  downward  trajectory  of  the  white  working  class  therefore  seems  as¬ sured  if  its  rate  of  decline  is  uncertain.  As  with  the  data  since  the  Second World  War  reviewed  at  the  beginning  of  this  chapter,  it  appears  likely  that the  future  rate  of  decline  will  be  fastest  under  an  income-based  definition, slowest  under  an  occupation-based  definition,  and  intermediate  under  an education-based  definition.  More  precise  statements  about  the  projected population  share  of  the  white  working  class  are  difficult,  but  some  educated guesses  can  be  made. Looking  first  at  the  broad  education-based  definition  (whites  without  a four-year  college  degree),  the  rate  of  decline  of  the  white  working  class  since the  Second  World  War  has  been  0.57  percentage  points  a  year.  Adjusting  this rate  downward  a  bit  to  allow  for  the  expected  slowdown  in  educational  up¬ grading  and  projecting  it  forward  to  the  presidential  election  of  2020  yields an  estimate  of  41%  of  adults  in  the  white  working  class  and  perhaps  a  per¬ centage  point  more  of  voters.  Under  the  occupation-based  definition  (whites without  a  professional  or  managerial  job),  the  rate  of  decline  since  the  Sec¬ ond  World  War  has  been  0.47  percentage  points  a  year.  Adjusting  the  rate downward  to  allow  for  the  projected  slowdown  in  occupational  upgrading and  projecting  forward  to  2020  yields  an  estimate  of  37%  of  workers  in  the white  working  class.  Finally,  under  the  income-based  definition  (white  fami¬ lies  under  $60,000),  the  rate  of  decline  since  1947  has  been  0.91  percent¬ age  points  a  year.  Keeping  the  rate  the  same  and  projecting  forward  to  2020 yields  an  estimate  of  20%  of  families  qualifying  as  white  working  class.38 These  changes  now  make  it  possible  for  the  Democrats  to  build  majority support  with  smaller  proportions  of  the  white  working  class.  Conversely,  Re¬ publicans,  who  are  dependent  today  on  supermajorities  of  the  white  working- class  vote  to  cobble  together  a  majority  coalition,  will  need  ever  larger  ma¬ jorities  of  the  white  working-class  vote  over  time  to  sustain  their  coalition. DESPITE  THE  SETBACK  in  the  2010  midterms,  together  the  foregoing  trends have  put  the  Democrats  in  a  position  to  eventually  build  a  dominant  center- left  majority  in  the  United  States.  Fundamental  changes  in  the  American  elec¬ torate  are  more  likely  to  favor  them  than  the  GOP  for  a  considerable  time to  come.  As  recent  events  have  demonstrated,  however,  the  real  challenge for  the  Democrats  now  is  governance  — and  they  entered  office  at  a  particu- The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  183 larly  challenging  time,  with  the  most  serious  economic  crisis  since  the  Second World  War  gripping  the  country.  But  with  this  crisis  also  came  opportunity. It  was  far  more  feasible  for  Obama  and  the  Democrats  to  attain  passage  of large-scale  reforms  with  commensurate  levels  of  spending  than  it  would  have been  in  more  tranquil  times. Obama  took  advantage  of  this  situation.  Start  with  the  $787  billion  stimu¬ lus  bill  that  included  significant  investments  in  education  and  clean  energy. These  expenditures,  combined  with  extensive  interventions  to  stabilize  the banking  system,  pulled  the  United  States  economy  back  from  the  brink  of a  truly  catastrophic  meltdown  and  onto  a  growth  path  that  while  currently slow,  should  pick  up  considerably  in  the  future. And  then  there  is  healthcare  reform,  something  that  progressives  in America  have  been  trying  to  accomplish  for  nearly  a  century.  It  was  a  long, grueling  process,  but  a  healthcare  reform  bill  was  finally  passed  and  signed into  law  by  President  Obama.  It  covers  more  than  thirty  million  people  who were  previously  uninsured,  reforms  the  insurance  market  so  that  people  with pre-existing  conditions  cannot  be  denied  coverage,  and  much,  much  more. The  details  are  byzantine,  but  the  most  important  fact  is  this:  for  the  first time,  the  principle  that  everyone  in  America  should  have  access  to  affordable healthcare  has  been  enshrined  in  law.  The  law  will  have  to  be  extended  and modified  in  the  future,  but  the  stunning  nature  of  this  accomplishment  can¬ not  be  denied. Obama  also  delivered  on  his  promise  to  tackle  climate  change.  Besides  the investments  in  clean  energy  mentioned  above,  he  pushed  a  cap-and-trade energy  bill  through  the  House  of  Representatives,  although  it  unfortunately died  in  the  Senate.  And  Obama  traveled  to  Copenhagen,  where  he  helped negotiate  a  preliminary  agreement  that  may  eventually  lead  to  a  binding international  agreement  on  greenhouse  gas  emissions.  The  contrast  could not  be  sharper  with  the  Bush  administration’s  lack  of  interest  in  fighting  cli¬ mate  change.  There  is  also  a  sharp  contrast  with  the  Bush  administration’s approach  to  international  relations.  Obama  has  thoroughly  revamped  the United  States  approach  to  working  with  other  countries  and  international institutions,  replacing  Bush’s  unilateralism  with  an  open,  cooperative  multi¬ lateralism. Obama  achieved  one  more  important  legislative  goal:  a  regulatory  reform bill  for  the  financial  sector,  the  most  significant  such  legislation  since  the 1930s,  establishing  new  federal  regulatory  powers  to  police  financial  markets and  protect  consumers  and  reining  in  the  derivatives  market  that  lay  at  the heart  of  the  financial  crisis.  He  promised  to  take  bold  action  in  this  area  dur¬ ing  his  campaign. 184  Teixeira That  is  where  we  are  on  Obama’s  progressive  agenda.  But  what  of  Obama’s Democratic  majority?  Here  the  news  is  obviously  not  so  good.  Obama’s  ap¬ proval  rating  peaked  at  67%  in  the  Gallup  poll  around  the  time  of  his  inaugu¬ ration  in  January  2009.  Since  then  it  has  declined  considerably,  standing  at about  47%  across  all  polls  in  April  2011.  His  approval  ratings  are  lower  still on  the  economy,  the  budget  deficit,  and  healthcare. This  declining  public  support  for  Obama  and  his  policies  contributed  to the  Republicans’  2010  midterm  election  victories.  A  few  fundamental  or “structural”  factors  explain  this  outcome:  the  poor  state  of  the  economy;  the abnormally  conservative  composition  of  the  midterm  electorate;  and  the large  number  of  vulnerable  seats  in  conservative-leaning  areas.  Independent voters,  white  working-class  voters,  seniors,  and  men  broke  heavily  against the  Democrats  because  of  the  economy.  Turnout  levels  were  also  unusually low  among  young  and  minority  voters  and  unusually  high  among  seniors, whites,  and  conservatives,  thus  contributing  to  a  massively  skewed  midterm electorate.  The  Democrats  therefore  faced  a  predictable,  and  arguably  un¬ avoidable,  convergence  of  forces  (for  a  much  more  detailed  discussion  see Teixeira  and  Halpin  2010). Although  Obama  and  the  Democrats  lost  support  since  the  2008  election among  most  demographic  groups,  the  biggest  decline  was  among  the  white working  class.  This  makes  sense  for  two  reasons.  First,  this  group  is  very sensitive  to  economic  conditions,  and  those  conditions  have  been  terrible. Obama  may  have  succeeded  in  averting  an  economic  cataclysm,  but  he  could not  prevent  a  steady  rise  in  the  unemployment  rate  since  his  election  (though it  appears  that  that  rise  has  finally  abated).  In  November  2008  the  unem¬ ployment  rate  stood  at  6.8%.  By  the  following  November  it  was  10%,  and a  year  later  it  was  still  9.6%.  Second,  the  white  working  class,  even  more than  the  American  public  as  a  whole,  is  inclined  to  be  suspicious  of  govern¬ ment  interventions  and  spending,  of  which  there  has  been  a  considerable amount  since  the  election.  This  hostility  toward  “big  government”  was  bound to  be  inflamed  by  the  perceived  failure  of  these  government  actions  (if  we  are spending  so  much  money  to  fix  things,  why  is  the  economy  in  such  terrible shape?)  and  by  the  relentless  attacks  on  Obama  by  the  conservative  opposi¬ tion,  ranging  from  the  Republicans  in  Congress  to  “Tea  Party”  activists  at  the grassroots. It  is  important  to  note,  however,  that  although  their  loss  of  the  House  and the  reduction  of  their  Senate  majority  was  a  serious  rebuke  to  the  Democrats and  the  political  status  quo,  it  was  not  an  endorsement  of  a  conservative agenda.  Data  on  voter  opinions  expressed  in  pre-  and  post-election  polling confirms  that  the  2010  election  was  neither  a  mandate  for  antigovernment The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  185 and  Tea  Party  ideology  nor  an  endorsement  of  GOP  policies  on  taxes  and regulation.  Nor  did  the  election  turn  on  a  repudiation  of  Obama’s  healthcare plan,  despite  staunch  Republican  opposition. Given  all  this,  looking  ahead  toward  the  presidential  election  of  2012,  what is  the  prognosis  for  Obama’s  coalition?  Better  than  one  might  expect  in  the wake  of  the  recent  midterms.  In  this  regard  the  example  of  Ronald  Reagan  is instructive.  Reagan  had  to  contend  with  a  severe  recession,  just  like  Obama— indeed  for  Reagan,  unemployment  peaked  at  10.8%,  higher  than  Obama  has experienced.  At  about  this  point  in  Reagan’s  first  term,  his  approval  rating was  actually  lower  than  Obama’s  current  rating,  and  his  party  wound  up losing  twenty-six  House  seats  in  the  congressional  election  of  1982.  But  1983 and  1984  were  years  of  strong  economic  growth,  and  the  unemployment  rate declined  over  those  years,  reaching  7.2%  by  election  day  1984.  In  that  election Reagan  won  a  landslide  victory  with  59%  of  the  popular  vote. Obama’s  first  term  could  well  follow  a  similar  trajectory.  As  noted  above, his  party  lost  seats  in  2010,  largely  as  a  result  of  the  poor  economy  and  the historical  tendency  of  incumbent  parties  to  lose  seats  in  midterm  elections. But  by  2012  the  economic  situation  should  be  improved  and  unemploy¬ ment  lower— Obama’s  version  of  Reagan’s  “morning  in  America.”  Moreover, Obama  will  have  the  advantage  of  four  more  years  of  growth  in  his  demo¬ graphic  coalition  plus  an  election  (presidential)  in  which  that  coalition  is likely  to  turn  out  at  high  levels.  The  result,  I  believe,  will  be  a  victory  for Obama  in  2012  and  the  reemergence  of  the  Democratic  majority  that  we  saw in  the  United  States  presidential  election  of  2008. Notes 1.  Author’s  analysis  of  data  from  Current  Population  Survey  (CPS)  and  exit  polls. 2.  Author’s  analysis  of  2006  exit  polls  from  National  Election  Pool  (NEP). 3.  In  2009  the  Census  Bureau  issued  a  set  of  projections  that  are  “supplemental”  to the  2008  projections.  What  this  means  is  that  even  though  the  2008  projections  remain the  recommended  data  series  for  general  use,  the  2009  supplemental  projections  can be  used  to  assess  the  effects  of  different  immigration  scenarios  on  future  population levels  and  distribution.  Of  the  scenarios  provided,  the  “low  net  international  migra¬ tion,”  or  low  NIM,  which  projects  the  number  of  immigrants  per  year  to  increase  slowly to  2050,  is  fairly  close  to  the  original  2008  projections  and  quite  similar  to  the  projec¬ tions  produced  by  the  demographers  Jeffrey  Passel  and  D’Vera  Cohen  for  the  Pew  Re¬ search  Center  (“US  Population  Projections:  2005-2050,”  11  February  2008),  based  on a  constant  rate  of  immigration  relative  to  population  size.  The  low  NIM  scenario  puts the  majority-minority  crossover  point  at  2045.  Some  argue  that  the  constant  NIM  sce¬ nario  (under  which  the  number  of  immigrants  per  year  remains  constant  to  the  year 186  Teixeira 2050)  should  be  preferred,  since  it  corresponds  well  to  the  recent  experience  of  the United  States  with  immigrant  flows  (see  William  Frey,  “Immigration  and  the  Coming ‘Majority  Minority,’”  Brookings  Institution,  19  March  2010).  The  constant  NIM  scenario has  a  majority-minority  crossover  date  of  2050,  corresponding  to  the  date  frequently cited  in  popular  accounts  of  rising  diversity. 4.  See  Ruy  Teixeira,  http://www.emergingdemocraticmajorityweblog.com/donkey rising/archives/ooi234.php,  for  references  and  discussion. 5.  Author’s  analysis  of  2004  NEP  national  exit  polls. 6.  If  you  do  an  apples-to-apples  comparison  of  data;  see  Ruy  Teixeira,  http://www .emergingdemocraticmajorityweblog.com/donkeyrising/archives/001227.php,  for analysis  and  discussion. 7.  Author’s  analysis  of  data  from  Current  Population  Survey  (CPS)  and  exit  polls. 8.  Author’s  analysis  of  2000-2006  exit  polls. 9.  Author’s  analysis  of  data  from  CPS  and  exit  polls  and  Frey,  “Immigration  and  the Coming  ‘Majority  Minority.’” 10.  Figures  in  this  and  next  paragraph  based  on  author’s  analysis  of  2004  NEP  exit polls. 11.  Author’s  analysis  of  2004  NEP  exit  polls. 12.  Author’s  analysis  of  2006  NEP  exit  polls. 13.  Author’s  analysis  of  census  data  on  marital  status. 14.  Ibid. 15.  Author’s  analysis  of  census  data  on  educational  attainment. 16.  Author’s  analysis  of  1960-2004  National  Election  Study. 17.  Author’s  analysis  of  2006  NEP  exit  polls. 18.  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  occupational  projections. 19.  Judis  and  Teixeira  (2002);  author’s  analysis  of  2004  National  Election  Study. 20.  All  data  in  this  and  subsequent  paragraph  from  author’s  analysis  of  census  popu¬ lation  projections. 21.  Author’s  analysis  of  2008  census  national  population  projections,  2008  national NEP  exit  poll  and  2004  Current  Population  Survey  voter  supplement  data. 22.  Author’s  analysis  of  2002-2006  exit  polls. 23.  Author’s  analysis  of  2006  NEP  exit  polls. 24.  Author’s  analysis  of  2004  NEP  exit  polls,  except  for  the  figure  on  Jews,  which  is taken  from  Mellman,  Strauss,  Greenberg,  McCreesh,  and  Wald,  “The  Jewish  Vote  in 2004.” 25.  Author’s  analysis  of  data  from  2006  NEP  exit  polls. 26.  Author’s  analysis  of  2004  NEP  exit  polls. 27.  Author’s  analysis  of  2006  NEP  exit  polls. 28.  Data  in  this  and  following  paragraph  from  author’s  analysis  of  1940  census  and 2007  Current  Population  Survey  Annual  Social  and  Economic  Supplement. 29.  This  and  following  paragraph  based  on  author’s  analysis  of  1940  census  and 2006  American  Community  Survey  occupation  data. 30.  This  and  following  paragraph  based  on  author’s  analysis  of  1947  and  2005  Cur¬ rent  Population  Survey  Annual  Social  and  Economic  Supplement  income  data. The  Evolving  Democratic  Coalition  187 31.  Author’s  analysis  of  1940  census  and  2007  Current  Population  Survey  Annual Social  and  Economic  Supplement  education  data. 32.  Data  in  this  and  following  paragraph  are  conservative  extrapolations  from  Tei- xeira  and  Rogers  2000, 16-17. 33.  Data  in  this  paragraph  from  author’s  analysis  of  1992  and  1996  Voter  News  Ser¬ vice  (VNS)  national  exit  polls. 34.  Data  in  this  paragraph  from  author’s  analysis  of  2000  VNS  and  2004  NEP  na¬ tional  exit  polls. 35.  Data  in  this  paragraph  from  author’s  analysis  of  2004  NEP  national  exit  polls. 36.  All  data  in  this  paragraph  from  author’s  analysis  of  2006  NEP  national  exit  polls. 37.  This  and  following  paragraph  based  on  author’s  analysis  of  1947-2005  Current Population  Survey  Annual  Social  and  Economic  Supplement  income  data. 38.  This  paragraph  based  on  author’s  analysis  of  1940-2000  census  data  and  2007 Current  Population  Survey  Annual  Social  and  Economic  Supplement  education  data; author’s  analysis  of  1940  census  data  and  2006  American  Community  Survey  occupa¬ tion  data;  and  author’s  analysis  of  1947-2005  Current  Population  Survey  Annual  Social and  Economic  Supplement  income  data. Party  Politics  and  the American  Welfare  State Christopher  Howard Including  the  United  States  in  this  book  may  strike  some  readers  as  odd.  If one  aim  is  to  chart  the  transformation  of  left  parties  into  center-left  parties, why  study  a  polity  that  has  never  had  much  of  a  left?  For  years  scholars have  been  analyzing  the  sources  and  symptoms  of  “American  exceptional- ism.”  Their  central  question,  posed  and  answered  in  different  ways,  has  in¬ volved  the  weakness  of  left-wing  organizations  and  ideology  (e.g.,  Kingdon 1999;  Lipset  and  Marks  2000;  Sombart  1976  [1906]).  The  best  showing  of any  United  States  socialist  party  in  national  elections  was  a  meager  6%  of  the vote  —  and  that  was  way  back  in  1912.  The  power  of  organized  labor  was  never great  to  begin  with  and  declined  throughout  the  second  half  of  the  twentieth century.  The  size  of  government,  measured  by  public  spending  as  a  share  of GDP,  has  consistently  been  smaller  in  the  United  States  than  in  Europe.  When socialism  collapsed  across  Eastern  Europe  and  the  Soviet  Union  broke  apart, the  dominant  reaction  in  the  United  States  was  a  feeling  of  vindication,  not loss.  In  the  context  of  this  book,  it  would  seem  to  make  more  sense  to  focus on  countries  such  as  Sweden,  Germany,  France,  and  the  United  Kingdom, which  several  authors  do. Nevertheless,  there  are  compelling  reasons  to  investigate  the  American case.  As  the  editors  note  in  their  introductory  chapter,  the  United  States  is hardly  sui  generis.  Lower  union  membership,  the  shift  from  manufacturing to  services,  the  decline  of  Keynesianism  and  rise  of  neoliberalism,  and  new styles  of  political  campaigns  are  evident  on  both  sides  of  the  Atlantic.  The “new  social  risks”  discussed  by  Jenson  (this  volume)— rooted  in  longer  life expectancy,  higher  rates  of  female  employment,  and  more  single-parent  fami¬ lies— affect  millions  of  people  in  the  United  States  as  well  as  in  the  countries she  analyzes.  Policies  long  established  in  the  United  States,  such  as  means¬ testing  of  benefits  and  the  use  of  market  mechanisms  in  healthcare,  are  be- Party  Politics  189 coming  more  common  in  Europe.  As  we  shall  see,  recent  trends  in  social spending,  poverty,  and  inequality  are  also  similar  in  the  United  States  and Europe.  In  short,  we  should  not  exaggerate  American  exceptionalism. In  some  respects  the  United  States  is  a  good  choice  for  a  case  study.  It  is one  thing  to  argue  that  certain  forces  have  moved  social  democratic  and  labor parties  toward  the  center.  If  those  same  forces  affect  the  Democratic  Party, which  occupies  the  left  in  the  United  States  but  would  be  center-left  almost anywhere  in  Europe,  then  they  must  be  powerful  indeed.  Readers  who  won¬ der  where  the  European  left  could  be  heading  may  consider  the  American  ex¬ perience  a  useful  roadmap  — or  a  cautionary  tale. The  welfare  state  is  a  major  component  of  the  modern  state,  and  how  offi¬ cials  treat  their  welfare  states  tells  us  much  about  how  they  govern.  In  this chapter  I  will  indicate  how  Democratic  officials  have  changed  their  approach to  the  American  welfare  state  in  recent  decades.  When  creating  new  pro¬ grams  Democrats  have  gravitated  away  from  social  insurance  and  toward  tax expenditures  and  social  regulations.  While  protecting  some  programs,  espe¬ cially  those  for  the  elderly,  they  have  helped  retrench  programs  for  the  poor. The  net  effect  has  been  a  bigger  American  welfare  state.  That  is  what  a  classic left-wing  party  is  supposed  to  accomplish.  And  yet  these  changes  have  made it  harder,  not  easier,  to  reduce  poverty  and  inequality.  “Doing  more,  achiev¬ ing  less”  captures  the  current  state  of  United  States  social  policy. To  understand  these  developments  we  cannot  focus  solely  on  the  Demo¬ crats.  We  also  need  to  pay  close  attention  to  the  Republican  Party.  When  the American  welfare  state  was  established  between  the  1930s  and  1960s,  Re¬ publicans  were  clearly  the  minority  party.  Not  anymore.  Republicans  have made  important  gains  politically,  winning  five  of  the  last  eight  presidential elections.  Since  1980  they  have  controlled  at  least  one  house  of  Congress  two- thirds  of  the  time  (Stanley  and  Niemi  2008).  Without  some  cooperation  from Republicans,  the  story  would  have  been  gridlock.  Cooperation  meant  more than  simple  acquiescence;  at  times  Republican  leaders  took  the  lead  in  enact¬ ing  social  programs  and  shifting  the  distribution  of  social  benefits. Because  this  book  covers  so  much  territory  historically  and  geographi¬ cally,  readers  may  be  unfamiliar  with  the  specific  details  of  individual  coun¬ tries.  The  beginning  of  this  chapter  presents,  as  quickly  as  possible,  some  of the  significant  moments  and  trends  in  United  States  social  policy  since  1975. This  information  will  help  readers  to  understand  what  happened  before  we consider  how  and  why.  The  basic  point  is  that  the  American  welfare  state is  doing  more  but  accomplishing  less  than  it  did  in  the  immediate  postwar era.  This  chapter  then  analyzes  the  role  of  Democrats  and  Republicans  in  re¬ shaping  United  States  social  policy.  Neither  party  acted  in  a  vacuum;  signals 190  Howard from  the  general  public  and  from  voters  encouraged  elected  officials  to  find common  ground. The  Contemporary  American  Welfare  State Scholars  generally  agree  that  the  three  decades  following  the  Second  World War  were  a  golden  age  for  welfare  states.  Across  Europe  and  North  America new  social  programs  were  enacted  and  existing  programs  expanded.  Gov¬ ernment  social  spending  increased  dramatically.  Poverty  and  inequality  di¬ minished.  At  the  same  time,  the  power  of  left-wing  political  parties  was  rela¬ tively  high,  leading  many  scholars  to  link  the  remarkable  growth  of  welfare states  to  the  ascendance  of  these  parties  (Esping-Andersen  1985;  Huber  and Stephens  2001;  Shalev  1983).  The  United  States  was  no  exception.  Although Social  Security  was  created  in  1935,  it  did  not  become  an  important  source of  retirement  income  until  the  1950s,  and  it  experienced  rapid  growth  in  the 1960s  and  early  1970s.  Disability  insurance  started  in  the  1950s;  Medicare, Medicaid,  and  Food  Stamps  all  originated  in  the  1960s.  “Welfare,”  meaning income  support  for  poor,  single-parent  families,  grew  rapidly  in  the  1960s and  1970s.  The  nation  cut  the  poverty  rate  almost  in  half  (from  22.2%  to 12.3%)  between  i960  and  1975.1  Income  inequality  fell  sharply  around  the time  of  the  Second  World  War,  and  the  share  of  national  income  controlled by  the  richest  1%  dropped  gradually  in  the  1950s  and  1960s.  This  was  an  era when  Democrats  ruled  Congress  and  Democratic  presidents  such  as  Lyndon Johnson  made  bold  pronouncements  about  eradicating  poverty  and  building a  Great  Society  (Berkowitz  1991;  DeNavas-Walt,  Proctor,  and  Smith  2007; Derthick  1979;  Howard  2007a;  Piketty  and  Saez  2003). Scholars  sharply  disagree  over  what  has  happened  since  the  mid-1970s.  At one  end  of  the  spectrum  we  find  references  to  various  crises  of  the  welfare state— fiscal,  political,  ideological  (Kotlikoff  and  Burns  2004;  Mishra  1984; Offe  1984;  Stoesz  and  Karger  1992).  Less  ominously,  several  studies  find  evi¬ dence  of  retrenchment  as  countries  tightened  eligibility  for  social  programs, lowered  benefits,  and  introduced  forms  of  privatization  (Allan  and  Scruggs 2004;  Clayton  and  Pontusson  1998;  Huber  and  Stephens  2001;  Korpi  and Palme  2003;  Pontusson  2005a).  Or  retrenchment  occurred  indirectly  as  gov¬ ernments  failed  to  address  growing  social  needs  (Hacker  2004;  Taylor-Gooby ed.  2004).  Other  scholars  are  more  optimistic  and  stress  the  resilience  of  mod¬ ern  welfare  states.  “Thus  in  most  of  the  affluent  democracies,  the  politics  of social  policy  centers  on  the  renegotiation,  restructuring,  and  modernization  of the  terms  of  the  post-war  social  contract  rather  than  its  dismantling”  (Pierson 2002,  370;  see  also  Brooks  and  Manza  2007;  Pierson  1996;  Wilensky  2002).2 Party  Politics  191 While  the  American  welfare  state  never  reached  the  crisis  stage,  there  cer¬ tainly  were  episodes  of  retrenchment.  The  most  prominent  cutbacks  came in  1996,  when  officials  replaced  Aid  to  Families  with  Dependent  Children (AFDC),  a  core  “welfare”  program,  with  Temporary  Assistance  for  Needy Families  (TANF).  This  was  not  a  simple  one-for-one  exchange:  AFDC  was  a budgetary  entitlement,  but  spending  on  TANF  was  capped;  AFDC  imposed  no time  limit  on  recipients,  but  TANF  did.  The  goal  was  clearly  to  reduce  gov¬ ernment  support  for  poor  families  with  children.  The  current  TANF  caseload is  less  than  half  the  size  of  the  AFDC  caseload  circa  1996.  This  same  bill  in¬ cluded  large  cuts  to  the  means-tested  Food  Stamps  and  Supplemental  Secu¬ rity  Income  programs,  most  of  them  affecting  recent  immigrants.  Other  social programs  were  cut  less  dramatically.  Officials  increased  the  normal  retire¬ ment  age  for  Social  Security  from  sixty-five  to  sixty-seven,  which  reduced  the number  of  years  that  people  can  collect  benefits.  It  became  more  difficult  to qualify  for  disability  insurance  in  the  1980s  (Howard  2007a;  Weaver  2000). The  best  example  of  outright  termination  occurred  in  1981.  As  officials  were cutting  the  budgets  of  several  social  programs,  they  completely  eliminated public  service  employment  (PSE).  At  its  peak  in  the  late  1970s  PSE  employed 725,000  people.  Many  of  these  people  were  teenagers  and  racial  minorities who  had  great  difficulty  finding  jobs  in  the  private  sector  (Mucciaroni  1990).3 Nevertheless,  for  every  cutback  or  termination  there  was  at  least  one  ex¬ pansion.  Social  Security,  Medicare,  and  Medicaid  became  three  of  the  largest items  in  the  national  budget.  All  these  programs  benefited  the  elderly,  which helps  to  explain  why  the  poverty  rate  for  senior  citizens  continued  to  decline after  1975  (DeNavas-Walt,  Proctor,  and  Smith  2007).  And  the  United  States continued  to  create  social  programs.  Several  of  these  addressed  the  “new social  risks”  discussed  by  Jenson  (this  volume),  such  as  the  spread  of  low- wage  work  and  the  plight  of  children.  The  Earned  Income  Tax  Credit  (EITC), enacted  in  1975,  provides  income  support  to  millions  of  low-income  Ameri¬ cans,  especially  those  with  dependent  children.  The  primary  objective  of  the EITC  is  to  “make  work  pay”  by  providing  subsidies  to  taxpayers  who  earn  in¬ come  from  employment.4  The  Child  Tax  Credit  (1997)  benefits  millions  more families  with  children  and  is  not  means-tested.  These  two  tax  credits  cost the  United  States  government  over  $100  billion  in  forgone  revenues  and  tax refunds  in  2009  (U.S.  Congress,  Joint  Committee  on  Taxation,  2010).  To  put this  figure  in  perspective,  it  was  greater  than  what  the  government  spent  on TANF,  Food  Stamps,  and  public  housing  combined.  Another  new  policy  de¬ signed  to  help  parents  balance  work  and  family  was  the  Family  and  Medical Leave  Act  (FMLA),  enacted  in  1993.  The  FMLA  mandated  twelve  weeks  of parental  leave,  a  first  for  the  nation. 192  Howard With  so  many  Americans  uninsured  or  underinsured,  the  United  States  has had  many  opportunities  to  innovate  in  healthcare.  The  Consolidated  Omni¬ bus  Budget  Reconciliation  Act  (COBRA,  1986),  was  designed  to  make  health insurance  more  portable  for  those  who  were  between  jobs.  A  second  law, the  Health  Insurance  Portability  and  Accountability  Act  (HIPAA,  1996),  was supposed  to  make  it  harder  for  private  insurers  to  deny  coverage  to  people with  preexisting  medical  conditions.  The  Emergency  Medical  Treatment  and Labor  Act  (1986)  compelled  virtually  every  hospital  to  provide  emergency care  to  all  patients,  even  those  without  health  insurance.  In  addition,  new spending  programs  took  root.  The  State  Children’s  Health  Insurance  Program (SCHIP,  later  renamed  CHIP)  was  enacted  in  1997.  The  goal  of  this  new  block grant  was  to  extend  health  insurance  to  low-income  children,  especially those  from  families  with  incomes  too  high  for  the  existing  Medicaid  pro¬ gram.  Congress  approved  a  large  prescription  drug  benefit  for  the  elderly  in 2003.  Annual  spending  for  this  benefit  is  soon  expected  to  exceed  $50  billion (Henry  J.  Kaiser  Family  Foundation  2008;  Howard  2007a).5  These  episodes lacked  the  drama  of  the  attempted  Clinton  health  plan,  but  they  were  clearly important.  And  then,  of  course,  historic  changes  to  health  policy  were  en¬ acted  in  2010.  Over  time  the  ranks  of  the  uninsured  are  expected  to  drop  sub¬ stantially  (but  not  disappear),  and  costs  are  expected  to  rise  more  slowly.  I will  have  more  to  say  about  this  episode  later  in  the  chapter. Apart  from  these  new  social  programs,  the  other  major  breakthrough  oc¬ curred  in  disability  policy.  The  Americans  with  Disabilities  Act  (ADA)  became law  in  1990.  It  compelled  innumerable  public  agencies  and  private  businesses to  make  greater  accommodations  for  their  disabled  customers  and  employ¬ ees.  As  with  COBRA,  HIPAA,  and  the  FMLA,  the  United  States  government tried  to  effect  social  change  without  spending  taxpayers’  dollars. The  net  result  of  retrenchment  and  expansion  has  been  growth.  Measured by  the  number  of  social  programs,  the  American  welfare  state  is  larger  now than  it  was  thirty  years  ago.  Trends  in  social  spending  tell  the  same  story. According  to  the  Organisation  for  Economic  Cooperation  and  Development (OECD),  the  United  States  devoted  13.1%  of  GDP  to  its  welfare  state  in  1980. This  is  what  most  studies  refer  to  as  a  nation’s  “welfare  state  effort,”  and  it  in¬ cludes  public  spending  at  all  levels  of  government.  By  2005,  the  most  recent year  for  which  figures  are  available,  that  figure  had  risen  to  15.9%.  We  see similar  trends  in  other  affluent  democracies.  The  Canadian  welfare  state  grew from  13.7%  to  16.5%  of  GDP  during  this  same  era.  The  OECD  average  rose  from 16.0%  to  20.6%  of  GDP  between  1980  and  2005  (OECD  n.d.;  OECD  2007a).6 These  figures  actually  understate  the  true  level  of  social  spending  because they  omit  a  variety  of  tax  expenditures,  or  what  the  OECD  calls  tax  breaks  for Party  Politics  193 social  purposes  (tbsps).  Tax  expenditures  refer  to  a  variety  of  exceptions  to the  normal  tax  code  such  as  tax  credits  and  tax  deductions.  Many  countries have  created  special  provisions  in  their  tax  codes  to  address  a  variety  of  so¬ cial  problems,  and  this  indirect  spending  deserves  to  be  counted  just  as  much as  traditional  forms  of  direct  spending  do.  Tax  expenditures  have  been  quite common  in  the  United  States.  Besides  the  Earned  Income  Tax  Credit  and  the Child  Tax  Credit,  notable  examples  include  tax  breaks  for  employer-provided pensions  and  health  insurance,  and  the  home  mortgage  interest  deduction. Since  1980  the  largest  of  these  tax  expenditures  have  grown  faster  than  tra¬ ditional  forms  of  social  spending.  Tax  expenditures  helped  fuel  the  growth  of the  American  welfare  state  (Adema  and  Ladaique  2005;  Howard  2007b). Such  growth  was  impressive  on  several  counts.  It  occurred  even  as  the growth  in  overall  government  spending  was  negative  or  close  to  zero  in many  OECD  countries.  Thus  the  welfare  state  has  accounted  for  a  gradually increasing  share  of  government  spending  in  the  United  States  and  abroad. One  might  argue  that  this  growth  simply  reflected  greater  social  needs,  par¬ ticularly  the  aging  of  the  population.  Castles  (2004)  has  calculated  the  ratio of  social  spending  to  dependents— defined  as  people  over  the  age  of  sixty-five plus  all  working-age  adults  who  are  unemployed  — and  found  that  the  United States  spent  more  per  dependent  in  1998  than  it  did  in  1980.  If  one  creates  a comparable  ratio  for  social  spending  and  the  poverty  population,  the  story remains  the  same:  the  ratio  is  larger  now  than  it  was  a  quarter-century  ago. For  the  entire  population,  real  social  spending  per  capita  has  also  increased substantially  in  the  United  States  since  1980.  Finally,  one  might  ask  whether the  rapid  growth  in  medical  costs  has  been  largely  responsible  for  the  growth in  social  spending.  It  certainly  has  played  a  part,  but  the  public  share  of  total health  spending  in  the  United  States  has  grown  too  (OECD  2007b).  Changes to  Medicaid  and  the  creation  of  SCHIP  helped  to  increase  the  government’s role  in  paying  for  medical  care.  The  new  drug  benefit  for  the  elderly  will  help sustain  this  trend. Nevertheless,  despite  this  growth  the  American  welfare  state  has  appar¬ ently  lost  its  ability  to  fight  poverty  and  inequality.  Since  the  mid-1970s  the poverty  rate  has  fluctuated  between  11%  and  15%,  depending  on  the  economy. Although  the  rate  was  the  same  in  1975  and  2006,  the  United  States  economy was  just  pulling  out  of  recession  in  1975,  whereas  recovery  from  the  2001  re¬ cession  was  well  under  way  by  2006.  Severe  poverty,  meaning  income  of  less than  half  the  poverty  line,  increased  from  3.7%  to  5.2%  of  the  population between  1975  and  2006.  In  addition,  income  inequality  has  been  worsening. The  most  common  indicator  is  the  Gini  coefficient,  which  ranges  from  o  (total equality)  to  1  (total  inequality,  i.e.,  one  person  has  all  the  income).  According 194  Howard to  the  Luxembourg  Income  Study,  the  Gini  coefficient  in  the  United  States  was 0.318  in  1974.  By  2004  it  had  risen  to  0.372.  The  U.S.  Census  Bureau,  using  a different  methodology,  calculated  that  the  Gini  coefficient  moved  from  0.395 to  0.470  during  this  period.7  The  richest  one-fifth  of  the  nation  controlled 50%  of  national  income  in  2006,  up  from  44%  in  1975.  The  richest  of  the  rich saw  their  incomes  grow  even  faster  (DeNavas-Walt,  Proctor,  and  Smith  2007; Luxembourg  Income  Study  n.d.;  Piketty  and  Saez  2003;  U.S.  Bureau  of  the Census  n.d.).8 The  United  States  has  not  been  the  only  country  experiencing  difficul¬ ties.  Income  inequality  has  grown  in  Australia,  Canada,  Germany,  Italy,  Nor¬ way,  Sweden,  and  the  United  Kingdom  in  recent  decades.  Poverty  rates  have remained  constant  or  slightly  increased  in  a  number  of  wealthy  democra¬ cies  (Kenworthy  2008;  Luxembourg  Income  Study  n.d.).  The  combination  of spending  more  on  social  welfare  and  achieving  less  has  thus  become  more common  among  nations.  This  insight  may  help  reconcile  some  of  the  conflict¬ ing  judgments  discussed  earlier  in  this  chapter.  Crisis,  retrenchment,  and  re¬ silience  may  depend  on  which  features  of  the  welfare  state  are  being  studied. It  is  quite  possible  that  the  American  welfare  state  has  been  doing  more and  accomplishing  less  because  the  United  States  economy  has  been  gener¬ ating  more  poverty  and  inequality  than  it  used  to  do.  To  test  this  argument we  need  to  know  how  much  money  people  had  before  taxes  and  government transfers,  or  what  are  sometimes  referred  to  as  “market  poverty”  and  “market inequality.”  Market  poverty  rates  have  gradually  increased  and  decreased  in recent  decades,  with  no  clear  upward  trend.  Market  inequality,  on  the  other hand,  has  definitely  increased  (Kenworthy  2008;  U.S.  Bureau  of  the  Census 1992;  U.S.  Bureau  of  the  Census  2001;  U.S.  Bureau  of  the  Census  2007).  We might  conclude  that  changes  in  the  United  States  economy  have  been  widen¬ ing  the  gap  between  rich  and  poor,  and  that  public  policy  has  been  slow  to adapt  (Hacker  2004). While  true,  and  important,  this  conclusion  leads  us  to  focus  on  govern¬ ment  inaction,  and  yet  we  know  that  the  United  States  has  been  creating  a number  of  new  social  programs  and  increasing  social  spending.  Elected  offi¬ cials  have  not  ignored  the  plight  of  citizens  trying  to  afford  healthcare  and balance  the  demands  of  work  and  family.  Officials  have  tried  to  help  some  of these  people  — particularly  those  in  the  middle  and  upper  middle  classes.  Re¬ cent  laws  designed  to  shore  up  private  health  insurance  (COBRA  and  HIPAA) have  helped  workers  who  have  such  insurance,  who  tend  to  be  well-educated professionals,  union  members,  and  public  employees.  The  Family  and  Medi¬ cal  Leave  Act  had  a  large  exemption  for  small  businesses,  whose  workers  tend Party  Politics  195 to  have  less  education  and  lower  incomes.  Moreover,  because  the  FMLA  only required  unpaid  parental  leave,  it  has  provided  more  help  to  families  that  can afford  to  live  without  a  paycheck.  Similarly,  families  earning  over  $50,000 have  been  the  main  beneficiaries  of  the  new  Child  Tax  Credit  (Howard  2007a; Howard  2007b;  U.S.  Congress,  Joint  Committee  on  Taxation,  2010).  Such  poli¬ cies  are  a  good  way  to  expand  a  welfare  state  without  making  much  progress against  poverty  or  inequality. A  number  of  older  social  programs  fit  this  same  profile.  The  clearest  evi¬ dence  comes  from  the  largest  tax  expenditures.  The  United  States  tax  code has  provided  a  huge  and  growing  subsidy  for  private  pensions  (roughly  $100 billion  a  year).  On  average,  one-half  of  United  States  workers  participated  in some  sort  of  tax-favored  retirement  plan  in  2003.  But  averages  can  be  deceiv¬ ing.  The  participation  rates  ranged  from  20%  for  workers  earning  less  than $20,000  to  80%  for  workers  earning  over  $120,000.  Higher-income  workers also  contributed  more  to  their  plans  and  thus  received  a  larger  per  capita subsidy  from  the  government  (Congressional  Budget  Office  2007).  Sheils  and Haught  (2004)  have  calculated  that  tax  breaks  for  private  health  insurance were  worth  ten  times  more  to  a  family  earning  over  $100,000  than  to  a  family earning  less  than  $20,000.  Taxpayers  earning  over  $100,000  claimed  three- quarters  of  the  value  of  the  home  mortgage  interest  deduction,  the  nation’s largest  housing  program  (U.8.  Congress,  Joint  Committee  on  Taxation,  2010). Considering  that  homes  are  the  largest  single  asset  for  many  families,  this  tax break  exacerbates  inequalities  in  wealth. Tax  expenditures  are  sometimes  criticized  for  redistributing  income  from poor  to  rich,  but  that  is  not  entirely  accurate.  Few  Americans  earning  less than  $40,000  a  year  pay  any  income  taxes.  Whatever  they  owe  is  offset  by  the standard  deduction,  personal  exemptions,  and  the  Earned  Income  Tax  Credit. Overwhelmingly,  income  taxes  are  paid  by  the  upper  middle  class  and  the rich,  people  earning  over  $100,000  (U.S.  Congress,  Joint  Committee  on  Taxa¬ tion,  2010).  The  individual  income  tax  is  one  of  the  more  progressive  taxes in  the  United  States— certainly  more  progressive  than  payroll  taxes  or  sales taxes.  As  a  result,  any  deductions,  exemptions,  or  credits  are  usually  worth more  to  people  in  the  higher  tax  brackets.  Someone  in  the  28%  tax  bracket who  puts  $1,000  in  a  40i(k)  pension  plan  will  benefit  more  than  someone in  the  15%  bracket  who  puts  away  the  same  amount  of  money.  This  example helps  to  explain  why  major  tax  expenditures  for  health,  housing,  and  pen¬ sions  are  skewed  toward  the  more  affluent.  Another  reason  for  the  skew  is that  these  same  people  can  afford  to  buy  bigger  homes  and  save  more  for  re¬ tirement.  Thus  to  the  extent  that  tax  expenditures  redistribute  income,  most 196  Howard of  the  impact  is  limited  to  the  upper  half  of  the  income  distribution.  Tax  ex¬ penditures  help  the  haves  from  falling  farther  behind  the  have-lots. While  social  policy  in  recent  decades  has  favored  the  middle  and  upper middle  classes,  less  affluent  Americans  have  not  fared  so  well.  The  lives  of low-income  children  hardly  improved.  True,  they  were  helped  by  the  expan¬ sion  of  Medicaid,  the  creation  of  SCHIP,  and  the  remarkable  growth  of  the Earned  Income  Tax  Credit.9  Greater  access  to  public  health  insurance  helped to  offset  the  decline  of  private  health  insurance,  but  the  rate  of  uninsured children  was  basically  the  same  in  2001  as  it  had  been  in  1977  (Cunningham and  Kirby  2004).  The  EITC  helped  millions  of  families  among  the  working poor,  and  its  expansion  in  the  1990s  coincided  with  a  meaningful  decline  in the  child  poverty  rate.  Still,  the  rate  was  essentially  the  same  in  2005  as  1975 (DeNavas-Walt,  Proctor,  and  Smith  2007).  The  nonworking  poor  have  been the  big  losers.  They  were  the  ones  who  were  kicked  off  welfare  after  1996. They  were  the  ones  who  watched  the  value  of  welfare  and  unemployment benefits  gradually  erode  in  the  face  of  inflation.10  They  were  the  ones  who could  not  qualify  for  unemployment  benefits  because  they  worked  part-time or  had  been  employed  only  a  short  time  before  being  laid  off  (Graetz  and Mashaw  1999).  Recent  immigrants  also  found  it  more  difficult  to  get  benefits. In  many  ways  the  United  States  safety  net  has  been  compromised.  Little  won¬ der  that  poverty  stopped  declining  and  severe  poverty  has  been  on  the  rise. Party  Politics  and  Social  Policy Since  the  1970s  divided  government  has  been  the  norm  in  the  United  States. One  might  suspect  that  “doing  more,  achieving  less”  represented  a  compro¬ mise  between  the  two  parties:  Democrats  enacted  new  programs  and  in¬ creased  social  spending,  while  Republicans  made  sure  that  government  ex¬ pansion  did  little  to  reduce  poverty  or  inequality.  The  reality  turns  out  to  be more  complicated.  Consider  recent  legislative  milestones.  The  Clinton  ad¬ ministration  signed  off  on  the  Family  and  Medical  Leave  Act,  new  HIPAA regulations,  and  the  Child  Tax  Credit,  which  was  exactly  what  we  would  ex¬ pect  Democrats  to  do.  But  a  number  of  social  programs  were  enacted  during Republican  administrations.  President  Ford  signed  the  Earned  Income  Tax Credit  into  law.  The  first  President  Bush  and  a  number  of  congressional  Re¬ publicans  pushed  for  the  Americans  with  Disabilities  Act.  After  the  ADA  was enacted,  Bush  referred  to  it  several  times  as  one  of  the  crowning  achievements of  his  administration.  An  early  version  of  the  Child  Tax  Credit  appeared  in  the GOP  Contract  with  America.  President  George  W.  Bush  was  instrumental  in Party  Politics  197 passing  the  new  drug  benefit  for  senior  citizens  (Howard  2007a).11  These  pro¬ grams  were  every  bit  as  important  as  those  passed  under  Clinton. By  the  same  token,  Clinton’s  health  plan  went  down  to  defeat  even  though Democrats  controlled  the  White  House  and  both  houses  of  Congress.  Al¬ though  President  Reagan  cut  or  eliminated  several  means-tested  programs in  1981,  the  welfare  reform  law  signed  by  President  Clinton  in  1996  was  ar¬ guably  more  severe.  It  was  Clinton,  after  all,  who  promised  to  “end  welfare as  we  know  it.”  Republicans  also  defended  certain  social  programs  against cutbacks,  especially  the  sizable  tax  breaks  for  health  insurance,  retirement pensions,  and  housing  (Howard  1997;  Howard  2007a).  When  Ronald  Reagan signed  the  Tax  Reform  Act  of  1986,  which  included  the  first  major  increase  to the  Earned  Income  Tax  Credit,  he  publicly  declared  the  EITC  to  be  “the  best antipoverty  bill,  the  best  profamily  measure,  and  the  best  job-creation  pro¬ gram  ever  to  come  out  of  the  Congress.”12 Trends  in  social  spending  have  also  been  confusing.  The  nation’s  welfare state  effort  declined  during  the  Reagan  administration.  That  was  no  surprise. But  it  also  declined  under  Clinton.  Thank  goodness  for  the  Bush  family.  Social spending  increased  during  the  father’s  administration  and  the  son’s  first  term, and  those  gains  more  than  offset  what  happened  under  Reagan  and  Clinton. Spending  also  grew  during  President  Carter’s  time  in  office  (OECD  n.d.;  OECD 1985;  OECD  2007a). Democratic  administrations  have  performed  somewhat  better  than  their Republican  counterparts  on  key  social  indicators.  The  poverty  rate  reached  a lower  point  under  Carter  (11.4%)  and  Clinton  (11.3%)  than  it  ever  did  under Reagan  (13.0%),  George  H.  W.  Bush  (12.8%),  or  George  W.  Bush  (11.7%).  Of all  these  presidents  only  Clinton  made  any  real  progress  against  poverty.  Ana¬ lyzing  the  distribution  of  income  between  1948  and  2001,  Bartels  (2004)  has shown  that  inequality  grew  considerably  faster  when  Republicans  were  in  the White  House.  While  this  pattern  held  true  for  the  entire  postwar  era,  it  was less  pronounced  after  1975.  As  measured  by  the  Gini  index,  inequality  was basically  unchanged  under  Carter  and  actually  increased  a  bit  under  Clinton (Democrats  made  a  bigger  dent  in  inequality  under  Presidents  Kennedy  and Johnson).  Inequality  has  definitely  grown  under  the  three  most  recent  Re¬ publican  administrations  (DeNavas-Walt,  Proctor,  and  Smith  2007). Thus  it  appears  to  be  the  responsibility  of  both  political  parties  that  the American  welfare  state  is  “doing  more”  and  “achieving  less.”  A  closer  look  at public  opinion  and  elections  will  help  us  to  understand  why  the  two  parties converged  enough  to  make  meaningful  changes  to  social  policy.  Over  the  last few  decades  opinion  surveys  have  sent  a  clear  and  consistent  message:  Ameri- 198  Howard cans  want  their  government  to  play  a  central  role  in  social  welfare,  and  in most  cases  that  means  spending  more,  not  less.  The  main  exceptions  are  wel¬ fare,  which  most  Americans  dislike,  and  unemployment  benefits,  which  trig¬ ger  mixed  feelings.  The  biggest  pieces  of  the  welfare  state— retirement  pen¬ sions  and  healthcare— receive  strong  backing  (Gilens  1999;  Howard  2007a). Although  support  has  been  stronger  among  self-identified  Democrats, most  Republicans  also  expect  government  to  help  the  elderly,  the  sick,  and the  poor.  When  Republicans  made  history  by  capturing  both  houses  of  Con¬ gress  in  1994,  a  large  majority  of  people  who  called  themselves  strong  Repub¬ licans  said  that  current  spending  on  Social  Security  was  either  too  little  (43%) or  about  right  (44%).  When  President  George  W.  Bush  was  reelected  in  2004 Republican  support  for  Social  Security  was,  if  anything,  a  little  higher.  More¬ over,  a  majority  of  Republicans  in  2004  said  that  too  little  was  being  spent  on education  and  health.  Only  one  of  eight  Republicans  felt  that  too  much  was being  spent  to  help  the  poor.13  Republican  officials  may  have  wanted  to  slow the  growth  of  the  American  welfare  state,  but  they  risked  alienating  their core  supporters  if  they  tried  to  shrink  it. Americans  did  not,  however,  want  officials  to  expand  the  welfare  state  in any  manner  that  they  pleased.  Most  Americans,  regardless  of  party  affiliation, appeared  to  offer  little  support  for  redistributing  income  from  rich  to  poor. And  most  Americans,  regardless  of  party  affiliation,  did  not  trust  their  gov¬ ernment  very  much.  In  this  environment  anyone  pushing  for  a  guaranteed  in¬ come  or  national  health  insurance  was  going  to  be  rebuffed.  Relying  on  what are  known  as  “tax  expenditures”  and  social  regulations  was  the  better  way  to go.  Tax  expenditures  usually  relied  on  individuals  and  businesses  to  provide the  desired  goods  and  services  and  to  complete  the  necessary  forms.  Social regulations  likewise  tried  to  harness  the  private  sector  to  fulfill  social  objec¬ tives.  Neither  policy  tool,  as  discussed  above,  did  much  to  narrow  the  gap  be¬ tween  rich  and  poor  (Howard  2007a). Of  course  public  opinion  in  general  may  matter  less  than  the  views  of those  who  actually  vote.  The  American  electorate  does  not,  in  fact,  look  like the  American  public.  With  turnout  running  between  55%  and  60%  in  presi¬ dential  elections,  and  around  40%  in  off-year  elections,  lots  of  Americans  are not  voting.  They  are  disproportionately  less  educated  and  of  lower  income.  In the  election  of  2004,  for  instance,  almost  three-fourths  of  college  graduates reported  voting,  compared  to  only  one-third  of  high  school  dropouts.  People earning  less  than  $15,000  represented  14%  of  the  population  but  only  8%  of actual  voters  (DeNavas-Walt,  Proctor,  and  Smith  2007;  Stanley  and  Niemi 2008). 14  Voting  is  not  unique  in  this  regard.  Other  indicators  of  political  par¬ ticipation-campaigning,  donating  money,  contacting  officials,  and  belong- Party  Politics  199 ing  to  interest  groups  — all  increase  with  income,  education,  and  age  (Camp¬ bell  2003;  Jacobs  and  Skocpol  eds.  2005;  Verba,  Schlozman,  and  Brady  1995). Moreover,  inequalities  in  political  participation  appear  to  be  widening.  Ac¬ cording  to  data  collected  by  National  Election  Studies,  the  gaps  in  voter  turn¬ out  are  growing  larger  between  voters  with  high  and  low  levels  of  education, and  high  and  low  incomes.15 During  the  late  twentieth  century  and  the  early  twenty-first,  a  period  when the  two  parties  were  so  evenly  matched  and  control  of  government  changed so  frequently,  Democrats  and  Republicans  worked  consistently  to  expand  so¬ cial  benefits  for  the  politically  strong  and  periodically  to  retrench  programs for  the  politically  weak.  Members  of  both  parties  protected  tax  breaks  for housing,  healthcare,  and  pensions,  all  of  which  were  targeted  at  the  more affluent  members  of  society.  Clinton  wanted  the  Child  Tax  Credit  to  show middle-  and  upper-middle-class  families  that  the  Democratic  Party  had  not forgotten  them.  Bush  wanted  the  new  drug  benefit  to  show  that  Democrats were  not  the  only  ones  who  cared  about  senior  citizens.  Members  of  both parties  pushed  welfare  reform  to  show  middle-class  voters  that  welfare  de¬ pendence  among  the  poor  would  no  longer  be  tolerated.  Democratic  and  Re¬ publican  officials  thus  had  similar  reasons  for  expanding  the  American  wel¬ fare  state  and  for  not  pushing  hard  to  reduce  poverty  and  inequality.  They  had middle-  and  upper-middle-class  constituents  to  satisfy.  They  could  help  those constituents  pay  for  health  insurance,  save  for  retirement,  purchase  child care,  and  buy  a  home— in  effect,  to  achieve  the  American  Dream.16  Other  fac¬ tors,  specific  to  each  party,  also  moved  them  in  this  direction. Democrats In  several  respects  the  Democratic  vision  of  social  policy  has  changed  since the  1960s.  More  accurately,  the  views  of  many  Democratic  officials  have  mod¬ erated.  The  party  is  still  so  large  and  diverse  that  broad  generalizations  are hard  to  make;  some  contemporary  Democrats  would  have  been  quite  at  home in  the  days  of  the  New  Deal  and  the  Great  Society.  For  the  most  part,  though, the  current  generation  of  party  leaders  has  stressed  equality  of  opportunity over  result,  economic  growth  over  redistribution,  and  work  over  welfare. They  have  preached  fiscal  discipline  and  become  more  concerned  about  defi¬ cits  (Baer  2000;  Pierson  1998;  Shoch  2008).17  One  should  not  exaggerate  the extent  of  change.  The  New  Deal  relied  on  a  combination  of  work  programs and  cash  relief.  The  Economic  Opportunity  Act  of  1964  was  one  of  the  mile¬ stones  of  the  Great  Society.18  In  historical  perspective,  recent  changes  in  the Democratic  Party  have  been  modest  but  meaningful. 200  Howard One  key  change  has  been  the  choice  of  policy  tools  used  to  remedy  social problems.  During  the  New  Deal  and  Great  Society  the  main  tools  were  social insurance,  financed  by  payroll  taxes,  and  grants,  financed  by  general  reve¬ nues.  Democrats  since  the  1970s  have  shied  away  from  payroll  tax  financing. Clinton  officials  used  all  kinds  of  mechanisms  to  fund  health  reform— higher tobacco  taxes,  administrative  savings,  contingent  caps  on  insurance  premi¬ ums,  and  a  complicated  set  of  charges  on  employers  — but  not  payroll  taxes (Skocpol  1996).  More  recently,  while  congressional  Democrats  objected  to several  features  of  Bush’s  proposed  drug  benefit  for  the  elderly,  few  wanted to  rely  on  payroll  taxes  rather  than  the  combination  of  general  revenues  and monthly  premiums  that  eventually  passed.  Faced  with  problems  in  existing social  insurance  programs,  few  Democrats  proposed  a  general  increase  in payroll  taxes.  When  the  Social  Security  trust  fund  started  to  run  dangerously low  in  the  early  1980s,  the  main  answer  was  to  increase  the  retirement  age. When  Medicare  experienced  financial  troubles,  the  main  answer  was  to  limit reimbursements  to  doctors  and  hospitals  (Oberlander  2003). This  shift  was  part  of  a  larger  change  in  policy  discourse  (Campbell  and Morgan  2005).  Since  the  1970s  conservatives  in  the  United  States  have  been increasingly  successful  at  focusing  policy  debates  on  the  question  of  financ¬ ing.  “Who  pays?”  became  just  as  salient  a  question  as  “Who  benefits?”  In  this context  liberals  grew  concerned  about  the  regressive  nature  of  existing  pay¬ roll  taxes  and  their  impact  on  lower-  and  middle-income  families.  As  a  result, many  Democratic  officials  came  to  view  payroll  taxes  as  unfair.  The  heavy focus  on  taxes  obscured  the  impact  of  benefits,  which  in  social  insurance  pro¬ grams  like  Social  Security  clearly  favor  lower-income  workers.  With  payroll taxes  marginalized,  “the  American  welfare  state  lost  a  major  source  of  financ¬ ing,  stymieing  redistributive  initiatives  for  decades  to  come”  (Campbell  and Morgan,  2005, 180). Instead  Democrats  embraced  policy  tools  whose  costs  were  less  evident. Tax  expenditures  gained  favor  because  they  looked  as  much  like  tax  cuts  as spending.  Democrats  could  (and  did)  say  that  the  EITC  and  Child  Tax  Credit helped  working  families  keep  more  of  their  hard-earned  dollars.  Tax  expen¬ ditures  have  not  figured  prominently  in  official  budget  documents,  a  practice which  obscures  their  cost.  Social  legislation  such  as  the  Americans  with  Dis¬ abilities  Act  and  the  Family  and  Medical  Leave  Act  required  businesses  and individuals  to  change  their  behavior;  their  budgetary  cost  to  the  government was  minimal.  Instead  of  paying  for  parental  leave  the  government  told  many employers  to  give  their  workers  unpaid  leave,  and  effectively  told  parents who  wanted  leave  to  find  a  way  to  live  on  less  income.  Instead  of  enacting Party  Politics  201 national  health  insurance,  the  government  tried  to  make  private  health  in¬ surance  more  widely  available.  As  mentioned  earlier  in  the  chapter,  many  of these  tax  expenditures  and  social  provisions  benefited  the  haves  more  than the  have-nots  (Howard  2007a). Democratic  leaders  also  changed  their  approach  to  poverty.  For  one  thing, their  attention  to  the  problem  has  diminished.  Gerring  (1998)  analyzed  Demo¬ cratic  presidential  candidates’  acceptance  speeches  and  found  that  references to  the  poor  and  underprivileged  peaked  in  the  1960s  and  then  dropped  off. Clinton’s  speech  in  1992  barely  mentioned  poverty  at  all.  In  1968  the  official Democratic  platform  trumpeted  the  party’s  success  in  reducing  poverty.  It argued  that  the  government’s  War  on  Poverty  was  working  and  should  be expanded.  The  view  from  1996  was  far  less  sanguine:  “Today’s  Democratic Party  knows  there  is  no  greater  gap  between  mainstream  American  values and  modern  American  government  than  our  failed  welfare  system. . . .  Thanks to  President  Clinton  and  the  Democrats,  the  new  welfare  bill  imposes  time limits  and  real  work  requirements— so  anyone  who  can  work,  does  work,  and so  that  no  one  who  can  work  can  stay  on  welfare  forever.”19  Tellingly,  the  dis¬ cussion  of  welfare  in  1996  appeared  in  the  section  of  the  platform  titled  “Re¬ sponsibility,”  in  which  the  Democrats  also  discussed  crime  and  illegal  immi¬ gration.  Subsequent  party  platforms  have  reiterated  the  themes  of  work  and individual  responsibility  when  discussing  poverty. More  than  ever,  Democrats  came  to  believe  that  a  strong  economy  was  the best  way  to  fight  poverty.  Democrats  have  wanted  to  keep  unemployment low,  interest  rates  low,  and  wages  growing.  Reducing  the  deficit  was  a  key step  in  accomplishing  these  goals.  Before  President  Clinton  tried  to  reform healthcare  or  welfare,  his  first  budget  relied  on  a  combination  of  tax  increases and  spending  cuts  to  lower  the  deficit. Nevertheless,  Democratic  officials  knew  that  a  rising  economic  tide  would not  lift  all  boats  high  enough  or  fast  enough;  targeted  aid  would  still  be needed.  They  proceeded  to  draw  a  bright  line  between  the  working  poor,  who would  get  additional  money  from  the  government,  and  the  nonworking  poor, who  would  get  a  stronger  push  to  earn  money.  The  Earned  Income  Tax  Credit attracted  considerable  Democratic  support  and  grew  rapidly  during  the  1980s and  1990s.  By  definition  the  EITC  benefits  only  those  who  work  for  wages.  It now  serves  many  more  families  than  TANF  and  costs  a  lot  more.  At  the  same time,  Democrats  helped  Republicans  cut  spending  on  traditional  welfare  pro¬ grams,  notably  in  1981  and  1996.  Democrats  helped  tighten  eligibility  rules and  work  requirements.  They  tried  to  collect  more  child  support  from  absent parents.  They  shifted  more  spending  away  from  income  support  and  toward 202  Howard services  such  as  childcare  and  transportation  that  would  help  welfare  recipi¬ ents  find  employment.  The  new  measure  of  success  was  moving  people  off welfare,  not  out  of  poverty  (Howard  2007a;  Weaver  2000). These  changes  were  connected  to  the  resurgence  of  the  GOP  and  the  emer¬ gence  of  the  New  Democrats  (Baer  2000;  Hale  1995).  Republicans  won  both the  presidency  and  the  Senate  in  1980,  the  first  time  in  a  generation  that Democrats  failed  to  control  both  houses  of  Congress.  President  Reagan  won reelection  in  1984  by  a  huge  margin,  capturing  forty-nine  states.  In  response  a number  of  moderate  and  conservative  Democrats  joined  forces  to  chart  a  new path.  To  become  competitive  again,  these  “New  Democrats”  wanted  their party  to  shed  its  tax-and-spend  image  and  promote  a  leaner,  more  efficient government.  They  wanted  to  shift  responsibility  away  from  Washington  and toward  lower  levels  of  government,  as  well  as  toward  businesses  and  indi¬ viduals.  New  Democrats  wanted  to  spend  less  time  helping  specific  groups  of disadvantaged  citizens  and  more  time  helping  the  middle  class,  broadly  de¬ fined.  They  talked  often  about  the  ability  of  economic  growth  to  promote  the American  dream.  This  new  vision  would  in  theory  appeal  to  a  wider  range  of voters  and  enable  the  Democratic  Party  to  win  national  elections  more  con¬ sistently.  The  creation  of  the  Democratic  Leadership  Council  and  the  Progres¬ sive  Policy  Institute  gave  New  Democrats  formal  mechanisms  for  generating ideas  and  communicating  with  one  another.  Clinton’s  election  and  reelection gave  them  a  president  who  shared  many  of  their  goals  and  managed  to  trans¬ late  their  vision  into  specific  social  programs.  A1  Gore  and  John  Kerry  did not  depart  from  this  vision  when  they  campaigned  for  president  in  2000  and 2004.20 Within  Congress,  however,  were  many  traditional  Democrats  who  still  be¬ lieved  in  the  New  Deal  and  Great  Society.  When  Bill  Clinton  promised  as  a candidate  to  spend  billions  of  additional  dollars  to  improve  the  nation’s  infra¬ structure,  these  Democrats  were  hopeful.  When  Clinton  as  president  failed  to deliver,  they  were  dismayed.  Although  Clinton  felt  that  national  health  in¬ surance  along  Canadian  lines  was  a  political  non-starter,  the  liberal  wing  of his  party  disagreed  and  introduced  single-payer  legislation  (Skocpol  1996). Traditional  Democrats  often  viewed  New  Democrats  with  suspicion,  if  not hostility.  The  New  Democrats,  they  argued,  were  turning  their  party  into  a watered-down  version  of  the  Republican  Party. Over  the  last  few  years  the  friction  between  new  and  old  Democrats  has diminished.  Much  of  the  credit  belongs  to  George  W.  Bush,  whose  presidency helped  Democrats  realize  that  the  differences  among  them  were  not  nearly  as important  as  the  differences  separating  the  two  parties.  To  some  degree,  how¬ ever,  important  elements  of  the  New  Democrats’  creed  have  become  accepted Party  Politics  203 within  the  entire  party.  The  Democrats  now  criticize  the  GOP  for  running deficits  and  expect  new  government  programs  to  be  deficit-neutral  (except  in a  prolonged  recession).  After  Democrats  recaptured  the  House  of  Represen¬ tatives  in  2006,  the  incoming  speaker,  Nancy  Pelosi,  declared  that  ‘“Demo¬ crats  understand  the  importance  of  a  growing  and  vibrant  economy.’ ...  To be  successful,  ‘you  have  to  govern  from  the  middle’”  (Dunham  2006,  37;  see also  Scheiber  2007).  The  leading  Democratic  presidential  candidates  in  2008, Hillary  Clinton  and  Barack  Obama,  proposed  a  number  of  new  programs  for healthcare,  retirement  pensions,  housing,  and  education.  Most  of  them  relied to  some  degree  on  tax  breaks.  None  of  them  qualified  as  social  insurance.21 The  Democrats’  triumph  in  2008  gave  them  united  control  over  govern¬ ment  for  the  first  time  since  1992.  Obama  had  promised  health  reform  on  the campaign  trail,  and  in  his  first  year  in  office  the  new  president  started  to  de¬ liver.  He  quickly  approved  a  children’s  health  insurance  bill  that  President Bush  had  vetoed.  He  also  expanded  government’s  role  in  subsidizing  health insurance  for  workers  who  had  lost  their  jobs  and  their  coverage.  By  far  the biggest  triumph  came  in  2010,  as  President  Obama  and  congressional  Demo¬ crats  pushed  through  the  largest  changes  to  health  policy  since  the  Great  So¬ ciety.  Given  Republicans’  unwillingness  to  cooperate,  serious  disagreements within  the  Democratic  Party,  and  the  loss  of  a  key  Senate  seat  after  the  death of  Ted  Kennedy  (D-Mass.),  failure  was  always  a  strong  possibility.  Neverthe¬ less,  the  Democrats  prevailed. The  health  reform  bill  was  as  notable  for  what  it  did  not  do  as  what  it  did. The  United  States  did  not  adopt  a  single-payer  system  similar  to  Canada’s, and  it  did  not  even  consider  a  national  health  service  comparable  to  Great Britain’s.  It  did  not  create  a  government  insurance  program  to  compete  with private  insurers,  even  though  most  liberal  Democrats  wanted  this  “public option.”  And  it  did  not  rely  on  any  general  increase  in  payroll  taxes  for  fund¬ ing.  Instead  health  reform  relied  on  a  combination  of  regulations,  tax  breaks, and  traditional  spending  to  expand  private  and  public  health  insurance.  For example,  it  mandated  that  most  individuals  must  buy  health  insurance,  a step  that  some  conservative  think  tanks  and  politicians  had  embraced  years earlier.  It  prohibited  insurers  from  denying  coverage  to  people  with  preexist¬ ing  medical  conditions,  or  from  imposing  lifetime  dollar  limits  on  coverage. And  it  extended  Medicaid  to  more  low-income  Americans.  To  pay  for  broader coverage  the  package  relied  on  a  variety  of  administrative  reforms,  limits on  the  growth  of  Medicare,  new  taxes  on  specific  sectors  in  healthcare,  and higher  payroll  taxes  on  the  most  affluent  Americans  (Kaiser  Family  Foun¬ dation  2010).  According  to  the  Congressional  Budget  Office,  health  reform should  actually  reduce  the  national  deficit  over  the  next  decade,  a  feature 204  Howard that  Democrats  worked  hard  to  achieve  (Herszenhorn  2010).  In  all  these  ways the  Democrats’  approach  to  health  reform  in  2010  bore  a  stronger  resem¬ blance  to  President  Clinton’s  plan  than  to  President  Johnson’s. Republicans Hardly  anyone  is  surprised  to  hear  that  President  Reagan  cut  means-tested programs,  or  that  congressional  Republicans  led  by  Newt  Gingrich  worked overtime  to  undermine  Clinton’s  health  plan  and  eliminate  welfare  as  an  en¬ titlement.  Republicans  are  supposed  to  be  the  party  of  limited  government. The  more  interesting  question  is  how  the  American  welfare  state  managed to  grow  during  a  period  when  the  Republican  Party  was  strong  and  gaining power. There  were  times  when  Republicans  were  simply  outnumbered.  For  ex¬ ample,  the  first  President  Bush  vetoed  parental  leave  legislation  twice.  Presi¬ dent  Clinton  made  the  issue  one  of  his  top  priorities  and,  with  the  help  of  a Democratic  Congress,  enacted  the  Family  and  Medical  Leave  Act  early  in  his administration.  At  other  times,  Republicans  accepted  measures  to  achieve modest  expansion  of  the  welfare  state  when  they  were  coupled  with  other legislation  that  they  strongly  preferred;  this  is  how  the  SCHIP  health  insur¬ ance  program  passed  through  a  Republican  Congress. Nevertheless,  as  we  have  seen,  Republican  officials  were  important  advo¬ cates  of  expansion  on  several  occasions.  In  addition  to  the  motives  discussed previously,  Republicans  acted  strategically.  They  expanded  some  parts  of  the American  welfare  state  to  keep  other  parts  in  check.  The  Earned  Income  Tax Credit  was  supposed  to  keep  the  poor  off  welfare  and  reduce  pressure  to  in¬ crease  the  minimum  wage.  One  of  the  primary  motivations  for  the  ADA  was to  make  it  easier  for  the  disabled  to  work.  In  particular,  the  ADA  would  help people  who  could  not  meet  the  strict  eligibility  requirements  of  disability  in¬ surance  yet  clearly  faced  difficulties  in  the  job  market  because  of  some  handi¬ cap.  Without  the  help  of  the  ADA,  many  of  these  people  might  have  had  to rely  on  public  assistance.  Tax  breaks  for  retirement  pensions  would  slow  the growth  of  Social  Security.  Tax  breaks  for  employment-related  health  benefits, and  government  regulation  of  those  benefits,  would  make  national  health  in¬ surance  unnecessary  (Howard  1997;  Howard  2007a). In  short,  many  Republicans  have  been  trying  to  build  a  different  kind  of welfare  state,  one  focused  heavily  on  work  and  benefits  received  through work.  This  goal  has  created  opportunities  for  coalitions  across  party  lines, especially  with  New  Democrats.  Those  two  groups  could  agree  to  block  na¬ tional  health  insurance,  oppose  increases  in  the  minimum  wage,  abolish  wel- Party  Politics  205 fare  “as  we  know  it,”  slow  (but  not  stop)  the  growth  in  entitlement  spending, and  use  the  tax  code  to  make  social  policy.  Nonetheless,  that  kind  of  welfare state  was  less  capable  of  fighting  poverty  and  inequality  than  one  based  more on  social  insurance  and  a  reliable  safety  net. Concluding  Thoughts This  new  bargain  — do  more,  achieve  less— may  not  strike  readers  as  very desirable.  True,  the  American  welfare  state  does  reduce  poverty  and  in¬ equality.  It  just  does  not  do  so  as  well  as  it  did  formerly,  or  as  well  as  most other  wealthy  democracies  do  now.  For  policymakers  here  and  abroad,  the lesson  may  be  to  focus  less  on  the  level  of  social  spending  and  more  on  the distribution  of  benefits.  What  this  new  bargain  lacks  in  performance,  how¬ ever,  it  makes  up  for  in  political  viability.  Directing  government  aid  to  the middle  and  upper  middle  classes  means  helping  the  most  active  members  of the  polity.  That  is  a  smart  strategy  for  practically  any  Democratic  or  Republi¬ can  official. Compared  to  other  chapters  in  this  book,  my  account  emphasizes  domes¬ tic  influences  on  center-left  parties.  In  the  latter  decades  of  the  twentieth century  Democratic  officials  changed  their  approach  to  social  policy  in  re¬ sponse  to  election  outcomes  and  public  opinion.  They  largely  abandoned social  insurance,  which  has  been  the  foundation  of  modern  welfare  states. Instead  they  embraced  more  indirect  forms  of  assistance,  especially  tax  ex¬ penditures  and  regulation,  which  required  less  obvious  forms  of  government involvement  than  the  old  New  Deal  and  Great  Society  model.  They  were  more likely  to  declare  war  on  welfare  than  war  on  poverty.  This  was  neoliberalism American-style,  and  it  often  attracted  support  from  Republicans.22 If  history  is  any  guide,  the  elections  of  2008  mean  that  we  should  expect less  poverty  and  inequality  because  Democrats  are  now  in  charge.  The  first two  years  of  Obama’s  administration  pointed  in  that  direction.  The  Ameri¬ can  Recovery  and  Reinvestment  Act  of  2009  included  a  number  of  provisions aimed  at  lower-  and  middle-class  citizens.  This  act  expanded  the  scope  of  the Earned  Income  Tax  Credit  and  increased  its  value;  made  the  refundable  part of  the  Child  Tax  Credit  more  widely  available  to  poor  families;  exempted some  unemployment  benefits  from  income  taxation;  and  created  a  Making Work  Pay  Tax  Credit,  designed  to  offset  regressive  payroll  taxes.  All  these moves  ran  counter  to  the  dominant  trend  in  tax  policy.  They  used  the  tax  code to  make  social  policy  without  directing  most  of  the  benefits  to  upper-income taxpayers.  This  same  American  Recovery  and  Reinvestment  Act  boosted  tra¬ ditional  social  spending  as  well,  providing  more  money  for  unemployment 20  6  Howard benefits  and  Food  Stamps.  To  a  significant  degree  health  reforms  enacted  in 2010  will  use  money  from  the  rich  to  pay  for  health  insurance  for  those  with below-average  incomes  (Leonhardt  2010). That  said,  we  should  not  expect  reductions  in  poverty  and  inequality  to be  immediate  or  large.  Unemployment  and  poverty  are  again  on  the  rise  as the  economy  suffers  its  worst  slump  since  the  Great  Depression.  Income  in¬ equality  remains  high  (DeNavas-Walt,  Proctor,  and  Smith  2009).  Much  of what  the  Obama  administration  has  accomplished  will  keep  these  problems from  getting  worse,  but  it  is  hard  to  expect  more  than  a  standoff  in  the  near future.  The  president,  for  obvious  reasons,  is  worried  more  about  economic growth  and  unemployment,  and  so  are  ordinary  Americans  (Frank  2008, BU5).23  Compounding  these  difficulties  is  a  foreign  policy  agenda  that  is much  more  complicated— Afghanistan,  Iraq,  Libya,  Iran,  terrorism,  interna¬ tional  environmental  agreements  — than  what  President  Clinton  faced  in  the 1990s.  Moreover,  the  electorate  has  not  changed.  Voters  with  above-average incomes  divided  their  votes  evenly  between  Obama  and  the  Republican  can¬ didate,  John  McCain,  in  2008;  those  with  above-average  incomes  still  made up  the  majority  of  voters  in  2008.  Those  with  below-average  incomes  voted Democratic  by  a  3:2  margin.  The  same  basic  patterns  held  for  elections  to  the House  of  Representatives.24 The  midterm  elections  of  2010  will  make  poverty  and  inequality  even  more difficult  to  address.  Republicans  took  control  of  the  House  of  Representatives and  gained  additional  seats  in  the  Senate.  Their  top  priorities  include  pre¬ serving  tax  cuts  for  the  rich,  repealing  parts  or  all  of  the  2008  health  reform, and  cutting  social  spending.  As  I  write  (December  2010),  these  Republicans seem  less  willing  than  their  predecessors  to  compromise  and  less  interested  in creating  alternative  types  of  social  programs.  The  differences  between  Demo¬ crats  and  Republicans,  at  least  in  Congress,  will  be  stark.  There  have  been periods  of  divided  government  in  the  United  States  when  officials  managed to  make  progress  in  fighting  poverty  and  inequality;  this  does  not  appear  to be  one  of  them. Notes This  is  a  revised  version  of  a  paper  that  I  presented  at  the  conference  “What’s  Left  of the  Left?  Liberalism  and  Social  Democracy  in  a  Globalized  World”  at  the  Center  for European  Studies,  Harvard  University,  in  May  2008.  Many  thanks  to  Andrea  Camp¬ bell,  Jim  Cronin,  Jane  Jenson,  Jonas  Pontusson,  and  Jim  Shoch  for  their  helpful  sug¬ gestions  and  comments. 1.  The  postwar  low  was  11.1%,  in  1973. Party  Politics  207 2.  Considering  that  scholars  differ  about  what  happened  in  recent  decades,  it  is  not too  surprising  that  they  disagree  about  why  as  well.  While  some  believe  that  political parties  are  still  central  to  the  development  of  welfare  states  (Allan  and  Scruggs  2004; Korpi  and  Palme  2003),  others  argue  that  interest  groups  (Pierson  1996),  changes  in the  global  economy  (Mishra  1999),  demographic  pressures  (Kotlikoff  and  Burns  2004), or  public  opinion  (Brooks  and  Manza  2007)  have  become  equally  if  not  more  signifi¬ cant. 3.  This  was  not  the  first  time  that  social  programs  had  been  terminated.  A  number of  public  jobs  programs  created  during  the  New  Deal,  whose  collective  impact  was  far greater  than  PSE,  were  phased  out  in  the  1940s  (Amenta  1998). 4.  The  creation  and  expansion  of  the  EITC  might  be  considered  evidence  of  the  im¬ pact  of  globalization  on  United  States  social  policy.  Greater  competition  from  firms overseas  may  have  depressed  wages  and  created  more  members  of  the  working  poor. Nevertheless,  a  large  number  of  EITC  recipients  work  in  service  industries  (e.g.,  fast- food  restaurants,  hotels),  which  do  not  have  much  foreign  competition.  Moreover, policymakers  linked  the  EITC  to  domestic  issues  such  as  escalating  welfare  rolls,  in¬ creasing  payroll  taxes,  and  the  minimum  wage  (Howard  1997;  Howard  2007a). 5.  Following  Jenson  (this  volume),  one  might  say  that  the  addition  of  the  Medicare drug  benefit  also  qualifies  as  a  “new  social  need,”  considering  that  prescription  drugs were  a  growing  expense  for  the  elderly,  driven  by  changes  in  medical  treatment  and longer  life  expectancies. 6.  Although  the  OECD  tracks  social  spending  back  to  at  least  i960,  the  categories used  before  1980  are  not  entirely  comparable  with  those  after  1980  (OECD  1985). 7.  Unless  otherwise  noted,  all  references  to  income  inequality  in  this  chapter  are based  on  disposable  income,  after  taxes  and  transfers. 8.  While  most  of  the  debate  over  inequality  has  focused  on  income,  differences  in wealth  have  been  much  larger.  The  richest  one-fifth  of  United  States  households  con¬ trolled  almost  85%  of  the  nation’s  wealth  in  2004,  while  the  richest  1%  controlled  over one-third  of  all  wealth.  Like  income,  wealth  has  become  more  concentrated.  The  Gini coefficient  for  net  worth  was  already  an  astonishing  0.799  in  1983,  and  it  rose  to  0.829 by  2004  (Wolff  2007). 9.  The  EITC  is  unusual  among  tax  provisions  in  that  eligibility  is  limited  to  low- income  families  and  the  benefits  are  refundable,  meaning  that  taxpayers  with  zero  tax liability  can  still  benefit.  It  proves  that  tax  expenditures  do  not  have  to  benefit  the  more affluent. 10.  Single-parent  families  are  often  considered  a  “new  social  need”  in  Europe.  Such families  have  long  been  helped  in  the  United  States,  dating  back  at  least  as  far  as  Aid to  Dependent  Children  (1935).  Public  policies  helping  two-parent  families,  such  as  the Earned  Income  Tax  Credit  and  Child  Tax  Credit,  are  more  recent. 11.  Education  is  sometimes  considered  part  of  the  welfare  state  and  sometimes  not. It  is  worth  noting  that  President  George  W.  Bush  pushed  for  the  No  Child  Left  Behind Act  partly  because  he  felt  that  reducing  educational  inequalities  would  later  reduce poverty  and  income  inequality. 208  Howard 12.  Reagan’s  comments  can  be  viewed  online  at  www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/ index.php?pid=36629&st=&sti=. 13.  These  figures  are  based  on  responses  to  the  General  Social  Survey,  which  can  be accessed  at  http://sda.berkeley.edu/archive.htm. 14.  For  more  evidence  of  the  growing  importance  of  professionals  to  the  Democratic Party  see  the  chapter  by  Teixeira  in  this  volume. 15.  See  table  6A.2  (“Voter  Turnout”)  at  www.electionstudies.org/nesguide/nesguide .htm. 16.  I  am  assuming  that  such  concerns  would  be  highly  salient  to  voters,  which  would prompt  the  two  parties,  even  if  ideologically  polarized,  to  work  toward  some  compro¬ mise  (see,  e.g.,  Binder  2003). 17.  While  this  chapter  features  general  trends  more  than  single  events,  it  is  worth noting  that  both  Pierson  (1998)  and  Shoch  (2008)  point  to  Ross  Perot’s  impressive showing  as  an  independent  candidate  in  1992  as  a  main  reason  why  President  Clinton and  other  Democrats  became  much  more  concerned  about  the  deficit. 18.  The  act  created  Head  Start  and  the  Job  Corps,  designed  to  improve  human  capi¬ tal  and  ultimately  the  performance  of  American  workers. 19.  Democratic  Party  platforms  can  be  accessed  at  www.presidency.ucsb.edu/plat forms.php. 20.  Bertram  (2007)  shows  that  the  conservative  wing  of  the  Democratic  Party started  to  reshape  antipoverty  policies  away  from  welfare  and  toward  work  starting  in the  early  1970s. 21.  For  a  useful  summary  of  the  candidates’  tax  policies  go  to  http://www.tax policycenter.org/tpccontent/tax_plan_matrix15a.pdf. 22.  I  agree  with  Huber  and  Stephens  that  globalization  does  not  seem  to  have  exerted a  major  influence  on  the  American  welfare  state.  As  a  general  rule,  countries  that  are more  closely  integrated  into  the  world  economy  find  themselves  more  vulnerable  to unemployment  (e.g.,  when  demand  for  their  exports  drops).  During  the  last  decades of  the  twentieth  century  the  authors  “found  that  the  immediate  cause  of  welfare  state retrenchment  was  a  large  and  apparently  permanent  increase  in  unemployment.  With more  people  dependent  on  welfare  state  transfers  and  fewer  people  paying  taxes  to support  the  welfare  state,  budget  deficits  ballooned  and  governments  moved  to  control and  then  reduce  deficits  by  cutting  entitlements”  (Huber  and  Stephens  2001,  2).  The pattern  in  the  United  States  has  been  the  opposite:  although  unemployment  declined during  Reagan’s  and  Clinton’s  administrations,  so  too  did  welfare  state  effort;  as  un¬ employment  increased  during  the  first  Bush  administration,  so  did  welfare  state  effort. Moreover,  spending  cuts  in  the  United  States  have  been  targeted  at  means-tested  pro¬ grams  while  the  major  entitlements  have  largely  been  spared.  I  am  not  saying  that  the impact  of  globalization  should  always  be  downplayed.  There  may  well  be  policy  do¬ mains  in  the  United  States  (Shoch,  this  volume)  or  overseas  (Ross,  this  volume)  where changes  in  the  global  economy  matter  a  great  deal.  But  changes  in  major  United  States social  programs  do  appear  to  have  been  driven  more  by  domestic  influences  such  as political  parties  and  public  opinion. Party  Politics  209 There  is  a  long  and  large  debate  over  the  relationship  between  globalization  and  the welfare  state.  To  learn  more  one  might  start  with  Brady,  Beckfield,  and  Zhao  (2007), Hays,  Ehrlich,  and  Peinhardt  (2005),  and  Iversen  and  Cusack  (2000). 23.  See,  e.g.,  survey  questions  about  the  nation’s  most  important  problems  at  www .pollingreport.com/prioriti.htm. 24.  For  exit  poll  data  from  2008  see  www.cnn.com/ELECTlON/2008/results/polls .main/. Grappling  with  Globalization The  Democratic  Party’s  Struggles over  International  Market  Integration James  Shoch Europe  versus  America In  recent  decades  the  American  Democratic  Party,  like  center-left  parties everywhere,  has  confronted  the  challenge  posed  by  economic  globalization. But  the  Democrats’  response  to  growing  international  market  integration  has differed  from  that  of  most  European  social  democratic  parties. European  parties  — especially  in  the  Nordic  countries,  characterized  by small,  open  economies  — have  long  recognized  that  trade  liberalization  raises aggregate  national  welfare  by  fostering  exports,  lower  prices,  and  increased productivity  and  growth.1  But  these  parties  have  also  recognized  that  moves toward  greater  economic  openness  could  be  blocked  by  those  suffering  job and  income  losses  related  to  globalization  — especially  less  skilled  workers in  manufacturing  industries  that  compete  with  imports,  and  more  recently blue-  and  white-collar  workers  of  all  skill  levels  in  industries  engaged  in  off¬ shore  outsourcing,  as  well  as  other  workers  partly  competing  in  the  same labor  markets.2  Thus  since  the  1930s  and  1940s  social  democratic  parties, again  particularly  in  the  Nordic  countries,  have  built  successful  coalitions  in support  of  open  markets  by  arranging  deals  whereby  globalization’s  “win¬ ners”— firms  and  more  skilled  workers  in  export-oriented  and  multinational sectors  — agree  to  compensate  the  “losers”  with  extensive  unemployment benefits,  retraining,  healthcare,  pensions,  and  other  welfare  policies  (Hays, Ehrlich,  and  Peinhardt  2005;  Cameron  and  Kim  2006). Moreover,  since  the  early  1990s  many  of  these  same  parties,  grappling  with the  economic  supply-side  problems  of  the  previous  two  decades,  especially productivity  shortfalls,  have  also  backed  greatly  increased  public  investment in  education,  training,  and  technological  research.  These  policies  have  in¬ creased  overall  economic  productivity,  thereby  improving  competitiveness, Grappling  with  Globalization  211 preserving  jobs,  and  raising  wages,  while  also  creating  well-paying  new  jobs in  government  and  dynamic  new  industries.  At  the  same  time  improved  pro¬ ductivity  has  boosted  tax  revenues,  helping  to  pay  for  public  programs  whose rising  costs  have  at  times  eroded  their  popular  support  (Boix  1998;  Benner 2003;  Bernard  and  Boucher  2007;  Becker  2007;  Aiginger  2008).3  All  of  this has  again  aided  these  parties  in  maintaining  support  for  economic  openness and  broadening  their  coalitions  among  different  sectors  of  the  workforce. Consequently,  despite  recent  challenges  from  the  nationalist  and  protec¬ tionist  far  right  (Swank  and  Betz  2003;  Burgoon  2009),  by  simultaneously pursuing  open  markets  and  compensatory  social  spending  and  public  in¬ vestment  strategies,  European  social  democratic  parties  — albeit  more  in  the Nordic  countries  than  on  the  continent  (Einhorn  and  Logue  2010)  — have  suc¬ cessfully  fostered  growth,  employment,  social  equality,  and  inclusion.4 The  American  Democratic  Party  has  taken  a  different  path.  Historically the  party  of  free  trade,  in  the  1960s  the  party  became  much  more  equivocal in  its  support  for  that  doctrine.  Pressured  by  labor  constituents  battered  by imports,  many  Democrats  embraced  protectionism  and  opposed  further  trade liberalization  efforts.  With  a  leap  in  the  trade  deficit,  especially  with  Japan, and  the  political  salience  of  trade  during  the  presidencies  of  Ronald  Reagan and  his  successor,  George  H.  W.  Bush,  Democratic  members  of  Congress  and presidential  candidates  pushed  bills  first  to  curb  imports  and  then  to  pry  open closed  markets,  particularly  Japan’s.  During  his  first  term  in  office  Bill  Clinton also  pressed  Japan  to  open  its  markets. Since  the  early  1990s,  however,  the  United  States  has  renewed  its  drive  for further  trade— and  investment  — liberalization.5  Recent  years  have  seen  the approval  of  the  North  American  Free  Trade  Agreement,  a  new  General  Agree¬ ment  on  Tariffs  and  Trade  (GATT)  treaty,  permanent  normal  trade  relations with  China,  and  the  Central  American  Free  Trade  Agreement,  along  with other  bilateral  deals.  But  whereas  in  Europe,  as  noted  above,  social  demo¬ cratic  parties  have  been  key  supporters  of  trade  liberalization,  in  the  United States  Democratic  backing  for  liberalization  has  been  much  less  reliable.  In the  American  system  of  separated  powers,  movement  toward  freer  trade  has been  due  to  the  efforts  of  pro-trade  presidents  of  both  parties,  allied  with congressional  Republicans  and  a  substantial  number  of  Senate  Democrats, but  only  a  minority,  sometimes  a  small  one,  of  House  Democrats.  For  various reasons,  above  all  pressure  from  the  still  powerful  labor  movement  and  wide public  anxiety  about  globalization,  the  majority  of  House  Democrats  have opposed,  sometimes  overwhelmingly,  almost  all  of  these  trade  liberalization initiatives.  During  the  1990s  their  opposition  led  to  the  defeat  of  two  impor¬ tant  procedural  measures,  if  not  actual  agreements. 212  Shoch More  recently  the  entrance  of  the  “BRIC”  nations  — Brazil,  Russia,  India, and  China  — onto  the  world  economic  stage  has  further  heightened  labor  and public  concern  over  globalization  and  trade.  At  the  same  time  the  ranks  of congressional  Democratic  critics  of  free  trade  were  expanded  when  the  party regained  control  of  the  House  and  Senate  in  the  midterm  elections  of  2006. The  result  was  the  blocking  and  delaying  of  new  trade  liberalization  pro¬ posals  in  Congress,  while  the  Democrats’  presidential  nominee  and  eventual victor  in  2008,  Barack  Obama,  also  tilted,  at  least  temporarily,  against  new free  trade  agreements  and  called  for  a  more  aggressive  approach  to  China. One  reason  for  the  Democrats’  push  for  tougher  trade  policy  and  opposi¬ tion  to  trade  liberalization  in  recent  decades  has  been  their  inability  to  win, or  credibly  promise,  a  substantial  increase  in  compensatory  social  spending and  public  investment.  That  sort  of  increased  spending  might  have  reduced labor  and  popular  objections  to  expanded  trade  as  it  has  in  much  of  Europe. Until  recently,  spending  on  the  Trade  Adjustment  Assistance  (TAA)  program, intended  to  help  workers  dislocated  by  trade,  had  actually  declined  since 1980.  Once  a  leader  in  publicly  funded  education,  infrastructure,  and  techno¬ logical  research,  after  the  1960s  the  United  States  slipped  in  all  three  areas. With  American  industrial  competitiveness  eroding,  in  the  early  1980s  and again  in  the  early  1990s  the  Democrats  embraced  first  industrial  policy  and then  increased  public  investment,  along  with  certain  compensatory  social policies.  But  Democratic  leaders  soon  backed  off  from  these  ideas,  partly  be¬ cause  of  concerns  fueled  by  the  news  media  about  budget  deficits,  and  with¬ ering  Republican  and  business  criticism  that  the  Democrats  were  advocating more  “big  government”  and  “tax-and-spend  liberalism.” Again  in  the  wake  of  the  emergence  of  the  BRlCs  and  the  Democrats’  elec¬ tion  victories  in  2006,  congressional  Democrats  renewed  their  efforts  to  in¬ crease  TAA  and  public  investment,  while  Obama  backed  similar  policies  dur¬ ing  his  campaign.  But  the  scale  of  these  proposals  was  again  limited  by  deficit worries  and  Democratic  fears  of  being  politically  tarred  with  the  brush  of  fis¬ cal  irresponsibility.  That  is,  until  the  global  economic  crisis  struck  in  the  fall of  2008. That  crisis  for  a  time  loosened  constraints  on  government  economic  inter¬ vention.  With  Obama’s  victory  and  the  expansion  of  the  Democrats’  congres¬ sional  majorities  in  2008,  Obama  and  his  congressional  allies  enacted  a  major economic  stimulus  package  and  a  year  later  a  historic  healthcare  reform  bill that  should  eventually  ease  the  dislocations  caused  by  globalization  and  help build  a  more  productive,  competitive  economy.  In  the  short  term,  however,  the economy  remained  weak  while  public  skepticism  toward  the  growth  of  gov¬ ernment  increased,  leading  to  big  Republican  gains  in  the  congressional  elec- Grappling  with  Globalization  213 tions  of  2010.  Had  Obama  and  his  party  been  able  to  produce  policies  that  over time  proved  successful  and  thus  popular,  it  is  possible  that  opposition  to  trade liberalization  from  labor  and  the  public  at  large  might  at  some  point  have  de¬ clined,  allowing  the  Democrats’  approach  to  globalization  to  draw  closer  to that  of  their  European  colleagues.  But  these  prospects  have  now  dimmed. In  this  chapter,  after  presenting  a  very  brief  framework  for  understanding the  determinants  of  party  economic  policy  stances,  I  will  explain  the  evolu¬ tion  of  Democratic  positions  on  trade,  compensatory  spending,  and  competi¬ tiveness  policy,  with  a  focus  on  the  years  since  1980.6 Parties  and  Economic  Policymaking  in  the  White  House  and  Congress As  both  the  nation  and  his  party’s  main  economic  policy  actor,  a  newly  elected president,  assisted  by  his  advisers,  often  tries  to  develop  a  new  political- economic  strategy  and  a  corresponding  policy  program.  Both  strategy  and program  will  be  influenced  by  (1)  the  president’s  personal  beliefs,  including his  normative  values  and  his  cognitive  understanding  of  the  causal  dynamics of  the  economy;  (2)  the  preferences  of  core  party  constituents,  activists,  and donors;  swing  voters;  and  powerful  economic  interests,  especially  business and  labor;  and  (3)  the  anticipation  of  what  Congress  will  accept  (Spiliotes 2002;  Dolan,  Frendreis,  and  Tatalovich  2008).  The  president’s  program  is  al¬ most  never  enacted  without  controversy  and  conflict.  Members  of  the  presi¬ dent’s  party  in  Congress  usually  benefit  politically  from  his  achievements and  thus  will  be  generally  predisposed  to  back  his  proposals.  But  opposition party  members  have  little  interest  in  the  president’s  success  and  will  usually fight  to  change  or  replace  them.  Beyond  this,  congressional  party  members’ positions  on  floor  votes  will  also  be  determined  by  their  own  normative  and cognitive  beliefs,  the  preferences  of  their  own  core  partisan  and  swing  con¬ stituents,  majority  party  members’  desire  to  fashion  an  electorally  valuable collective  party  record  and  minority  party  members’  concern  to  prevent  them from  doing  so,  congressional  party  leaders’  strategies  and  pressure,  interest group  lobbying  and  campaign  contributions,  presidential  bargaining  and  per¬ suasion,  and  the  overall  climate  of  interparty  relations  (Bond  and  Fleisher eds.  2000;  Smith  2007;  Lee  2009;  Thurbered.  2009). Various  cultural,  political,  and  economic  structures  also  influence  the interests  and  preferences  of  contending  political  actors,  constrain  and  enable their  behavior,  and  condition  the  outcomes  of  their  policy  battles.  Among these  factors  are  (1)  the  nation’s  anti-statist  political  culture;  (2)  our  distinc¬ tive  electoral  system  and  fragmented  state  institutions;7  (3)  configurations of  institutional  authority,  including  partisan  control  of  the  presidency  and 214  Shoch the  partisan  and  ideological  balance  within  both  houses  of  Congress;  (4)  do¬ mestic  and  international  socioeconomic  structures;8  and  (5)  international “regimes”  and  geopolitical  relations. Parties  and  Trade  Policy  from  Roosevelt  to  Reagan The  Great  Depression  of  the  1930s  destroyed  the  old  Republican  political order  and  its  dominant  coalition  of  northern  industry  and  labor.  The  succes¬ sor  Democratic  or  New  Deal  order  and  its  underlying  coalition— including unionized  labor,  urban  ethnics,  southerners,  African  Americans,  middle-class liberals,  and  liberal  business  interests— emerged  from  the  turmoil  of  the  De¬ pression  and  the  Second  World  War.  The  new  order  rested  on  an  economic base  of  “Fordist”  mass  production  and  consumption.  It  was  institutionally stabilized  by  a  new  system  of  collective  bargaining,  new  financial  market regulations,  a  large  military  establishment,  and  a  limited  welfare  state,9  con¬ strained  in  part  by  America’s  individualist  and  anti-statist  political  culture.10 Democratic  presidents  employed  a  “Keynesian”  political-economic  strategy that  relied  on  countercyclical  fiscal  and  monetary  policy  to  prevent  another collapse  of  effective  demand. The  New  Deal  era  also  saw  the  beginning  of  the  dismantling  of  the  prevail¬ ing  system  of  tariff  protection,  which  had  sharply  divided  Republicans  and Democrats  since  the  mid-nineteenth  century.11  This  system  was  erected  and maintained  mainly  by  the  GOP,  with  the  support  of  northern  industries  that competed  with  imports.  It  was  mostly  opposed  by  the  low-tariff  Democrats and  their  backers  among  southern  agricultural  export  interests.  In  1930  the Republicans,  still  dominant,  responded  to  the  onset  of  the  Depression  by  en¬ acting,  in  the  face  of  united  Democratic  opposition,  the  Smoot-Hawley  Tariff Act,  which  dramatically  raised  tariffs  and  may  well  have  deepened  the  crisis. In  1932  Franklin  Roosevelt  and  the  Democrats  took  unified  control  of  gov¬ ernment.  Two  years  later,  this  time  in  the  face  of  strong  Republican  oppo¬ sition,  they  passed  the  Reciprocal  Trade  Agreements  Act,  which  delegated to  the  president  the  authority  to  negotiate  reciprocal,  bilateral  tariff  reduc¬ tions.  After  the  Second  World  War,  spurred  in  part  by  the  beginning  of  the cold  war,  the  Democratic  administration  of  President  Harry  Truman  took  the lead  in  founding  the  GATT,  under  whose  auspices  tariffs  were  further  reduced through  several  rounds  of  international  negotiations. The  Democrats  recognized  that  maintaining  both  economic  openness and  their  own  political  support  would  require  the  protection  of  vulnerable domestic  interests  from  trade-related  economic  distress.  Thus  was  born  the American  version  of  the  “compromise  of  embedded  liberalism”  (Ruggie  1982; Grappling  with  Globalization  215 Ruggie  ed.  2008;  Hays  2009).  In  exchange  for  their  support  for  openness, American  companies  and  workers  were  cushioned  against,  or  compensated for,  exposure  to  foreign  competition.  Various  devices  were  used  to  curb  im¬ ports;  hence  trade  would  be  “liberal”  or  “freer,”  rather  than  unqualifiedly “free.”  Certain  limited  social  welfare  and  other  spending  policies  were  also employed,  including  TAA,  passed  in  1962,  which  provided  unemployment benefits,  relocation,  retraining,  and  other  assistance  to  help  workers  move into  new  jobs  (Kapstein  1998). Also  important  to  the  maintenance  of  the  liberal  postwar  trading  order was  the  eventual  decline  of  partisanship  surrounding  the  making  of  trade policy.  This  decline  was  due  in  part  to  the  imperatives  of  the  cold  war,  the  in¬ fluence  of  the  GATT  regime,  and  the  operation  of  the  embedded  liberal  com¬ promise.  But  also  important  were  the  frequently  cited  “lessons”  of  Smoot- Hawley,  sustained  postwar  prosperity,  the  still  relatively  closed  nature  of  the United  States  economy,  and  the  expansion  of  pro-trade  export  and  multi¬ national  business  interests.  Thanks  to  all  these  factors,  the  political  salience and  divisiveness  of  trade  issues  gradually  faded,  and  a  bipartisan  consensus in  favor  of  liberal  trade  emerged  by  about  i960. In  the  early  1960s,  however,  America’s  Fordist  mass-production  industries came  under  pressure  from  firms  in  Western  Europe  and  Japan,  whose  econo¬ mies  had  recovered  from  the  devastation  of  the  Second  World  War.  These problems  were  soon  compounded  by  a  “crisis  of  Keynesianism,”  as  the  Demo¬ crats’  postwar  political-economic  strategy  of  demand  management  now  con¬ tributed  to  new  supply-side  cost  and  productivity  problems  that  fueled  infla¬ tion  and  cut  into  corporate  profits  and  competitiveness.  By  1971  the  United States  was  running  a  trade  deficit  in  manufactured  goods  for  the  first  time since  1888. Protectionist  pressures,  which  had  begun  to  gather  in  the  1950s,  now  in¬ tensified,  while  the  organized  labor  movement,  having  obtained  almost  no aid  through  the  TAA  program,  added  its  own  demands  for  relief  from  imports. Partisan  divisions  over  new  trade  liberalization  measures  also  reemerged,  at least  in  Congress,  in  the  early  1970s,  although  the  parties’  historic  positions were  now  reversed. As  noted  above,  before  the  1930s  the  Democratic  Party  had  been  rooted mainly  in  the  South,  dependent  on  exports  and  hence  pro-trade.  But  after  the New  Deal  realignment  of  the  1930s  the  Democrats  became  more  dependent on  the  votes,  volunteers,  and  money  of  the  increasingly  protectionist  labor movement  in  the  Northeast  and  Midwest.  Meanwhile  the  Republicans  be¬ came  more  closely  allied  with  exported-oriented  and  multinational  business interests  that  backed  liberal  trade. 216  Shoch Throughout  the  1970s  the  dual  crisis  of  Fordism  and  Keynesianism  deep¬ ened,  manifesting  itself  as  “stagflation,”  a  painful  combination  of  high  un¬ employment  and  high  inflation  that  hastened  a  long,  disruptive  transition  to “post-Fordism”  involving  several  shifts:  from  mass  production  for  mass  mar¬ kets  to  flexibly  specialized  production  for  niche  markets;  from  basic  manufac¬ turing  industries  to  new  high-technology  sectors;  from  a  manufacturing-based industrial  society  to  a  service-oriented,  postindustrial,  or  knowledge-based society;  from  a  production-dominated  international  economy  to  a  “financial- ized”  global  economy;  and  from  a  “Keynesian  welfare  state”  focused  on  de¬ mand  to  a  more  supply-oriented  “competition  state”  emphasizing  cost  cut¬ ting  and  productivity  growth  (Amin  1995;  Castells  2000;  Jessop  2002;  Cerny 2000;  Coriat,  Petit,  and  Schmeder  eds.  2006;  Zysman  and  Newman  eds. 2006). Politically  the  crisis  disrupted  the  New  Deal  coalition.  Many  white working-class  voters,  already  alienated  by  the  Democrats’  identification  with the  social  movements  of  the  1960s,  now  also  turned  away  from  the  party for  its  failure  to  deliver  continued  prosperity.  The  transition  to  post-Fordism and  post-industrialism  simultaneously  shrank  this  same  blue-collar  indus¬ trial  working  class  while  expanding  the  ranks  of  professionals,  managers,  and routine  white-collar  workers  (Teixeira,  this  volume).  Accordingly,  leaders  of both  parties  sought  new  political-economic  strategies  intended  to  facilitate, cushion,  or  in  some  cases  slow  the  transition  to  post-Fordism,  revive  the  econ¬ omy,  defend  their  core  constituencies,  and  attract  new  constituencies  (Blyth 2002;  Collins  2000). In  1980  Ronald  Reagan,  a  staunch  Republican  proponent  of  “neoliberal¬ ism”  or  “market  fundamentalism”  and  limited  government,  was  elected  presi¬ dent,  inaugurating  a  new  conservative  political  order.  Reagan’s  victory  was due  mainly  to  voters’  anger  at  Jimmy  Carter’s  apparent  mismanagement  of the  economy  but  also  to  a  rightward  shift  in  the  public  mood  toward  gov¬ ernment  (Stimson  2004).  Reagan’s  conservative  “supply-side”  political- economic  strategy  included  big  corporate  and  personal  tax  cuts,  reduced  so¬ cial  spending,  deregulation,  restrictive  monetary  policy,  and  a  commitment to  liberal  trade.  Politically  the  strategy  was  intended  to  win  the  support  of core  middle-class  Republicans;  new  middle-  and  working-class  swing  voters, including  blue-collar  “Reagan  Democrats”;  and  big  and  small  business  inter¬ ests,  all  of  whom  were  weary  of  inflation  and  taxes  (Blumenthal  1986,  55-86, 197-203).  Soon  after  Reagan  took  office,  though,  the  Federal  Reserve’s  tight money  policy  drove  interest  rates  and  the  value  of  the  dollar  up  and  the  econ¬ omy  into  what  became  the  worst  downturn  since  the  Great  Depression,  while the  United  States  budget  and  trade  deficits  ballooned. Grappling  with  Globalization  217 Democrats  Turn  to  TougherTrade  Policy  and  Competitiveness  Initiatives In  response  the  Democrats  intensified  their  search  for  a  new  political- economic  strategy  of  their  own.  Their  advocacy  of  demand  stimulus  policies was  largely  ruled  out  by  the  intellectual  discrediting  of  Keynesianism,  the more  conservative  public  view  of  government,  and  the  Democrats’  embrace of  fiscal  discipline  to  score  political  points  against  “Reaganomics.”  Thus  the Democrats  instead  launched  what  would  become  a  decade-long  attempt  to make  tougher  trade  policy  a  winning  electoral  issue  for  their  party.  The  trade deficit  with  Japan  was  rising  explosively,  so  the  Democrats  focused  on  curb¬ ing  Japanese  imports  and  then  opening  Japanese  markets. With  imports  battering  the  country’s  Fordist  mass-production  industries during  his  first  term,  Reagan,  rather  than  strengthening  the  embedded  liberal compromise,  instead  abandoned  it.  He  only  sparingly  used  the  nation’s  trade remedy  laws  to  stem  the  import  tide.  And  along  with  cutting  other  welfare spending,  he  actually  slashed  TAA  funding  despite  Democratic  opposition. As  a  consequence  many  Democratic  legislators  from  industrial  states  backed legislation  and  administrative  action  to  curb  imports— of  cars,  steel,  and  tex¬ tiles— in  the  hopes  of  defending  their  embattled  labor  supporters,  regaining lost  working-class  support,  and  perhaps  even  winning  some  support  from business  interests  concerned  about  imports. In  the  end,  trade  played  little  role  in  the  presidential  election  of  1984. Nevertheless,  at  the  beginning  of  Reagan’s  second  term  the  Democrats  sensed continued  Republican  vulnerability  on  the  issue,  now  even  among  export interests.  They  thereupon  turned  toward  efforts  to  break  into  closed  foreign markets,  again  especially  Japanese  markets,  through  the  tactic  of  “aggres¬ sive  reciprocity.”  A  long  legislative  process  driven  by  Democrats  culminated in  the  enactment  of  the  Omnibus  Trade  and  Competitiveness  Act  of  1988.  The heart  of  the  bill  was  the  “Super  301”  provision  that  threatened  retaliation against  unfair  foreign  traders  who  refused  to  open  their  markets  to  United States  goods  (Schwab  1994).  The  trade  issue  was  again  of  little  importance in  the  presidential  race  in  1988,  but  the  Democrats  kept  the  pressure  on  any¬ way.  Four  years  later,  in  the  middle  of  the  next  presidential  contest,  the  House of  Representatives,  controlled  by  Democrats,  passed  another  bill  that  would have  reauthorized  the  expiring  Super  301  law  and  imposed  a  cap  on  sales  in the  United  States  of  Japanese  cars,  but  the  Senate  failed  to  produce  its  own version  of  the  bill. Trade  policy  was  not  the  Democrats’  only  foreign  economic  policy  focus during  the  1980s.  Throughout  the  decade  many  Democrats,  looking  for  an alternative  to  protectionism,  supported  different  versions  of  a  relatively  low- 218  Shoch cost  supply-side  or  “competitiveness”  strategy  of  their  own,  intended  to  both reverse  the  nation’s  apparent  economic  decline  and  revive  Democratic  politi¬ cal  prospects  (Hughes  2007).  In  the  early  1980s,  recalling  both  the  short¬ lived  planning  experiments  of  the  Depression  and  the  Second  World  War  and the  apparent  successes  of  the  Japanese  “statist”  model  of  development,  “old” liberals  of  the  Rust  Belt,  backed  by  labor,  called  for  an  “industrial  policy” to  provide  aid  mainly  to  declining  mass-production  or  “sunset”  industries. At  the  same  time,  middle-class  “neoliberals”  from  the  suburbs  and  the  Sun Belt,12  facing  the  erosion  of  the  Democrats’  traditional  blue-collar,  working- class  base,  urged  help  for  new,  post-Fordist,  high-technology  or  “sunrise”  in¬ dustries.  Their  hope  was  to  expand  their  support  among  the  growing  ranks of  post-industrial  professionals  and  other  white-collar  workers,  as  well  as among  politically  unaligned  high-technology  business  interests  (Graham 1992). After  several  years  of  intense  debate,  by  mid-1984  the  Democrats  had  re¬ treated  from  their  advocacy  of  industrial  policy  for  a  number  of  reasons, including  economic  and  administrative  objections  from  Republicans,  busi¬ ness,  mainstream  economists,  and  the  news  media.  More  fundamentally,  the Democrats  became  convinced  that  industrial  policy  was  bad  politics.  First, divisions  between  traditional  liberals  and  neoliberals  threatened  to  split  the party.  Second,  the  mass  political  appeal  of  industrial  policy  was  undermined by  its  technical  character  and  by  the  uncertain  and  long-term  nature  of  its likely  benefits.  Third,  the  economic  recovery  of  1983-84  reduced  the  per¬ ceived  political  urgency  of  government  action.  Finally  and  most  important, Democrats  worried  that  intensified  attacks  on  the  concept  by  Republicans and  other  elites  would  further  resonate  with  the  public’s  long-standing  anti¬ statist  cultural  sensibilities,  branding  the  Democrats  as  the  party  of  big  gov¬ ernment. Although  industrial  policy  had  been  driven  from  the  political  agenda  by mid-1984,  productivity  growth  and  economic  performance  during  the  rest of  the  decade  remained  relatively  lackluster,  while  after  falling  for  several years,  the  United  States  trade  deficit,  especially  with  Japan,  headed  back  up again.  Concern  for  the  apparent  decline  of  American  industry,  now  including high-technology  firms,  therefore  also  remained  alive.  Consequently,  policy experts  aligned  with  the  Democrats  developed  new  proposals  for  what  was now  termed  expanded  “public  investment”  — in  education  and  training,  infra¬ structure,  and  dynamic  new  technologies.  Some  proposals  of  this  kind  were included  in  the  Trade  Act  of  1988  (which  Democrats  sponsored),  were  ad¬ vanced  by  the  Democratic  presidential  candidate  Michael  Dukakis  that  same Grappling  with  Globalization  219 year,  and  were  subsequently  introduced  by  congressional  Democrats  during George  H.  W.  Bush’s  presidency. The  Clinton  Years: From  Promoting  Public  Investment  to  Battling  over  Free  Trade Clinton’s  Public  Investment  Program  and  Its  Demise The  Democratic  presidential  nominee  in  1992  was  Governor  Bill  Clinton  of Arkansas.  A  self-proclaimed  “New  Democrat,”  Clinton  had  led  the  Demo¬ cratic  Leadership  Council  (dlc),  a  moderate  group  formed  shortly  after Ronald  Reagan’s  reelection  in  1984  to  break  the  grip  of  labor  and  other  “spe¬ cial  interests”  on  the  Democratic  Party  and  pull  it  back  to  the  political  cen¬ ter.  Making  a  new  political-economic  strategy  central  to  his  campaign,  Clin¬ ton  sought  to  facilitate  the  transition  to  a  more  internationally  competitive post-Fordist  economic  order.  But  he  also  hoped  to  cushion  the  impact  of  this transition  and  to  spread  its  benefits  by  reviving,  albeit  in  more  limited  form, a  version  of  the  embedded  liberal  compromise. Accordingly,  in  a  plan  released  in  June  1992,  Clinton,  like  other  New Democrats,  embraced  freer  trade.  But  again  influenced  by  public  policy  ex¬ periments  during  the  Depression  and  the  Second  World  War  and  by  Japanese and  European  technology  and  labor  market  policies,  he  also  called  for  in¬ creased  public  investment  in  physical  and  human  capital.13  Technology  and manufacturing  plans  followed  in  September.  This  strategy  was  to  be  comple¬ mented  by  the  establishment  of  a  comprehensive  new  national  health  insur¬ ance  system.  At  the  same  time,  Clinton’s  plan  called  for  halving  the  burgeon¬ ing  federal  budget  deficit  within  four  years. Clinton’s  plan  was  therefore  actually  a  hybrid  of  statist,  social  democratic, and  neoliberal  elements  intended  to  appeal  simultaneously  to  core  Demo¬ cratic  constituencies,  including  labor  and  African-Americans;  swing  voters, including  blue-collar  “Reagan  Democrats,”  middle-class  suburbanites,  and the  socially  diverse,  deficit-conscious  supporters  of  the  independent  presi¬ dential  candidate  Ross  Perot;  and  various  industrial  and  financial  interests. Yet  by  the  time  Clinton  had  become  president  and  submitted  his  first  eco¬ nomic  plan  to  Congress  in  February  1993,  his  original  public  investment  pro¬ posals  had  been  cut  in  half  in  favor  of  a  greater  stress  on  deficit  reduction. This  shift  of  emphasis  was  due  in  part  to  the  influence  of  the  Federal  Reserve chairman,  Alan  Greenspan,  and  Clinton’s  own  economic  advisors,  who  con¬ vinced  him  that  the  financial  markets,  averse  to  deficits  and  inflation,  had  to be  further  conciliated  to  bring  down  interest  rates.  Also  important  was  Clin- 220  Shoch ton’s  perceived  need  to  secure  reelection  support  from  the  backers  of  Perot, who  had  won  a  stunning  19%  of  the  vote  in  the  presidential  race.  In  Congress Clinton’s  plan  faced  severe  criticism  from  Republicans  and  business  who  saw it  as  a  return  to  big  government  and  “tax-and-spend  liberalism.”  When  these attacks  appeared  to  resonate  with  voters’  anti-statist  cultural  values,  Demo¬ crats  facing  reelection,  especially  southern  conservatives,  voted  to  cut  Clin¬ ton’s  investment  program  by  half  again  to  make  room  for  still  more  deficit reduction.  A  year  later  Clinton’s  healthcare  plan  was  similarly  torpedoed  by intense  Republican  and  business  opposition,  which  transformed  initial  public enthusiasm  for  the  plan  into  opposition  and  again  prompted  leading  congres¬ sional  Democrats  to  back  away  from  offering  their  own  support. After  the  Republicans  captured  control  of  Congress  in  the  midterm  elec¬ tions  of  1994,  their  opposition  limited  Clinton’s  subsequent  public  investment and  social  spending  initiatives.  But  Clinton  and  his  Democratic  colleagues themselves  continued  to  retreat  from  these  ideas  throughout  the  rest  of  his presidency.  This  was  due  to  the  subsequent  economic  recovery,  which  was attributed  by  the  White  House  to  the  president’s  shift  toward  fiscal  restraint; the  election  debacle,  which  was  accurately  perceived  as  being  in  part  a  re¬ action  to  Clinton’s  alleged  tax-and-spend  proclivities;  and  Clinton’s  reelection and  modest  Democratic  congressional  gains  in  1996,  which  appeared  to  con¬ firm  for  him  and  his  party  the  political  wisdom  of  his  economic  policy  course adjustments. The  Intra-Democratic  Struggle  over  Trade  Liberalization With  the  demise  of  his  public  investment  strategy  by  the  summer  of  1993, Clinton  turned  to  a  two-pronged  strategy  of  “export-led  growth”  to  help  re¬ vive  the  sluggish  economy  and  improve  his  reelection  chances.  First,  the White  House  escalated  efforts  begun  by  Reagan  and  Bush  under  Democratic pressure  to  open  Japan’s  markets,  concluding  limited  agreements  with  Tokyo in  both  1993  and  1995.  Second  and  more  important,  Clinton  pursued  a  num¬ ber  of  bilateral,  regional,  and  multilateral  free-trade  agreements.  By  the early  1990s  growing  international  economic  integration  had  expanded  the ranks  of  export-oriented  and  multinational  firms,  while  interests  threatened by  imports  had  either  been  driven  out  of  business  or  been  forced  to  adjust to  more  competitive  market  conditions  by  technologically  modernizing  and moving  production  offshore.  Together  with  the  waning  of  Japanese  economic strength,  these  changes  produced  a  lasting  reorientation  of  the  objectives  of American  trade  policy  away  from  import  limits  and  aggressive  reciprocity and  toward  trade  and  investment  liberalization. Grappling  with  Globalization  221 Most  presidents  are  free  traders,  because  of  their  national  electoral  con¬ stituencies  and  their  foreign  policy  responsibilities.  But  Clinton’s  concerted efforts  to  negotiate  and  win  approval  of  these  new  trade  deals  were  also  con¬ sistent  with  his  personal  belief  in  open  trade,  and  intended  to  win  him  the support  of  internationally  oriented  business  interests  and  voters  who  were expected  to  benefit  from  export-related  job  growth.  Conversely,  Clinton  was willing  to  risk  provoking  opposition  from  organized  labor,  many  of  whose members,  absent  any  significant  expansion  of  paltry  existing  compensation programs,  were  likely  to  be  harmed  by  further  trade  liberalization. The  fate  of  Clinton’s  substantive  and  procedural  free-trade  initiatives  was mixed.  Congressional  approval  of  the  North  American  Free  Trade  Agreement (NAFTA)  in  the  fall  of  1993  was  followed  a  year  later  by  ratification  of  the “Uruguay  Round”  GATT  treaty,  which  among  other  things  established  the new  World  Trade  Organization  (WTO).  In  both  1997  and  1998,  however,  trade liberalization  ground  to  a  halt,  when  the  House  of  Representatives  blocked legislation  to  extend  Clinton’s  “fast-track”  trade  negotiating  authority.  Fast- track  authority  facilitates  the  negotiation  of  free-trade  agreements  by  award¬ ing  them  quick  up-or-down  votes  in  Congress  without  amendments  that  can unhinge  the  entire  process.  Clinton  had  hoped  to  use  this  renewed  authority to  strike  new  free-trade  deals  with  Latin  American  and  Asian  nations.  But  two years  later,  in  2000,  Congress  approved  legislation  granting  “permanent  nor¬ mal  trade  relations”  status  to  the  People’s  Republic  of  China. This  seesawing  set  of  outcomes  was  decided  mainly  in  the  House,  since Senate  support  for  free  trade  was  less  problematic.14  The  variable  and  often very  close  House  votes  were  determined  principally  by  the  shifting  positions of  House  Democrats.  By  contrast,  two-thirds  to  three-quarters  of  House  Re¬ publicans  consistently  supported  these  measures,  in  large  part  because  they represented  mostly  export-oriented  and  white-collar  districts  and  were  de¬ pendent  on  internationally  oriented  business  donors. During  the  Clinton  years  a  deep  split  over  trade  opened  in  the  Democratic Party,  including  within  Congress.  On  one  side  were  liberal,  blue-collar,  and labor-backed  urban  “old”  Democrats  from  the  Northeast  and  Midwest.  The majority  opposed  free  trade,  not  least  because  the  demise  of  Clinton’s  public investment  and  healthcare  plans  left  their  working-class  constituents  heavily exposed  to  the  dislocating  pressures  of  the  world  economy.  On  the  other  side were  moderate  and  conservative  white-collar,  business-supported,  suburban “new”  Democrats  from  the  South  and  West,  often  aligned  with  the  centrist DLC.  Most  supported  free  trade.  The  fluctuation  in  House  Democratic  voting on  trade  issues  during  these  years  can  to  a  degree  be  explained  by  election- induced  shifts  in  the  relative  strength  of  these  two  Democratic  factions. 222  Shoch Other  considerations  were  also  important,  including  the  varying  inten¬ sity  of  the  lobbying  campaigns  mounted  by  pro-trade  business  interests  and by  labor  and  other  opponents  of  free  trade,  shifts  in  the  relative  dependence of  House  Democrats  on  business  and  labor  campaign  contributions,15  the  co¬ hesiveness  of  the  House  Democratic  leadership,  and  the  effectiveness  of  the bargaining  activities  of  Bill  Clinton  and  other  White  House  officials. Trade  Liberalization  Advances:  NAFTA  and  GATT In  November  1993  the  first  of  Clinton’s  trade  and  investment  liberalization deals,  NAFTA,  was  ratified,  thanks  to  a  split  in  the  House  Democratic  Cau¬ cus.16  Hoping  to  appeal  to  both  old  and  new  Democratic  constituencies,  Clin¬ ton  had  endorsed  NAFTA  during  his  presidential  campaign  while  also  pledg¬ ing  to  negotiate  labor  and  environmental  side  agreements  to  allay  the  fears  of unions  and  environmental  groups  of  a  “race  to  the  bottom”  by  United  States corporations  looking  to  take  advantage  of  Mexico’s  cheap  labor  and  poorly enforced  environmental  laws. Criticizing  the  agreements  negotiated  by  the  Clinton  administration  as too  weak,  organized  labor  and  its  allies  waged  an  intense  campaign  against NAFTA,  eventually  leading  60%  of  House  Democrats  to  oppose  it.  The  other 40%  of  House  Democrats  had  a  number  of  reasons  for  voting  in  favor.  First,  a bloc  of  moderate  and  conservative,  disproportionately  southern  Democrats backed  the  deal,  encouraged  by  the  DLC.  Second,  internationally  oriented business  interests  organized  a  strong  pro-NAFTA  lobbying  campaign,  focused mainly  on  undecided  Democrats.  Third,  the  Democrats’  dependence  on  busi¬ ness  campaign  contributions  had  increased  since  the  early  1980s.  Fourth, there  was  a  deep  split  in  the  House  Democratic  leadership,  reflecting  rank- and-file  differences.  Finally,  Clinton  undertook  furious  efforts  to  persuade Congress  and  the  public,  which  included  both  appeals  to  party  loyalty  and promises  of  selective  import  curbs  and  a  new  trade  adjustment  assistance program.17 In  the  following  year  the  Uruguay  Round  GATT  treaty  was  ratified  by  the House  with  considerably  greater  ease,  as  fully  65%  of  the  Democratic  cau¬ cus  supported  the  accord.  The  key  here  was  that  labor  expressed  only  token opposition  to  the  deal,  the  effects  of  which  seemed  likely  to  be  diffuse  rather than  focused  on  specific  income  groups;  this  made  labor  less  concerned  about the  Uruguay  Round  than  it  had  been  about  NAFTA,  which  the  unions  feared would  produce  a  devastating  flight  of  capital  to  Mexico  (Baldwin  and  Magee 2000,  29,  42). Grappling  with  Globalization  223 Trade  Liberalization  Stalled:  The  Fast-Track  Battles Three  years  later,  in  November  1997,  the  process  of  trade  liberalization  stalled when  Clinton  was  forced  to  withdraw  the  “clean”  fast-track  proposal  he  had introduced  (it  contained  no  significant  labor  and  environmental  provisions). Principally  dooming  the  proposal  was  the  opposition  of  about  80%  of  House Democrats  (Shoch  2000;  Conley  1999;  Schnietz  and  Nieman  1999;  Bardwell 2000). This  pronounced  shift  in  Democratic  behavior  had  several  causes.  First,  a substantial  number  of  pro-trade  Democrats  retired  or  were  defeated  in  the congressional  elections  of  1994  and  1996,  while  the  latter  year  saw  the  elec¬ tion  of  a  number  of  liberal  and  moderate  Democrats  from  mostly  northern districts  where  opposition  to  free  trade  was  stronger.  Second,  the  business campaign  for  fast-track  authority  was  poorly  organized  and  unenergetic, largely  because  fast-track  was  a  procedural  measure  lacking  concrete  bene¬ fits,  unlike  the  NAFTA  accord,  which  contained  many.  Third,  despite  its  secu¬ lar  decline  labor  waged  a  more  intense  and  effective  campaign  against  fast- track  than  it  had  done  against  NAFTA.  In  conjunction  with  the  unions’  success in  turning  out  and  influencing  the  labor  vote  in  the  congressional  elections of  1996,  this  led  most  Democrats  to  oppose  Clinton’s  bill  in  the  hope  of  bene¬ fiting  from  a  similar  labor  effort  in  the  midterm  elections  in  1998  (Francia 2005).  Fourth,  after  the  elections  in  1994  there  was  a  shift  of  business  cam¬ paign  contributions  from  the  Democrats  to  the  now  majority  Republicans, as  well  as  an  increase  in  labor  donations  to  Democratic  candidates.  This  left the  party,  including  even  New  Democrats,  more  dependent  on  labor  money. Fifth,  the  House  Democratic  leadership  undertook  a  more  unified  campaign against  fast-track.  Finally,  Clinton’s  lobbying  efforts  were  less  concerted  and effective  than  they  had  been  on  NAFTA.  His  “inside-the-beltway”  strategy  of promising  concessions  failed  to  sway  Democrats  alienated  by  his  failure  to deliver  on  retraining  and  other  promises  made  during  the  NAFTA  fight. Hoping  to  mend  relations  with  House  Democrats,  Clinton  decided  to  hold off  on  sending  another  fast-track  proposal  to  Congress  until  after  the  midterm congressional  elections  in  November  1998.  Instead,  it  was  the  Republican House  speaker,  Newt  Gingrich,  who  in  late  June  announced  a  fall  vote  on  a new  “clean”  fast-track  proposal.  Gingrich  hoped  to  use  the  bill  in  the  elections against  Democratic  fast-track  opponents  from  districts  with  concentrations  of export-dependent  agricultural  interests  (Shoch  2000;  Biglaiser,  Jackson,  and Peake  2004). In  late  September  the  House  decisively  defeated  the  GOP  bill,  as  86%  of the  chamber’s  Democrats  voted  against  it.  Democratic  opposition  to  the  bill 224  Shoch was  heightened  by  splits  among  businesses  over  the  timing  of  the  vote  and the  bill’s  poor  prospects.  Second,  the  unions  waged  another  strong  campaign against  the  bill.  This  again  led  both  liberal  and  moderate  Democrats  to  op¬ pose  it  in  the  hope  of  securing  grassroots  activism  and  campaign  contribu¬ tions  from  unions  in  the  upcoming  elections.  Third,  Bill  Clinton  and  many New  Democrats  refused  to  support  the  bill,  which  they  saw  as  an  obvious  GOP attempt  to  embarrass  and  divide  their  party  before  the  elections. Trade  Liberalization  Resumed:  PNTR  with  China The  final  free-trade  battle  of  the  Clinton  years  was  over  permanent  normal trade  relations  (PNTR)  with  China.  PNTR  status  would  have  allowed  Congress to  abandon  its  annual  vote  on  whether  to  grant  “most  favored  nation”  status to  China,  a  cold  war  practice  intended  to  pressure  Beijing  to  improve  human rights.  Administration  officials  believed  that  awarding  PNTR  status  to  China was  necessary  if  eager  American  firms  were  to  receive  the  various  market¬ opening  and  investment  concessions  that  Beijing  had  made  in  an  agreement struck  with  the  United  States  in  late  1999  to  facilitate  China’s  entry  into  the WTO.  After  yet  another  furious  battle,  the  PNTR  bill  was  approved  by  the House  in  May  2000.  The  key  to  the  measure’s  passage  was  support  from  35% of  Democrats,  up  from  the  20%  and  14%  of  party  members  who  had  backed the  fast-track  bills  in  1997  and  1998  (Hasnat  and  Callahan  2002). This  new  turnaround  in  Democratic  behavior  was  partly  due  to  the  vic¬ tory  in  1998  of  a  number  of  young,  pro-business,  pro-trade  moderate  Demo¬ crats  from  affluent  suburban  districts,  mainly  in  the  Northeast.  Organized labor,  fearing  the  offshoring  of  United  States  production  to  China,  had  waged another  strong  campaign  against  PNTR.  But  that  effort  was  weakened  by support  for  the  deal  by  some  union  locals  representing  workers  in  trade- dependent  industries,  and  by  fears  that  defeat  of  the  measure  would  jeopar¬ dize  the  prospects  in  the  forthcoming  elections  of  the  Democratic  presiden¬ tial  nominee,  A1  Gore,  or  the  Democrats’  hopes  of  recapturing  control  of  the House.  A  third  reason  was  that  business  interests  saw  vast  market  and  in¬ vestment  opportunities  in  the  China  deal  and  undertook  a  massive  lobbying campaign  on  behalf  of  PNTR  in  Washington  and  at  the  grassroots,  as  they  had not  done  when  the  procedural  fast-track  bill  was  being  considered  in  1997. Fourth,  the  1999-2000  election  cycle  saw  a  new  if  limited  shift  of  business campaign  contributions  back  to  the  Democrats.  Many  corporate  leaders,  en¬ couraged  by  various  New  Democratic  groups,  recognized  in  the  wake  of  the fast-track  defeat  in  1997  that  in  dramatically  shifting  their  support  to  the  Re¬ publicans  after  the  midterms  in  1994  they  had  lost  influence  with  the  Demo- Grappling  with  Globalization  225 crats,  who  had  become  more  financially  beholden  to,  and  therefore  more  sup¬ portive  of,  organized  labor.  Fifth,  that  same  election  cycle  saw  the  emergence of  the  internationally  oriented  high-technology  sector  as  a  major  contributor to  Democratic  candidates,  especially  pro-trade  New  Democrats.  Sixth,  a  new split  opened  among  House  Democratic  leaders,  some  of  whom,  although  op¬ posed  to  PNTR,  refrained  from  actively  organizing  against  it  to  avoid  offend¬ ing  existing  and  potential  business  donors.  Finally,  there  were  the  reenergized lobbying  efforts  of  Bill  Clinton,  who  hoped  that  approval  of  PNTR  would  help to  secure  his  legacy  as  a  champion  of  free  trade  and  lighten  the  stain  of  the House’s  vote  to  impeach  him  in  1998. The  Democrats  and  Trade  Liberalization  during  the  Bush  Years The  dramatic  presidential  race  of  2000  saw  the  election  of  George  W.  Bush,  a Republican  who  pushed  to  complete  the  neoliberal  “Reagan  Revolution”  with big  new  tax  cuts.  The  process  of  trade  liberalization  also  continued  during Bush’s  presidency,  but  only  after  bruising  fights,  again  mainly  in  the  House. In  the  summer  of  2002,  after  a  series  of  extraordinarily  close  and  partisan House  votes,  Congress  gave  Bush  fast-track  authority  — now  renamed  “trade promotion  authority”  (TPA)— to  help  him  negotiate  a  new  international  trade agreement  under  the  auspices  of  the  WTO  and  a  Free  Trade  Agreement  of  the Americas.  Finally,  after  another  bitter,  close,  and  partisan  fight  in  the  House, Congress  approved  the  Central  America  Free  Trade  Agreement  (CAFTA)  in the  summer  of  2005.18 Whereas  the  positions  of  House  Democrats  on  the  several  major  trade  lib¬ eralization  measures  of  the  Clinton  years  were  quite  variable,  Democratic opposition  to  both  TPA  and  CAFTA  rose  substantially.  This  was  in  part  be¬ cause  the  Democrats  were  no  longer  confronting  a  fellow  Democratic  presi¬ dent  whose  political  fortunes  they  to  a  degree  shared,  but  rather  a  staunchly conservative  Republican  one.  But  other  factors  discussed  below  were  impor¬ tant  too. Bush’s  victories  on  both  issues  were  thus  due  not  to  shifts  in  Democratic behavior  but  rather  to  increased  GOP  support  for  trade  liberalization.  Strong business  lobbying  and  pressure  from  House  Republican  leaders  and  the  White House  played  a  role  in  this.  Particularly  important  was  the  inclination  of  Re¬ publicans  who  might  have  opposed  the  trade  liberalization  proposals  of  a Democratic  president  to  instead  back  TPA  and  CAFTA  as  the  initiatives  of  a Republican  president  whose  fate  they  in  part  shared. 226  Shoch The  Trade  Promotion  Authority  Battle Despite  the  victory  of  PNTR,  as  George  W.  Bush  took  office  in  early  2001  pro¬ trade  business  leaders  and  policy  experts  remained  concerned  that  presiden¬ tial  fast-track  authority  to  facilitate  the  negotiation  of  new  free-trade  agree¬ ments  had  still  not  been  renewed.  Thereupon,  in  early  October  2001  a  trade promotion  authority  proposal  sponsored  by  the  GOP  was  introduced  in  the House.  In  the  hope  of  winning  at  least  some  support  from  moderate  New Democrats,  the  measure  gave  greater  prominence  to  labor  and  environmen¬ tal  standards  than  previous  bills  had  done.  But  to  avoid  GOP  opposition,  the bill  was  largely  silent  on  enforcement  mechanisms,  which  angered  labor  and environmental  activists. In  early  December,  after  a  bitter  fight,  the  bill  passed  by  an  excruciatingly close  margin  of  215-214  (Biglaiser,  Jackson,  and  Peake  2004;  Destler  2005, 290-98;  Forgette  2004, 163-65).  Six  months  later  the  House  approved  a  mo¬ tion  to  send  the  TPA  bill  to  conference  with  the  Senate— again,  almost  incred¬ ibly,  by  the  margin  of  a  single  vote:  216-215.  In  a  successful  move  to  win  more New  Democratic  support  for  the  measure,  a  provision  originated  by  Senate Democrats  was  added  to  expand  the  TAA  program  and  provide  a  new  health¬ care  tax  credit  and  a  wage  insurance  program  for  displaced  workers.  A  month later  the  House  narrowly  passed  a  compromise  conference  bill  by  yet  another extremely  close  vote,  215-212. These  were  all  not  only  close  votes  but  also  exceptionally  partisan  ones; the  most  partisan,  in  fact,  of  any  congressional  trade  votes  taken  since  the Second  World  War.  Democratic  opposition  to  TPA  rose  to  90%  on  the  vote  in December  2001  (up  from  65%  on  PNTR),  to  95%  on  the  vote  in  June  2002  to send  the  House  version  of  the  bill  to  conference,  and  to  88%  on  the  final  con¬ ference  bill.  This  would  have  been  enough  to  defeat  the  measures  had  not  Re¬ publican  support  for  TPA  on  the  three  votes  climbed  to  89%,  93%,  and  88%. Opposition  to  TPA  was  strong  among  Democrats  of  all  ideological  orien¬ tations— including  most  moderate,  usually  pro-trade  New  Democrats— for  a number  of  reasons.  First,  there  was  the  perception  that  public  anxiety  over globalization  was  growing  just  as  the  economy  was  falling  into  recession.  Sec¬ ond,  a  strong  campaign  was  waged  against  the  bill  by  environmental  activists and  especially  organized  labor,  which  was  unimpressed  by  the  limited  TAA, healthcare,  and  wage  insurance  provisions  included  in  the  measure.19  Labor’s influence  within  the  party  had  grown  because  of  the  unions’  massive  mobili¬ zation  for  A1  Gore  and  other  Democratic  candidates  in  2000  and  the  substan¬ tial  union  effort  planned  for  the  midterm  elections  of  2002,  when  low  turn¬ out  was  forecast.  The  decision  by  the  AFL-CIO  to  endorse  up  to  seventy-five Grappling  with  Globalization  227 moderate  Republican  candidates  in  those  races  also  made  it  harder  for  the Democrats  to  take  labor’s  support  for  granted.  Third,  there  was  the  beginning of  yet  another  shift  of  business  campaign  contributions  back  to  the  Republi¬ cans  after  Bush’s  victory  and  the  GOP’s  success  in  retaining  control  of  the House,  which  again  left  Democrats  more  dependent  on  labor  money.  Fourth, the  collapse  of  the  “dot-coms”  and  troubles  throughout  the  high-technology sector  hurt  the  New  Democrats’  fundraising,  still  further  increasing  their  reli¬ ance  on  labor  money.  Fifth,  because  of  a  secular  geographical  and  ideological realignment  of  the  parties’  electoral  coalitions,  the  growing  polarization  of party  activists,  a  combatively  conservative  Republican  congressional  leader¬ ship,  and  a  divisive  president  playing  to  his  base  rather  than  to  swing  voters, the  level  of  partisanship  in  Washington  was  extremely  high,  while  both  old and  new  Democrats  were  angry  in  particular  at  the  way  Bush  and  congres¬ sional  Republicans  tried  to  ram  the  TPA  bill  through  the  House.  Finally,  House Democratic  leaders  made  determined  efforts  to  rally  their  members  against the  TPA  bill,  which  contrasted  with  their  much  more  passive  role  in  the  PNTR fight. The  strong  Democratic  opposition  to  TPA  would  have  been  sufficient  to sink  the  bill  had  it  received  a  level  of  support  from  Republicans  comparable to  their  support  for  free-trade  measures  of  the  previous  decade.  But  for  the reasons  mentioned  above,  GOP  support  for  TPA  rose  to  new  heights,  making this  the  key  to  the  bill’s  victory. The  Central  America  Free  Trade  Agreement Buoyed  by  his  narrow  TPA  victory,  over  the  next  several  years  George  W.  Bush used  his  new  authority  to  negotiate  and  obtain  the  ratification  of  several  un- controversial  bilateral  trade  agreements.  In  the  summer  of  2004,  however, his  administration  also  struck  a  much  more  contentious  deal:  the  Central America  Free  Trade  Agreement.20  Central  America  was  not  a  big  market  for United  States  goods.  But  the  White  House  and  business  interests  saw  the  ap¬ proval  of  cafta  as  a  stepping  stone  to  the  successful  conclusion  of  the  “Doha Round”  of  international  trade  negotiations,  begun  in  Qatar  in  late  2001,  and the  negotiation  of  a  Free  Trade  Agreement  of  the  Americas. As  usual,  the  House  battle  over  CAFTA  in  the  spring  and  summer  of  2005 was  a  bitter  one,  culminating  in  another  nail-biting,  highly  partisan  victory for  the  White  House  by  a  vote  of  217-215.  Democratic  opposition  to  CAFTA reached  93%,  which  again  would  have  sunk  the  pact  had  not  88%  of  Republi¬ cans  supported  it. The  unified  Democratic  opposition  to  CAFTA,  which  included  most  New 228  Shoch Democrats,  again  had  multiple  sources.  First  were  the  still  growing  fears that  economic  globalization  was  eroding  the  jobs  and  wages  of  United  States workers,  while  there  was  also  more  specific  disappointment  with  the  results of  NAFTA  and  of  pntr  with  China.  Second,  there  was  additional  dismay  that Bush  had  not  delivered  on  training  and  education  provisions  of  the  TPA  bill enacted  in  2002.  Third,  labor  undertook  yet  another  energetic  mobilization effort  against  the  deal.  Fourth,  New  Democrats,  already  inflamed  by  Republi¬ can  hard-line  conservatism  and  authoritarianism,  were  further  angered  by how  they  were  treated  during  the  CAFTA  fight.  House  GOP  leaders  excluded the  New  Democrats  from  discussions  of  the  CAFTA  implementing  legislation, goaded  them  to  oppose  a  bill  with  weak  labor  and  environmental  provisions, and  pressured  corporate  donors,  including  high-technology  interests,  to abandon  their  already  diminished  support  for  Democratic  candidates.  Fifth,  a resulting  further  decline  in  business  contributions  left  Democrats  of  all  ideo¬ logical  stripes  still  more  reliant  on  labor  money.  Finally,  opposition  to  CAFTA was  strong  among  House  Democratic  leaders. As  with  TPA  and  for  similar  reasons,  the  key  to  CAFTA ’s  passage  in  the  face of  strong  Democratic  opposition  was  the  almost  equally  strong  Republican backing  for  the  deal. Democratic  Resurgence: Trade,  Compensatory  Spending,  and  Competitiveness  Policy Despite  CAFTA ’s  approval,  during  the  past  six  years  popular  concern  over globalization  has  continued  to  mount,  in  part  because  of  the  emergence  of four  major  new  economic  challengers,  the  “BRIC”  nations  — Brazil,  Russia, and  especially  India  and  China— on  the  global  economic  stage.  Organized labor,  still  a  key  Democratic  constituency  despite  its  long-term  decline,  re¬ mains  resolutely  opposed  to  new  trade  and  investment  liberalization  mea¬ sures.  And  the  wider  public  is  increasingly  convinced  that  globalization,  in¬ cluding  expanded  trade  and  now  the  offshore  outsourcing  of  both  blue-  and white-collar  jobs,  has  contributed  to  slow  employment  growth,  stagnant wages,  and  eroding  healthcare  and  retirement  benefits. The  Democrats  benefited  from  these  sentiments  in  the  congressional  mid¬ term  elections  of  2006.  The  party  regained  control  of  both  houses  of  Congress for  the  first  time  since  1994,  thanks  in  part  to  the  victory  of  a  significant  num¬ ber  of  “populist,”  labor-backed  critics  of  free  trade.  During  the  next  two  years congressional  Democrats  refused  to  renew  Bush’s  trade  negotiating  authority and  blocked  approval  of  a  number  of  bilateral  free-trade  agreements,  includ¬ ing,  most  controversially,  one  with  Colombia  (Destler  2007). Grappling  with  Globalization  229 The  Democrats’  presidential  nominee  and  eventual  victor  in  2008,  Sena¬ tor  Barack  Obama,  was  at  heart  a  free  trader.  But  during  his  campaign— and especially  just  before  crucial  primaries  in  heavily  working-class  Ohio  and Pennsylvania— Obama  called  for  a  halt  to  the  negotiation  of  new  trade  agree¬ ments  without  strong  labor  and  environmental  standards.  He  also  pledged to  revisit  NAFTA.  Finally,  Obama  also  promised  to  get  tough  with  China  for unfairly  subsidizing  its  exporters  with  cash,  loans,  and  an  undervalued  cur¬ rency.  After  his  victory,  however,  freed  from  immediate  election  pressures, Obama  softened  his  position  on  NAFTA  and  China,  in  the  latter  case  for  fear of  provoking  a  sell-off  of  United  States  government  debt  held  by  the  Chinese. He  also  hoped  to  win  quick  congressional  approval  of  stalled  trade  agree¬ ments  with  Panama,  Colombia,  and  South  Korea  and  to  finish  negotiations  on a  global  trade  deal  by  the  end  of  2010  (Ashbee  and  Waddan  2010). But  with  the  victory  of  still  more  populist  Democrats  to  Congress  in  the same  election,  and  especially  with  the  economy  only  slowly  recovering  from the  worst  recession  since  the  1930s,  congressional  Democrats  continued  their hardened  approach  to  trade  policy.  Supported  by  labor  and  some  manufactur¬ ers,  in  their  big  economic  stimulus  bill  in  early  2009  the  Democrats  included a  controversial,  albeit  watered-down,  “Buy  American”  provision.  Later, strong  congressional  opposition,  especially  from  House  Democrats,  led  the White  House  to  temporarily  back  off  from  its  drive  for  new  trade  deals  and to  pledge  instead  to  focus  on  more  aggressively  enforcing  existing  trade  and labor  rights  rules,  in  the  hope  that  doing  so  would  eventually  weaken  oppo¬ sition  to  further  trade  liberalization.21 In  the  late  spring  of  2010,  however,  along  with  an  ambitious  plan  to  spur job  growth  by  doubling  exports,  Obama  renewed  his  promise  to  push  ahead on  stalled  and  new  free-trade  agreements,  including  a  new  Trans  Pacific  Part¬ nership.22  A  deal  was  subsequently  reached  in  early  November  with  South Korea  that  reduced  barriers  to  United  States  auto  and  food  exports  to  the country.  The  following  April  an  “action  plan”  to  improve  labor  rights  in Colombia  was  negotiated  to  facilitate  completion  of  the  stalled  free  trade  pact with  the  nation.  Most  of  the  labor  movement,  however,  continues  to  oppose these  agreements,  which  are  still  felt  to  lack  sufficiently  strong  workplace  and environmental  standards.  As  a  consequence,  most  congressional  Democrats also  remain  opposed  to  these  deals.  Instead,  about  half  of  House  Democrats are  backing  legislation  that  would  require  a  wide-ranging  review  of  NAFTA and  other  trade  pacts  and  boost  the  role  of  Congress  in  negotiations  over future  deals.  And  in  early  October  2010  House  Democrats,  joined  by  many Republicans,  passed  a  bill  that  would  impose  tariffs  on  imports  from  China should  Beijing  continue  to  manipulate  the  value  of  its  currency.  It  is  possible, 230  Shoch though,  that  sufficient  support  for  pending  and  future  free  trade  agreements will  eventually  be  found  from  Republicans  and  pro-trade  Democrats  to  secure their  approval. With  respect  to  compensatory  spending,  in  November  2007  House  Demo¬ crats  passed  a  bill  to  expand  and  extend  TAA  benefits,  but  Senate  Republicans blocked  it.  Democratic  leaders  suggested  that  approval  of  this  measure  and related  unemployment,  training,  and  other  legislation  was  necessary  before new  trade  deals  with  Colombia  and  other  nations  could  be  voted  on.  Obama likewise  supported  such  compensatory  policies  during  the  presidential  race. Both  he  and  congressional  Democrats  also  called  for  a  major  revamping  of  the United  States  healthcare  system  to  expand  access  and  lower  costs. Meanwhile,  after  fading  away  during  Bill  Clinton’s  second  term  and George  W.  Bush’s  first,  the  issues  of  competitiveness  and  public  investment have  recently  returned  to  the  United  States  political  agenda  with  the  rise  of the  BRlCs.  Building  on  the  House  Democrats’  Innovation  Agenda  from  2006, in  August  2007  Congress  passed  and  George  Bush  signed  the  America  Com¬ petes  Act.  The  bill  called  for  increased  spending  on  various  federal  energy, science,  technology,  and  research  programs.  Congressional  Democrats  also introduced  legislation  to  modernize  the  nation’s  aging  infrastructure.  During his  presidential  campaign  Obama  had  similarly  promised  to  increase  pub¬ lic  investment  in  education  and  training,  infrastructure,  renewable  energy sources,  and  technological  research. Then  in  the  fall  of  2008  came  the  dramatic  worsening  of  the  develop¬ ing  crisis  of  “financialized  capitalism,”  the  product  of  stagnant  wages  and rising  consumer  debt,  an  influx  of  foreign  capital  and  loose  monetary  policy by  the  Federal  Reserve,  risky  mortgage  lending  and  derivatives  trading,  and lax  financial  regulation  (Rajan  2010).  Contributing  to  the  demise  of  the  Re¬ publican  order  and  renewed  Democratic  control  of  the  White  House  and  Con¬ gress,  the  severe  crisis  also  relaxed  various  constraints  on  greater  government activism.  Most  important,  as  Obama  took  office  in  January  2009  the  Ameri¬ can  public,  traditionally  hesitant  about  the  economic  role  of  government,23 now  backed  a  big  economic  stimulus  package  that  included  substantial  new spending,  even  if  it  was  expected  to  lead  to  bigger  budget  deficits.24 In  addition,  faced  with  collapsing  consumer  demand,  frozen  credit  mar¬ kets,  growing  unemployment,  and  the  threat  of  deflation,  as  well  as  the  seem¬ ing  impotence  of  monetary  expansion  and  lower  interest  rates  to  bring  about recovery,  usually  deficit-wary  economists,  including  veterans  of  Clinton’s  ad¬ ministration  who  were  advising  Obama,  rediscovered  the  merits  of  Keynesian fiscal  policy.  Mainstream  economists  typically  worry  that  big  deficits  will lead  to  inflation,  a  sell-off  of  government  securities,  a  sagging  dollar,  the Grappling  with  Globalization  231 “crowding  out”  of  private  borrowing,  and  rising  interest  rates.  But  with  eco¬ nomic  resources  lying  idle,  interest  rates  near  zero,  and  domestic  and  foreign investors,  including  Chinese  and  other  central  bankers,  nevertheless  rush¬ ing  to  buy  “safe”  debt  issued  by  the  U.S.  Treasury,  most  economists  at  least temporarily  put  aside  their  deficit  fears  and  backed  the  major  fiscal  stimulus package  and  its  big  spending  increases. Accordingly,  in  mid-February  Obama  and  Congress  enacted  a  hefty  $787 billion  bill,  the  American  Recovery  and  Reinvestment  Act,  with  broad  sup¬ port  from  business,  labor,  and  the  public.  Most  of  the  bill  consisted  of  per¬ sonal  tax  relief  and  unemployment,  healthcare,  and  other  direct  aid  to  indi¬ viduals  and  fiscally  strapped  states.  But  there  was  also  almost  $270  billion  in new  public  investment  and  about  $30  billion  in  tax  incentives  intended  to encourage  both  short-  and  long-term  growth.  Although  the  package  was  less than  some  liberals  had  hoped  for,  it  was  more  than  Clinton  had  been  able  to win  in  his  entire  eight  years  in  office.  The  bill  provided  for  tax  credits  and new  and  increased  spending  to  promote  infrastructure  (roads,  bridges,  and mass  transit),  “green”  investments  (renewable  energy  sources,  a  new  elec¬ tric  grid,  and  conservation),  computerized  medical  records,  rural  broadband networks,  scientific  and  technological  research,  education  and  training,  and Trade  Adjustment  Assistance.25 Shorn  in  recent  decades  of  most  of  their  conservative  southern  wing, Democrats  overwhelmingly  supported  the  bill.  Conversely,  with  the  purge of  moderate  Republicans  in  the  two  previous  elections,  the  legislation  drew near  unanimous  GOP  opposition,  as  party  leaders  again  conjured  well-worn images  of  pork,  waste,  deficits,  big  government,  and  even  socialism.  Never¬ theless,  the  stimulus  measure  narrowly  passed  in  a  form  that  looked  very much  like  Obama’s  original  proposal.26 In  late  February  Obama  presented  his  budget  proposal  for  fiscal  2010, which  included  hundreds  of  billions  of  dollars  in  additional  spending  on new  energy  projects  (some  of  which  were  included  in  the  climate  and  clean- energy  bill  passed  by  the  House  in  June),  high-speed  rail,  increased  grants  for college  students,  and  most  controversially  a  major  healthcare  expansion  and reform  plan.  After  another  fierce  battle,  a  final  $3.4  billion  budget  resolution (or  outline)  passed  both  houses  of  Congress  in  late  April  without  a  single  Re¬ publican  vote.27  The  administration  also  provided  tens  of  billions  of  dollars  in loans  and  other  assistance  to  bail  out  the  beleaguered  United  States  auto  in¬ dustry,  even  assuming  a  60%  ownership  stake  in  General  Motors,  which  had filed  for  bankruptcy.28  Later  in  the  summer  Obama  also  proposed  important new  programs  to  improve  the  quality  of  K-12  and  community  college  educa¬ tion.  Bills  backed  by  the  president  to  establish  a  National  Infrastructure  Bank 232  Shoch were  introduced  in  both  houses  of  Congress.  Finally  and  most  important,  in the  face  of  continued  Republican  intransigence  and  a  public  now  increasingly concerned  about  the  growth  of  big  government,  in  March  2010  Obama  and his  congressional  Democratic  allies  passed  a  historic  ten-year  healthcare  re¬ form  bill  with  a  cost  of  $940  billion  (Howard,  this  volume).29 Obama  and  the  Democrats’  initiatives  to  date  have  been  mainly  designed to  save  and  create  jobs  and  reduce  economic  insecurity.  But  these  measures should  also  help  the  country  adjust  to  the  challenges  of  globalization— by cushioning  its  impact  on  workers  and  communities,  improving  the  competi¬ tiveness  of  existing  industries,  and  fostering  globally  competitive  new  ones. Conclusion:  Toward  a  Revived  Embedded  Liberal  Compromise? In  the  past  few  years  a  number  of  prominent  American  policy  intellectuals, including  the  former  director  of  Obama’s  National  Economic  Council,  Law¬ rence  Summers,  and  even  some  business  interests  have  called  for  reviving  and strengthening  the  embedded  liberal  compromise  (Shoch  2008;  Schatz  2008). They  propose  a  mildly  social  democratic  approach  to  globalization  that  would combine  open  markets  with  substantial  increases  in  compensatory  social spending  and  public  investment  (Scheve  and  Slaughter  2007;  Kuttner  2008a; Kuttner  2008b;  Summers  2008;  see  also  Pontusson  2005a  and  especially  Hays 2009).  This  approach  would  involve  learning  from  Europe,  particularly  from the  Nordic  countries,  and  a  consequent  degree  of  “hybridization”  of  Ameri¬ can  and  European  “social  models”  or  “varieties  of  capitalism.”30 Although  not  mainly  intended  as  such  a  hybrid  approach  to  globalization, Obama’s  economic  and  social  program,  even  more  than  Clinton’s  ill-fated  ini¬ tiatives,  embodies  key  elements  of  it,  and  the  future  of  this  approach  depends in  part  on  the  success  and  popularity  of  Obama’s  overall  program.  What  if Obama’s  and  the  Democrats’  policies  had  contributed  to  a  strong  recovery and  the  beginning  of  a  new  era  of  growth  while  mitigating  economic  insecu¬ rity,  including  the  trade-related  dislocations  experienced  by  workers  in  un¬ competitive  sectors?  In  addition  to  Obama’s  reelection  and  continued  Demo¬ cratic  congressional  dominance,  this  outcome  might  also  have  reduced  labor and  public  opposition  to  further  trade  liberalization  (Schatz  2008).  That  in turn  might  have  encouraged  Obama  to  conclude  new  trade  deals  contain¬ ing  strong  labor  and  environmental  standards,  which  congressional  Demo¬ crats,  together  with  pro-trade  Republicans,  might  then  have  approved.  In other  words,  we  might  have  seen  the  emergence  of  a  new  embedded  liberal compromise  and  a  narrowing  of  the  differences  between  the  approaches  to globalization  taken  by  the  Democratic  Party  and  its  European  counterparts. Grappling  with  Globalization  233 It  does  now  appear  that  the  “Great  Recession”  has  bottomed  out  and  that a  recovery  has  begun,  including  in  the  labor  market,  thanks  to  an  expansion¬ ary  monetary  policy  but  also  to  the  stimulus  bill,  whose  beneficial  effects have  not  been  widely  recognized.  It  also  appears,  though,  that  absent  an¬ other  significant  but  politically  unlikely  stimulus  package  or  a  strong  demand for  exports,  the  recovery  is  likely  to  be  a  protracted  and  relatively  “jobless” one— a  “lost  decade”  like  that  endured  by  Japan  is  possible— because  of  the retrenchment  of  consumer  spending,  continued  wage  stagnation,  employers’ restructuring  of  their  workforce,  state  and  local  government  spending  cuts, the  tapering  off  of  stimulus  spending,  and  a  reduction  in  bank  lending  and business  investment  in  the  face  of  weak  effective  demand.  In  addition,  sus¬ tained,  often  deceptive  Republican  attacks  on  the  stimulus  program,  govern¬ ment  bailouts,  and  the  healthcare  bill,  together  with  the  perceived  failure  of these  measures  to  strengthen  the  economy,  have  contributed  during  the  past year  to  mounting  public  apprehension  over  the  growth  of  government  spend¬ ing,  deficits,  and  intrusiveness. The  struggling  economy  and  negative  sentiment  toward  their  healthcare and  other  reform  efforts  cost  the  Democrats  six  Senate  seats  and  control  of the  House  of  Representatives  in  the  midterm  elections  in  2010.  With  the  Re¬ publicans  pressing  for  deep  cuts  in  government  spending,  Obama’s  and  the Democrats’  programmatic  achievements  are  now  likely  to  be  eroded  rather than  expanded.  Even  if  Obama  is  reelected  in  2012,  the  Republicans  are  likely to  keep  control  of  the  House  and  even  to  regain  control  of  the  Senate,  since 23  of  the  33  seats  to  be  contested  are  currently  held  by  Democrats.  This  will doom  any  significant  new  Democratic  compensatory  and  public  investment spending  initiatives,  which  in  turn  means  that  labor,  popular,  and  Democratic opposition  to  trade  liberalization  will  remain  strong.  Hopes  for  a  revived, Democratic-led  embedded  liberal  compromise  will  unfortunately  go  unful¬ filled. Notes 1.  The  commitment  of  these  parties  to  trade  liberalization  has  been  further  secured by  the  delegation  of  trade  policymaking  authority  by  member  states  first  to  the  Euro¬ pean  Economic  Community  and  later  to  the  European  Union  (Katzenstein  1985;  Han¬ son  1998;  Young  and  Peterson  2006). 2.  Here  I  am  straddling  Stolper-Samuelson  and  Ricardo-Viner,  or  “specific  fac¬ tors”  models  of  individual  trade  policy  preferences.  The  former  theories,  assuming that  production  factors  are  fully  mobile  across  industries,  argue  that  scarce  factors (in  advanced  countries,  unskilled  labor)  will  support  protection,  while  abundant  fac¬ tors  (capital  and  skilled  labor)  will  support  free  trade.  The  latter  theories,  assuming 234  Shoch that  production  factors  are  completely  immobile,  maintain  instead  that  capital  and labor  in  import-competing  industries  will  support  protection,  while  capital  and  labor in  export-oriented  and  multinational  sectors  will  support  free  trade.  For  recent  empiri¬ cal  studies  of  public  opinion  on  trade  issues  based  on  these  two  theories  see  Scheve and  Slaughter  2006  and  Hays,  Ehrlich,  and  Peinhardt  2005.  If  instead,  as  others  have argued  (cf.  Blonigen  2008),  factor  mobility  varies  over  time  and  across  countries, and  production  factors  in  the  contemporary  United  States  are  partially  mobile,  then worker  trade  policy  preferences  may  be  influenced  in  the  way  I  suggest.  For  additional recent  discussion  see  Mansfield  and  Mutz  2009  and  Jeong  2009. 3.  It  should  be  noted  that  a  number  of  welfare  state  activities,  especially  “human capital”  policies  like  education  and  training,  have  “productive”  as  well  as  “protec¬ tive”  functions.  Thus,  contra  Esping-Andersen’s  well-known  view  (1990)  that  in  “de- commodifying”  labor,  politics  work  “against”  markets,  politics  can  also  work  “with” or  “for”  markets.  See  Room  2002;  Andersen  2007;  Hudson  and  Kuhner  2008;  and Obinger,  Starke,  Moser,  Bogedan,  Obinger-Gindulis,  and  Leibfried  2010. 4.  To  briefly  situate  this  discussion  within  current  debates  among  comparative  and international  political  economists,  proponents  of  the  “compensation”  hypothesis  see greater  or  increasing  economic  openness  leading  to  a  larger  public  sector,  as  win¬ ners  compensate  losers  and  often  expand  public  investment  to  preserve  open  markets. Supporters  of  the  contrasting  “efficiency”  hypothesis  argue  that  globalization  forces governments  to  cut  spending  and  taxes  in  order  to  maintain  national  economic  com¬ petitiveness  and  prevent  capital  flight.  “Skeptics”  find  no  causal  link  between  global¬ ization  and  the  size  of  government,  emphasizing  instead  the  importance  of  domestic factors.  For  recent  reviews  of,  and  empirical  evidence  for,  the  competing  positions  see Busemeyer  2009,  Potrafke  2009,  Haupt  2010,  Jensen  2010,  and  Walter  2010. I  would  argue,  following  Carles  Boix  (2006),  that  the  influence  of  globalization  on government  policy  is  contingently  mediated  by  electoral  politics,  as  parties  struggle to  construct  winning  political  coalitions  by  deploying  competing  political-economic strategies.  These  strategies  can  include  protectionism  and  opposition  to  further  trade liberalization  as  an  alternative  to  compensation  and  public  investment  or  to  fiscal  con¬ servatism. 5.  Most  of  the  free-trade  deals  of  the  past  fifteen  years  have  actually  been  intended more  to  open  foreign  countries  to  United  States  investors  than  to  exporters.  In  this chapter  I  mostly  use  the  shorter  term  “trade  liberalization”  for  economy. 6.  For  a  book-length  version  of  much  of  the  material  contained  in  this  chapter through  Bill  Clinton’s  presidency  see  Shoch  2001. 7.  Including  (1)  winner-take-call,  single-member  district,  two-stage,  staggered,  and separated  presidential  and  congressional  elections,  and  (2)  the  separation  of  powers, the  presidential  veto,  bicameralism,  the  congressional  party  and  committee  systems, the  Senate  filibuster,  federalism,  and  policy  feedback  effects. 8.  Including  prevailing  macroeconomic  conditions;  the  level  of  economic  develop¬ ment;  demographic,  class,  sectoral,  and  skill  structures;  the  balance  of  social  forces; the  level  of  economic  openness;  the  international  division  of  labor;  and  the  depen¬ dence  of  the  state  on  globally  mobile  capital. Grappling  with  Globalization  235 9.  Critics  of  “American  exceptionalism”  argue  that  if  socially  oriented  tax  ex¬ penditures  (Howard  2007a;  Howard,  in  this  volume)  and  employer-provided  but government-subsidized  and  regulated  social  benefits  (Hacker  2002)  are  counted  along with  direct  government  spending,  the  United  States  welfare  state  is  actually  compa¬ rable  in  size  to  the  welfare  states  of  Europe.  This  kind  of  concept  “stretching”  makes it  unclear  why  anything  the  government  does  that  affects  social  welfare  should  not  be considered  part  of  the  welfare  state  (Hacker  2005). 10.  On  this  “Lockean  liberalism”  and  its  policy  consequences  see  Kingdon  1999  and Lockhart  2003.  Scholars  of  American  political  development  have  demonstrated  that there  are  actually  “multiple  traditions”  or  elements  within  this  country’s  political  cul¬ ture.  But  as  James  Morone  (2005)  argues,  in  the  narrower  economic  sphere  the  liberal element  is  generally  dominant. In  singling  out  the  importance  of  political  culture  and  mass  public  opinion  in  re¬ straining  the  size  of  the  American  welfare  state,  I  am  reacting  to  analyses  that  neglect these  influences  in  favor  of  other  limiting  factors  like  the  weakness  of  organized  labor or  the  strength  of  business,  racial  divisions  and  the  power  of  southern  Democrats  in Congress,  this  country’s  fragmented  state  and  majoritarian  electoral  institutions,  the economy’s  dependence  on  general  rather  than  specific  skills,  etc.  (see  also  Zelizer  2003 and  Schickler  and  Caughey  2010).  For  three  recent  comparative  studies  of  the  impact of  public  opinion  on  the  welfare  state  see  Mehrtens  2004,  Brooks  and  Manza  2007, and  Kang  and  Powell  2010. 11.  On  parties  and  trade  policy  in  American  history  see  Rattner  1972;  Eckes  1995; Keech  and  Pak  1995;  Destler  2005;  and  Shoch  2001. 12.  This  label  for  moderate  Democrats  in  the  early  1980s  should  not  be  confused with  the  more  general  term  used  above  to  designate  a  form  of  contemporary  conser¬ vatism:  “neoliberalism.” 13.  On  the  development  of  and  the  subsequent  battle  over  Clinton’s  plan  see  Shoch 2008;  Akard  1998;  Weatherford  and  McDonnell  1996;  and  Pierson  1998. 14.  The  Senate  is  generally  more  supportive  of  free  trade  than  the  House  is,  for  a number  of  reasons.  First,  most  senators  represent  fairly  large,  heterogeneous  constitu¬ encies,  including  consumers  and  internationally  oriented  interests,  that  counterbal¬ ance  the  views  of  domestically  oriented  interests  opposed  to  free  trade.  Second,  the Senate  overrepresents  more  agricultural,  less  unionized,  and  therefore  more  pro-trade parts  of  the  country.  Third,  senators  have  long  terms,  giving  ideological  free  traders considerable  leeway  to  resist  pressure  from  protectionist  interests.  Finally,  senators have  broad  foreign  policy  responsibilities  that  incline  them  to  try  to  avoid  trade  con¬ flicts  with  other  nations.  On  the  first  two  of  these  points  see  Wirls  1998. 15.  Labor  unions  donate  almost  all  their  campaign  money  to  Democrats  in  the  hopes of  influencing  which  party  controls  the  House.  Conversely,  some  particularly  ideologi¬ cal  business  interests  give  almost  exclusively  to  Republican  candidates.  But  most  busi¬ nesses  are  pragmatic,  seeking  instead  to  influence  legislative  decision  making,  which leads  them  to  support  incumbents  of  both  parties.  These  same  business  interests  con¬ tribute  additional  money  to  candidates  from  the  party  in  control  of  the  House,  or  ex¬ pected  to  win  control  of  the  House,  as  well  as  to  candidates  of  either  party  who  either 236  Shoch share  or  may  be  induced  to  share  their  positions  on  important  issues.  Consequently,  to some  degree  business  support  for  House  candidates  shifts  with  changes  in  (1)  control of  the  chamber,  either  actual  or  anticipated,  (2)  party  policy  stances,  and  (3)  the  in¬ clination  of  business  donors  to  try  to  induce  such  changes  in  party  positions  (Fellowes and  Wolf  2004;  Stratman  2005). 16.  The  agreement  was  actually  negotiated  by  George  H.  W.  Bush’s  administration. For  four  excellent  analyses  of  the  politics  of  negotiating  and  approving  NAFTA  see Grayson  1995;  Mayer  1998;  Cameron  and  Tomlin  2000;  and  MacArthur  2000. 17.  For  a  lengthy  list  of  mostly  quantitative  analyses  of  the  House  vote  see  Shoch 2001,  344-45- 18.  For  a  much  more  detailed  analysis  of  the  TPA  and  CAFTA  hghts  see  Shoch  2006. 19.  Throughout  the  history  of  the  program,  organized  labor  has  provided  only  weak support  for  TAA,  choosing  instead  to  focus  on  blocking  trade  agreements.  From  hard experience,  labor  knows  that  politicians,  having  secured  the  approval  of  free-trade deals,  have  often  reneged  on  promises  to  deliver  adjustment  aid,  which  in  any  case  is often  ineffective  and  does  little  to  save  union  jobs  (Kapstein  1998;  Burgoon  and  Hiscox 2000;  Burgoon  and  Hiscox  2008;  Davidson,  Matusz,  and  Nelson  2007). 20.  The  CAFTA  countries  included  the  United  States,  El  Salvador,  Guatemala,  Hon¬ duras,  Costa  Rica,  Nicaragua,  and  the  Dominican  Republic. 21.  Toward  this  end,  and  to  preserve  labor  support  for  his  healthcare  reform  effort, in  September  2009  Obama  announced  a  35%  tariff  on  Chinese  tire  imports  and  later imposed  duties  on  Chinese  steel  pipe  imports. 22.  In  which  the  United  States  would  be  joined  by  Australia,  Brunei,  Chile,  New  Zea¬ land,  Peru,  Singapore,  and  Vietnam. 23.  For  the  well-known  argument  that  Americans  are  “ideologically  conservative” but  “operationally  liberal,”  i.e.,  that  they  oppose  government  in  the  abstract  but  sup¬ port  the  maintenance  or  expansion  of  most  specific  government  programs,  see  Cantril and  Cantril  1999.  For  a  review  of  recent  public  opinion  data  on  Americans’  views  of government  taxing  and  spending  see  Shoch  2008. 24.  For  evidence  of  considerable  public  support  for  economic  stimulus  legislation see  PollingReport.com  2009.  Some  polls  did  show  that  the  public  had  concerns  about overspending— concerns  that  would  increase  during  the  battle  over  healthcare  re¬ form— and  preferred  tax  cuts  to  spending  increases  to  boost  the  economy. 25.  TAA  benefits,  previously  reserved  for  manufacturing  workers  displaced  by  trade, were  both  increased  and  extended  to  service-sector  workers  whose  jobs  were  lost  to foreign  imports  or  moved  offshore. 26.  House  Democrats  had  wanted  a  bigger  bill  containing  more  spending  and  smaller tax  cuts,  but  they  were  forced  to  make  concessions  in  conference  to  a  handful  of  mod¬ erate  Senate  Republicans  and  Democrats  whose  support  was  necessary  to  reach  the sixty  votes  required  to  waive  a  budget  point  of  order. 27.  Later  in  the  year  Congress  appropriated  the  funds  for  many  of  these  initiatives. 28.  Of  course  Obama,  continuing  efforts  begun  by  George  W.  Bush,  has  also  spent hundreds  of  billions  of  dollars  to  rescue  the  nation’s  banking  system. Grappling  with  Globalization  237 29.  The  bill  also  shored  up  the  Pell  Grant  student  loan  program  and  allocated  $2  bil¬ lion  for  worker  training  programs  at  the  nation’s  community  colleges. 30.  Adherents  of  the  Varieties  of  Capitalism  theory  (Hall  and  Soskice  2001)  see  little likelihood  of  convergence  or  hybridization  between  what  they  call  “liberal  market economies”  (LMEs)  like  the  United  States  and  the  “coordinated  market  economies” (CMEs)  of  Europe,  because  of  the  presence  within  both  types  of  economies  of  reinforc¬ ing  “institutional  complementarities”  that  prevent  such  change.  I  would  suggest  that more  hybridization  of  different  models  is  possible  than  this  overly  structuralist  theory allows  (Crouch  2005;  Becker  2009;  Campbell  and  Pedersen  2007).  The  structural  and institutional  complexes  characteristic  of  the  two  (or  more)  varieties  of  capitalism  are typically  only  loosely  integrated  and  constraining.  Consequently,  a  number  of  domes¬ tic  political  factors— including  public  opinion,  the  relative  strength  and  influence  of business  and  labor,  party  competition  and  conflict,  and  policymakers’  ideas— can  com¬ bine  in  various  ways  to  produce  a  range  of  economically  viable  policies,  including some  borrowed  from  other  capitalist  models.  Consistent  with  this  view,  Jonas  Pon- tusson  (2005a;  and  chapter  in  this  volume)  argues  that  LMEs  can  adopt  quasi-Nordic social  democratic  policies— for  example  expanded  education,  healthcare,  and  other social  welfare  spending— even  in  the  absence  of  social  democratic  institutions.  But although  LMEs  can  adopt  certain  social  democratic  policies,  domestic  political  factors may  instead  prevent  this.  Thus  Pontusson  argues  as  well  that  without  stronger  unions, it  will  be  very  hard  to  move  American  economic  and  social  policies  in  a  social  demo¬ cratic  direction.  I  will  suggest  below  that  additional  domestic  political  influences  are also  likely  to  block  the  further  growth  of  social  and  public  investment  spending  in  this country. Partlll New  Risks,  New  Challenges,  New  Possibilities European  Center-Left  Parties and  New  Social  Risks Facing  Up  to  New  Policy  Challenges Jane  Jenson European  center-left  parties  and  the  governments  that  they  have  formed  or  in which  they  have  participated  face  a  set  of  social  policy  challenges.  Since  the mid-1990s  they  have  acted  in  an  environment  shaped  by  sociological  and  eco¬ nomic  transformations  that  have  put  paid  to  many  of  the  assumptions  under¬ lying  the  policy  hopes  of  social  democrats  and  the  design  of  social  policy during  the  years  of  postwar  boom.  In  addition,  the  environment  of  these center-lefts  has  been  profoundly  altered  by  the  neoliberal  politics  and  enthu¬ siasm  for  remaking  the  role  of  the  state  that  swept  through  European  soci¬ eties  in  the  1980s  and  first  half  of  the  1990s.  While  not  all  parties  faced  strong and  avowedly  neoliberal  opponents,  all  had  to  live  with  ideological  currents in  their  own  societies  and  international  organizations  that  worked  to  delegiti- mize  some  of  the  most  cherished  post-1945  victories  of  social  democracy. Social  and  economic  transformations  have  generated  what  have  come to  be  called  “new  social  risks.”  Some  changes  are  common  to  all  societies. Population  aging  not  only  results  in  concerns  about  the  sustainability  of  pen¬ sion  systems  but  also  raises  questions  about  social  care.  Who  will,  for  ex¬ ample,  provide— and  pay  for— care  for  the  frail  elderly  as  the  ranks  of  the “oldest  of  the  old”  swell  across  European  societies?  Faced  with  this  ques¬ tion,  most  European  countries  have  instituted  “cash  for  care,”  that  is,  benefits paid  to  elderly  persons  in  need  of  services,  but  the  conditions  of  access  and amounts  vary.  Other  changes  are  more  challenging  for  some  policy  regimes than  others.  Where  the  postwar  settlement  included  a  strict  gender  division of  labor  for  paid  and  unpaid  work,  policy  adaptation  to  declining  male  earn¬ ings  and  rising  numbers  of  single-parent  families  has  been  difficult,  whereas there  is  less  of  a  policy  challenge  around  the  balance  of  work  and  family 242  Jenson where  the  dual-earner  family  has  been  the  norm  for  decades.  Finally,  some policy  choices  made  in  the  years  of  neoliberal  hegemony  have  created  greater stress  than  other  choices  on  social  policy  design.  Where  income-security  poli¬ cies  sustained  attacks  from  neoliberals,  the  rates  of  child  and  family  poverty are  now  much  higher  than  where  income  transfers  were  redesigned  rather than  assaulted.  As  Christopher  Howard  (this  volume)  documents  for  the United  States  — and  the  situation  is  equally  true  for  other  liberal  regimes1 in  Europe  such  as  the  United  Kingdom  and  Ireland— poverty  in  general  and child  poverty  in  particular  remains  very  high  in  international  terms,  and  this despite  significant  policy  attention  to  it  over  the  last  decade.2 The  1990s  saw  an  increase  in  public  social  expenditure  across  Europe,  just as  it  did  in  the  United  States.3  It  is  important  to  emphasize  from  the  beginning that  the  response  to  new  social  risks  cannot  be  assessed  simply  by  examining spending  levels,  which  reveal  little  about  the  composition  of  spending.4  Gov¬ ernments  have  shifted  resources  from  one  policy  area  to  another  and  altered the  mix  of  taxes,  social  transfers,  and  services.  In  general  these  reforms,  even those  promoted  by  center-left  parties  and  governments,  reflect  ideas  about the  role  of  the  state  different  from  those  that  dominated  in  the  years  after 1945.  The  state  was  to  be  responsible  for  “social  investments”  in  human  capi¬ tal-education,  including  early  childhood  education,  and  training— at  least as  much  as  for  social  “protection”  against  the  risks  of  ill-health,  job  loss,  and old  age.5 After  presenting  the  notion  of  new  social  risks  and  the  challenges  they present  in  more  detail,  this  chapter  examines  the  responses  to  them  by  three center-left  parties:  the  Swedish  Social  Democratic  Party,  Britain’s  Labour Party,  and  the  German  Social  Democratic  Party.  All  three  have  recently been  in  government,  and  have  therefore  had  the  opportunity  to  shape  pub¬ lic  policy.  The  chapter  describes  their  initiatives  primarily  as  responses  to “policy  challenges”  rather  than  as  elements  of  political  strategy. The  Policy  Challenge  of  the  New  Social  Risks “Old  social  risks”— aging,  illness,  unemployment,  and  so  on— have  not  dis¬ appeared.  They  remain  both  real  in  people’s  lives  and  on  the  agenda  of  gov¬ ernments.  Nonetheless,  attention  has  also  turned  to  the  risks  resulting  from income  and  service  gaps  in  postindustrial  labor  markets  as  well  as  from  demo¬ graphic  and  social  transformations.  Labor  market  shifts  associated  with  the emergence  of  knowledge-based  as  well  as  service-sector  employment  polar¬ ize  skills  and  earning  capabilities.  Families  with  only  one  income  have  a  sub¬ stantially  higher  risk  of  being  poor.  Yet  transformations  in  family  life  have European  Center-Left  Parties  243 brought  a  significant  increase  in  single-parent  families.  There  has  been  a  de¬ cline  in  the  fertility  rate  and  an  increase  in  life  expectancy.  The  working-age population  and  several  specific  categories,  such  as  single-parent  families  and those  in  need  of  social  care,  are  more  at  risk  of  social  exclusion  as  well  as  of low  income.6 Policy  challenges  are  of  two  broad  types.  One  relates  to  the  means  of  en¬ suring  adequate  income.  If  a  single  wage  supported  several  adults  and  chil¬ dren  fifty  years  ago,  this  is  much  less  true  today,  both  because  of  job  losses  in the  industrial  sector  and  because  of  the  rise  of  the  service  sector,  which  tra¬ ditionally  has  lower-paying  jobs.  More  generally,  the  polarization  of  the  post¬ industrial  income  structure  in  many  countries  has  generated  an  increase  in low-income  rates  among  young  families,  whether  single-parent  or  headed  by couples:  therefore  the  appearance  of  what  has  been  termed  “child  poverty.” These  patterns  are  often  also  concentrated  among  minority  ethnic  groups  and in  cities.  High  unemployment  and  low  employment  rates  also  plague  many economies.  A  second  broad  challenge  is  to  social  care  arrangements.  Across all  types  of  welfare  regimes  there  are  now  serious  contradictions  between  the realities  that  families  face  in  balancing  work  and  family  life  and  the  assump¬ tions  used  when  European  social  protection  systems  were  designed  after 1945.  For  example,  women’s  higher  labor  force  participation  means  reduced availability  for  full-time  family  caring,  while  single-parent  families  have  only one  adult  to  provide  both  income  and  care.  Aging  populations  mean  more frail  elderly  in  need  of  care  and  fewer  family  members  at  home  to  care  for them. Governments  have  reacted  to  the  new  structure  of  risk,  albeit  at  different rates.  One  widely  shared  strategy  is  the  deployment  of  labor  market  policies that  seek  to  foster  labor  force  participation  by  almost  all  working-age  adults. These  often  focus  on  workers  in  declining  sectors,  on  women,  on  youth,  and on  any  category  in  need  of  skills  training  or  updating.  If  active  labor  market policies  (ALMP)  have  been  widely  used  in  Nordic  countries  since  the  1950s (see  Pontusson,  this  volume),  they  are  now  found  in  one  form  or  another  in  all types  of  welfare  regimes,  within  member  states  of  the  European  Union  and  at the  level  of  the  EU  itself.7  As  Tony  Blair  and  Gerhard  Schroder  put  it  in  their manifesto  for  “third  way”  politics  (1999),  “A  welfare  system  that  puts  limits on  an  individual’s  ability  to  find  a  job  must  be  reformed.  Modern  social  demo¬ crats  want  to  transform  the  safety  net  of  entitlements  into  a  springboard  to personal  responsibility.”8 Blair  and  Schroder,  like  many  other  center-left  thinkers,  argued  that achieving  these  ends  would  involve  remodeling  income-transfer  programs. But  they  also  understood  the  need  for  additional  services  for  improving  indi- 244  Jenson □  social  democratic  1999 □  social  democratic  1980 □  corporatist  1 999 □  corporatist  1 980 ■  liberal  1999 □  liberal  1980 Figure  l.  Spending  on  services  for  new  social  risks  as  percentage  of  gross  domestic product  in  EU  countries,  by  type  of  regime  (developed  from  Taylor-Cooby  2004, 16). viduals’  employability  and  for  social  care.  One  example  is  the  call  for  im¬ proved  childcare  services,  including  services  that  pay  attention  to  the  edu¬ cational  and  developmental  needs  of  children,  which  comes  not  only  from advocates  for  gender  equality  and  children’s  rights  but  also  from  long-time proponents  of  labor  market  activation  strategies,  such  as  the  Organisation  for Economic  Cooperation  and  Development  (OECD)  (Mahon  2006). We  can  see  the  results  of  responses  to  new  social  risks.  Across  all  types of  welfare  regimes,  services  have  gained  ground  in  the  expenditure  mix.  As figure  1  documents,  the  numbers  for  1999  are  all  higher  than  those  of  1980. In  addition,  the  classic  cross-regime  patterns  also  continue  to  structure  out¬ comes,  with  levels  of  spending  varying  in  the  usual  way.  They  are  highest  in social  democratic  regimes  and  lowest  in  liberal  ones. Equally  important  is  the  timing  and  content  of  reforms,  as  shown  by  the detailed  case  studies  discussed  here.  The  social  democratic  welfare  regimes altered  several  policy  positions  early  on,  so  that  the  impact  of  new  social risks  was  mitigated  although  not  eliminated  in  the  most  recent  decade.  The continental  European  countries,  in  contrast,  first  reinforced  traditional  male European  Center-Left  Parties  245 breadwinner  models  under  pressure  from  the  social  partners,  but  in  the  last decade  have  recognized  the  significance  of  the  challenges  and  are  under¬ taking  redesign.  The  liberal  regimes,  as  is  their  wont,  relied  on  market  solu¬ tions  to  welfare  problems  and  found  themselves  faced  with  some  severe manifestations  of  the  costs  of  new  social  risks,  especially  in  the  form  of  high rates  of  poverty. Center-Lefts  Respond  to  New  Social  Risks:  Three  Welfare  Regimes Given  these  observations,  this  chapter  concentrates  on  one  case  from  each type  of  welfare  regime:  Sweden  represents  the  social  democratic  type,  Great Britain  the  liberal  type,  and  Germany  the  continental-corporatist  type. A  First  Responder:  New  Social  Risks  and  Sweden Swedish  Social  Democrats:  Platform  2006 Work  for  all  is  the  most  important  goal  for  social  democracy  .  .  . Justice  and  security  are  the  core  values  of  social  democratic  welfare  policy  .  .  . Along  side  these  primary  goals  the  social  democrats  intend  to  carry  through  re¬ forms  in  the  coming  parliament  that  provide  the  basis  for  a  long  term  modernisa¬ tion  of  our  country: 1.  A  competitive  Sweden  with  modern  jobs  .  .  . 2.  Sweden,  a  model  for  the  green  turnaround  .  .  . 3.  The  next  step  in  welfare  policy  involves  dental  care  .  .  . 4.  Sweden  will  be  the  best  of  countries  to  grow  up  in  . . . 5.  Sweden  will  be  the  best  of  countries  in  which  to  grow  old  .  .  . 6.  We  all  gain  from  supporting  each  other.9 If  the  new  social  risks  are  the  result  of  labor  market  restructuring  and  new needs  for  social  care,  Sweden  had  a  response  to  these  risks  well  before  the other  two  countries  examined  in  detail  in  this  chapter.  Indeed  Sweden  had its  own  “third  way”  long  before  other  countries  were  even  thinking  of  one. During  the  heyday  of  international  neoliberalism  the  Social  Democratic  gov¬ ernments  (between  1982  and  1991),  partly  in  response  to  the  drop  in  the employers’  enthusiasm  for  corporatism,  promised  a  middle  route  between Thatcherism  and  Keynesianism  (Ryner  1999,  60).  But  responses  to  new  social risks  predated  even  this  precocious  third  way. Sweden  has  a  long  tradition  of  active  labor  market  policy.  Indeed,  as  Jonas Pontusson  argues  (this  volume),  it  has  been  a  core  ingredient  of  Swedish  social democracy.  Through  the  1990s  thinking  about  Swedish  labor  market  policy 246  Jenson was  shaped  by  principles  put  forth  at  the  end  of  the  1940s  by  the  trade  union economists  Gosta  Rehn  and  Rudolf  Meidner.  For  them  ALMP  was  a  necessary ingredient  in  a  policy  mix  designed  to  combine  low  inflation,  full  employ¬ ment,  and  wage  compression.  Fearing  unemployment  in  low-productivity sectors  that  would  follow  from  anti-inflation  measures,  they  recommended labor  market  retraining  and  other  mobility-enhancing  measures  that  would allow  workers  threatened  by  unemployment  to  transfer  to  high-productivity sectors,  and  thereby  to  relieve  labor  shortages  there.  While  the  original  em¬ phasis  was  on  labor  mobility,  from  the  1960s  through  the  1990s  it  gradually shifted  toward  holding  down  unemployment  in  general  (Calmfors,  Forslund, and  Hemstrom  2002,  3-4). The  anti-unemployment  objective  was  dominant  by  the  1990s,  as  Sweden entered  its  deepest  postwar  recession.  Employment  fell  by  13%  between  1990 and  1994,  and  as  a  result,  placement  of  the  unemployed  in  a  labor  market  pro¬ gram  served  as  the  main  short-run  policy  instrument  to  counteract  the  steep decline.  Enrollment  in  a  program  became  a  mechanism  of  short-term  income security,  filling  the  gap  when  unemployment  benefits  ran  out  and  as  a  means to  regain  entitlements.10  As  we  will  see  below,  exit  from  the  recession  also brought  a  redesign  of  ALMP. Public  provision  of  non-parental  childcare  developed  early  in  Sweden  in comparison  to  many  other  non-Nordic  countries.  By  the  mid-1960s  the  “sex role  debate”  was  roiling  through  the  Social  Democratic  Party  and  the  major labor  federation.11  Led  by  feminists  from  left  and  liberal  circles,  it  divided not  only  left  from  right  but  also  the  forces  of  the  left  itself.  Eventually  reach¬ ing  a  certain  level  of  consensus  by  promising  parents  “choice”  between  work and  care  as  well  as  about  forms  of  non-parental  care  (center-based  or  family daycare),  new  investments  in  services  brought  a  rapid  increase  in  childcare spaces,  from  a  modest  17,900  in  1965  to  224,900  a  decade  later.  In  the  same years  parental  leaves  were  debated  and  introduced.  In  1972  the  Social  Demo¬ cratic  Party  opted  for  paid  parental  leaves,  clearly  rejecting  the  preference of  the  right-wing  parties  and  some  liberal  feminists  for  a  “care  allowance” that  would  subsidize  parental  (stay-at-home  mothers)  as  well  as  non-parental care. This  decision,  which  generated  legislation  two  years  later,  alongside  the commitment  to  public  support  for  non-parental  childcare,  was  decisive  for the  way  that  social  care  has  been  organized  in  Sweden.  Its  continuing  influ¬ ence  shaped  governments’  decisions  over  the  next  decades  to  extend  paren¬ tal  leave  and  childcare  services.  It  also  continues  to  be  shaped  by  the  Social Democratic  Party’s  approach  to  gender  and  employment,  which  is  that  all Swedes  enjoy  “the  right  of  being  both  an  active  parent  and  an  active  gain- European  Center-Left  Parties  247 ful  employee.”12  As  economic  crisis  shook  Sweden  in  the  1990s,  reliance  on these  policy  instruments  to  organize  social  care  were  tested  and  debated  but not  abandoned.  Electoral  losses  by  the  Social  Democrats  brought  a  revival  of the  care  allowance  proposal,  and  the  center-right  government  of  Carl  Bildt introduced  a  “care  wage,”  which  was  intended  to  reimburse  partially  the  “lost wages”  of  parents  who  provided  their  own  childcare.  The  same  government, however,  also  introduced  a  guarantee  of  a  childcare  place  for  any  child  whose parent  wanted  one  (something  the  Social  Democrats  had  talked  about  for  at least  nine  years)  and  a  “father’s  month”  as  an  incentive  to  fathers  to  share parental  leaves.  On  their  return  to  office  in  1994  the  Social  Democrats  re¬ scinded  the  care  allowance,  while  promising  to  institute  a  second  father’s month. Social  care  for  the  elderly  was  launched  on  a  generous  high  road  in  post- 1945  decades,  as  services  and  housing  were  arranged  in  ways  to  maximize  the possibilities  for  the  elderly  to  live  on  their  own,  avoiding  both  residential  care and  dependence  on  their  families,  even  when  their  health  declined  and  their frailties  increased.  These  early  choices  implied  both  improved  housing  and high  levels  of  in-home  services.  Thus  in  the  1970s  studies  found  that  almost 40%  of  Swedes  over  eighty  received  home-help  services,  although  another 30%  were  cared  for  in  institutions  (Sundstrom,  Johansson,  and  Hassing  2002, 351).  In  contrast  to  childcare,  the  high  point  of  coverage  was  reached  in  the 1970s,  and  it  has  declined  since. These  policy  instruments  in  the  domains  of  ALMP  and  social  care  came under  pressure  as  the  new  social  risks  structured  the  circumstances  of  more Swedes.  The  deep  recession  of  the  1990s  and  subsequent  restructuring  hit  sev¬ eral  population  categories  particularly  hard.  The  cutbacks  in  social  spending instituted  at  the  time  were  particularly  costly  for  young  people,  single-parent families,  recently  arrived  immigrants,  and  those  poorly  anchored  in  the  labor market  (Timonen  2004,  85).  Three  responses  will  be  considered  here:  recon¬ figuring  ALMP  policies,  addressing  the  needs  of  the  elderly,  and  investing  in children. Swedish  jobs  rebounded  somewhat  after  the  1990s,  although  not  all  the way  back.  Employment  rates  did  not  return  to  their  previous  highs,  and  de¬ pendence  on  public  income  transfers  did  not  fall  back  to  their  previous  lows (OECD  2007d,  chapter  7).  Precarious  work,  particularly  in  the  form  of  part- time  and  limited-term  contracts,  has  increased,  and  it  affects  women  more than  men.  One  policy  response  has  been  to  provide  better  social  protection  to part-time  workers  with  even  very  short  hours.  The  emphasis  on  lifelong  learn¬ ing  has  also  been  intensified,  with  the  Social  Democrats  proposing  to  create a  new  right  to  obtain  it  in  their  party  program  in  2001. 248  Jenson In  a  classic  reading  of  the  new  social  risks,  the  Swedish  government  also targeted  youth  and  technological  change.  The  “youth  guarantee”  program offers  priority  in  receiving  work,  training,  and  education  to  workers  aged twenty  to  twenty-four,  and  placement  programs  for  youth  were  introduced and  redesigned  in  the  1990s.  Grants  are  also  available  to  employers  who  hire the  older  long-term  unemployed  displaced  by  changing  skill  requirements. Computer  training  centers  and  other  programs  for  new  technologies  were introduced  over  the  1990s.  And  an  “activation  guarantee”  ( aktivitetsgarantie ) was  instituted  in  2000,  targeted  toward  the  long-term  unemployed  but  also those  working  shorter  hours  than  they  wished  (Timonen  2004,  96-97).13 In  the  same  years  awareness  of  population  aging  and  an  expansion  of  the number  of  frail  elderly  led  to  program  adjustments.  The  proportion  of  older persons  receiving  publicly  provided  homecare  has  declined  in  Sweden  in the  last  decades.  A  major  reform  by  the  center-right  government  in  1992  as¬ signed  responsibility  for  both  residential  care  and  home  help  to  municipali¬ ties.  As  the  number  of  elderly  rose  in  Sweden,  municipalities  squeezed  for funds  maintained  their  coverage  rate  in  residential  care  (that  is  the  care  used by  the  most  frail  and  those  without  family  support),  but  homecare  coverage declined.  Whereas  in  1994  68%  of  seniors  living  alone  and  in  need  of  help received  some  homecare  from  the  municipality,  by  2000  that  number  had fallen  to  52%.  The  result  was  that  almost  half  of  frail  seniors  living  alone and  in  need  of  help  with  everyday  living  relied  on  informal  care  from  non¬ cohabiting  family  or  friends.  This  was  a  big  jump  from  the  one-third  who  had found  themselves  in  the  same  situation  a  decade  earlier  (Sundstrom,  Johans¬ son,  and  Hassing  2002,  353).  Better-off  seniors  have  moved  into  the  private market  to  hire  the  help  they  need,  and  poorer  seniors  have  returned  to  reli¬ ance  on  their  families.  There  are  also  labor  shortages  in  the  social  care  field. Poor  working  conditions  and  better  job  prospects  drain  workers  to  other  sec¬ tors.  Municipalities,  responsible  for  providing  all  public  homecare  services, face  severe  labor  shortages  (Timonen  2004,  89-92).  These  issues  were  ad¬ dressed  in  the  party  platforms  and  program  of  the  current  decade;  as  noted in  the  passage  quoted  above,  the  Social  Democrats  promised  to  make  Sweden “the  best  country  in  which  to  grow  old.”  Yet  in  party  documents  attention  to children  and  youth  far  outpaces  that  going  to  the  elderly.14  Significant  gaps remain  between  needs  and  available  services.  With  regard  to  these  new  social risks,  Sweden  is  falling  behind  in  comparison  to  its  earlier  record.15 Single-parent  families  constitute  a  paradigmatic  location  for  new  social risks.  In  Sweden  the  needs  of  this  type  of  family  have  always  been  dealt  with through  standard  labor  market  instruments  as  well  as  by  providing  generous family  benefits  to  all  families.  In  other  words,  mothers  raising  children  alone have  always  been  expected  to  be  employed,  and  they  have  received  the  same European  Center-Left  Parties  249 family  benefits  as  families  headed  by  couples.  In  addition,  the  state  guaran¬ tees  a  small  monthly  child  maintenance  payment  if  the  non-custodial  parent does  not  make  his  or  her  child  support  payments. Child  poverty  has  become  an  increasingly  important  topic  in  policy  circles, and  Sweden’s  single-parent  families  have  not  escaped  the  scourge  (Kamer- man,  Neuman,  Waldfogel,  and  Brooks- Gunn  2003,  6).  In  its  pathbreaking study  of  child  poverty  in  rich  countries,  UNICEF  identified  single  parent¬ hood  as  the  overwhelmingly  important  factor  in  Swedish  child  poverty.  Al¬ though  Sweden  has  by  far  the  lowest  rate  of  child  poverty  overall  (only  2.6% of  children  live  in  poverty  after  taxes  and  transfers  are  considered),  the  rate among  single-parent  families,  which  in  Sweden  are  numerous,  was  almost five  times  greater  than  that  of  two-parent  families  (UNICEF  2000,  17,  10).16 Policy  changes  have  been  proposed,  such  as  replacing  the  housing  allowances by  a  more  generous  income  transfer.  This  proposal  has  been  opposed  quite widely,  however.  Therefore  action  falls  back  on  the  traditional  strategy,  and labor  market  policies  are  used  to  try  to  increase  the  employment  of  lone  par¬ ents  (Hallerod  2007,  26).  Here  performance  lags.  While  Sweden  is  a  strong performer  in  UNICEF’s  general  “child  poverty  league  tables,”  it  is  only  in the  middle-performing  group  with  respect  to  rates  of  workless  households, many  of  which  are  likely  to  be  headed  by  one  adult  (UNICEF  2000, 17).  These poor  performance  indicators  result  from  the  basic  new  social  risk,  which is  the  intransigence  of  new  labor  market  structures  in  which  young  people in  particular  have  so  many  difficulties  finding  employment,  and  especially good  jobs. Yet  overall,  much  less  attention  is  now  paid  to  families  than  to  children. This  is  a  shift  from  the  golden  age  of  Swedish  social  democracy,  when  gener¬ ous  parental  leaves  and  accessible  childcare  of  high  quality  were  promoted as  policy  instruments  to  achieve  gender  equality  within  the  family  and  so¬ ciety.  “[For]  the  development  of  pervasive,  high  quality  and  affordable  pub¬ lic  childcare  in  Sweden,  starting  in  the  1960s  .  .  .  one  motivation  was  just  to allow  gender  equality  in  practice,  by  allowing  women  both  to  have  children and  to  stay  in  employment  and  develop  careers.  Three  particular  landmarks are  the  1976  law  requiring  municipalities  to  draw  up  ten  year  childcare  ex¬ pansion  plans,  the  1985  law  giving  all  children  aged  eighteen  months  to  seven years,  with  working  or  studying  parents,  or  with  special  needs,  a  place  in  pub¬ lic  childcare  by  1991,  and  the  1995  law  making  it  obligatory  for  municipalities to  provide  childcare  on  demand.  The  Family  Policy  Committee’s  1972  Report also  recommended  buttressing  the  gender  equity  effects  of  the  public  child¬ care  system  by  transforming  maternity  leave  into  a  much  longer  and  gender- neutral  parental  leave,  subsequently  introduced  in  1974”  (Ahlberg,  Roman, and  Duncan  2008,  83). 250  Jenson It  was  only  with  the  reform  of  1995  that  access  to  childcare  was  clearly separated  from  parental  labor  market  status.  This  was  a  turning  point  toward the  child-centered  social  investment  strategy  that  is  now  so  prevalent.17  This emphasis  has  been  dominant  for  a  decade  now,  shown  by  a  simple  quantita¬ tive  indicator.  The  Social  Democrats’  election  manifesto  of  2006  mentioned families  twice,  parents  twice,  and  children  twenty-five  times.  Children  had become  the  focus  of  policy  interventions  for  combating  poverty,  achieving equality,  and  ensuring  the  future.  The  Social  Democrats’  program  of  2001 had  also  devoted  an  extraordinary  amount  of  attention  to  children.  Thus  the promise  cited  above  that  “Sweden  would  be  the  best  of  countries  to  grow up  in”  translated  into  promises  to  invest  in  services  for  children  because,  as the  manifesto  put  it,  “the  choices  made  by  children  today  will  determine  the future  of  Sweden.”  Children  have  become  actors  in  their  own  right,  and  hold the  future  of  the  country  in  their  little  hands! This  shift  to  an  emphasis  on  new  social  risks  has  not  been  without  oppo¬ sition.  Trade  unions  and  pensioners  have  used  their  solid  organizational strength  to  defend  earnings-related  benefits  and  to  launch  campaigns  to  re¬ store  cuts  to  unemployment  insurance.  Nonetheless,  new  coalitions  have  also emerged,  led  by  church  and  community-based  groups,  which  present  some¬ thing  of  a  challenge  to  the  long-standing  organization  of  Swedish  politics around  producer  groups.  These  new  coalitions  promote  the  rights  and  advo¬ cate  for  the  needs  of  groups  such  as  immigrants  and  the  working  poor  who have  been  most  touched  by  the  new  social  risks  (Timonen  2004, 105).  There¬ fore  the  full  political  consequences  of  the  Swedish  response  to  new  social risks  remain  to  be  assessed. Great  Britain:  New  Labour  Focuses  on  Child  Poverty  and  Social  Investment In  our  third  term  we  will  make  public  services  safe  for  a  generation.  No  going  back to  one-size-fits-all  monolithic  services.  No  going  back  to  the  Tory  years  of  cuts  and privatisation.  Going  forward  instead  to  services  free  to  all,  personal  to  each:  break¬ ing  once  and  for  all  the  dropout  culture  in  education  and  the  waiting-list  culture  in health,  by  raising  investment  and  driving  innovation  through  diversity  of  provision and  power  in  the  hands  of  the  patient,  the  parent  and  the  citizen. In  our  third  term  we  will  cement  a  new  social  contract  with  rights  matched  by responsibilities.  No  going  back  to  “no  such  thing  as  society.”  Going  forward  instead to  power  and  resources  in  the  hands  of  the  law-abiding  majority.  A  government committed  both  to  abolishing  child  poverty  and  to  putting  the  values  of  individual responsibility  and  duty  at  the  very  heart  of  policy. —Labour  Party  Manifesto  2005 European  Center-Left  Parties  251 The  British  center-left  provides  a  classic  example  of  a  liberal  welfare  state’s response  to  the  new  social  risks.  Out  of  power  for  a  decade  and  a  half  while Margaret  Thatcher’s  Conservative  Party  reshaped  the  social  as  well  as  eco¬ nomic  landscape,  Labour  had  ample  time  to  reflect  on  ways  to  transform itself  into  New  Labour.  Eventually  the  social  policy  spotlight  was  shifted  to new  social  risks,  particularly  worklessness  and  child  poverty,  and  solutions were  framed  in  terms  of  social  investments.18 In  the  1990s  unemployment  was  high  in  the  United  Kingdom,  as  industrial restructuring  slashed  jobs  from  traditional  industrial  sectors  and  the  service sector  did  not  provide  sufficient  replacements.  The  recession  at  the  beginning of  the  decade  was  severe,  such  that  in  1994  21%  of  men  aged  fifteen  to  twenty- four  and  14%  of  women  were  unemployed.  Rates  of  economic  inactivity  were rising,  and  at  14.2%  of  all  households,  the  rate  of  those  that  had  no  one  in employment  (that  is,  “workless”  households)  was  the  second-highest  of  the EU-15  (Taylor-Gooby  and  Larsen  2004,  58). In  large  part  because  of  this  statistic,  in  a  liberal  welfare  regime  with little  in  the  way  of  family  benefits  (in  contrast  to  Sweden,  for  example), child  poverty  was  also  very  high.  Indeed  “a  fifth  of  Britain’s  children  lived in  poverty  in  the  1990s,  a  rate  more  than  twice  as  high  as  in  France  or  the Netherlands  and  five  times  higher  than  in  Norway  or  Sweden. .  .  .  And  while child  poverty  has  remained  stable  or  risen  only  slightly  in  most  industrial nations  over  the  last  20  years  [that  is  the  1980s  and  1990s],  it  tripled  in  Brit¬ ain”  (UNICEF  2000,  21).  The  poverty  rate  was  particularly  high  among  single¬ parent  families,  in  which  the  employment  rate  was  significantly  lower  than elsewhere:  47%  as  compared  to  59%  across  the  EU  as  a  whole  (Taylor-Gooby and  Larsen  2004,  58). Given  these  patterns  and  under  the  pressure  of  successive  electoral  fail¬ ures,  the  Labour  leader  John  Smith  established  the  Commission  on  Social Justice  (CSJ)  in  1992  to  mark  the  fiftieth  anniversary  of  the  Beveridge  Report, which  underpinned  the  design  of  much  British  social  policy  after  1945.  While rejecting  any  return  to  past  policy  habits,  the  commission’s  report  called  for, among  other  things,  more  “investments.”  This  was  a  language  that  clearly  dis¬ tinguished  it  from  the  Conservatives’  continuing  reliance  on  the  neoliberal goal  of  reducing  the  role  of  the  state  by  cutting  back.  For  example,  “invest¬ ing  in  skills,  we  raise  people’s  capacity  to  add  value  to  the  economy,  to  take charge  of  their  own  lives,  and  to  contribute  to  their  families  and  communi¬ ties”  (CSJ  1994, 119-20).  The  report  set  out  an  argument  for  the  advantages  of spending  on  employability  programs  rather  than  welfare,  on  lifelong  learning and  on  work  for  all.  It  made  the  point  too  that  social  justice  is  “an  economic not  merely  a  social  necessity.”  The  report  also  promoted  concentrating  on 252  Jenson children  for  social  investment:  “the  investment  we  make  in  babies  and  young children  is  wholly  inadequate”;  “children  are  not  a  private  pleasure  or  a  per¬ sonal  burden;  they  are  too  percent  of  the  nation’s  future  . . .  the  best  indicator of  the  capacity  of  our  economy  tomorrow  is  the  quality  of  our  children  today” (CSJ  1994,  122,  311).  Finally,  it  concluded  that  “the  best  way  to  help  the  one in  three  children  growing  up  in  poverty  is  to  help  their  parents  get  jobs”  (CSJ 1994,  313). Chosen  as  Labour’s  leader  after  Smith’s  early  death,  Tony  Blair  rarely  ac¬ knowledged  directly  any  debt  to  the  CSJ.  Yet  the  commission,  housed  in  the Institute  for  Public  Policy  Research  (IPPR),  showed  a  skill  for  finding  the middle  ground  within  a  divided  party  that  identified  a  path  for  New  Labour when  it  took  office.  Drafted  by  one  of  New  Labour’s  rising  stars,  David  Mili¬ band,  the  commission’s  principles  underpin  the  key  values  enunciated  by Blair  for  New  Labour.  Reducing  child  poverty  became  one  of  the  big  policy ideas  of  the  Labour  government,  and  in  1999  Blair  pledged  to  end  it  in  a  gen¬ eration.  For  his  part,  Gordon  Brown  was  in  full  agreement:  “Our  children  are our  future,  and  the  most  important  investment  we  can  make  as  a  nation  is  in developing  the  potential  of  all  our  country’s  children.  Together  we  can  en¬ sure  that  no  child  is  left  behind”  (H.M.  Treasury  2001,  iii-iv).  Child  poverty, and  the  use  of  various  benefits  and  services  to  lower  the  rate,  were  a  major theme  in  Treasury  documents  for  the  decade  before  Brown  succeeded  Blair as  Labour’s  leader.  When  he  took  over  as  prime  minister  on  28  June  2007, one  of  his  three  new  creations  was  the  Department  of  Children,  Schools  and Families.19 In  contrast  to  the  story  of  the  Swedish  Social  Democratic  Party,  New Labour’s  is  one  of  significant  policy  shifts  in  the  mid-1990s  (see  Cronin,  this volume).  Whereas  the  Swedish  Social  Democrats  could  adjust  to  the  eco¬ nomic  crisis  of  the  1990s  and  the  rise  of  new  social  risks  by  fine-tuning  exist¬ ing  policies  and  programs  such  as  parental  leave,  childcare,  and  homecare, New  Labour  struck  out  on  new  paths  in  several  policy  areas.  In  doing  so  it did  not  abandon  its  standard  approach  to  designing  policy  within  a  liberal welfare  regime  (much  of  which  had  been  built  by  “old”  Labour  after  1945).  It remained  true  to  the  long-standing  preference  for  market  solutions  to  welfare problems,  using  instruments  of  income  transfer  and  services  targeted  to  the most  in  need.  Nonetheless  new  programs  were  invented  so  as  “to  make  work pay,”  with  several  built  on  work  subsidies  for  families,  in  contrast  to  the  pre¬ vious  Conservative  governments  (Seeleib-Kaiser  and  Fleckenstein  2007,  430). In  this  way  the  focus  on  investing  in  children  and  ending  child  poverty came  together  in  several  initiatives  with  the  issues  of  employment  and  com¬ bating  worklessness.  New  Labour’s  commitment  to  increasing  access  to  em- European  Center-Left  Parties  253 ployment  came  in  the  form  of  several  New  Deals.  “New  Deal  policies  provided intensive  training  and  work  preparation  programmes  and  slightly  enhanced rates  of  benefit,  and  were  targeted  on  specific  groups  of  those  out  of  work, most  prominently  young  people  and  lone  parents”  (Taylor-Gooby  and  Larsen 2004,  68).  The  election  manifesto  of  1997  had  promised  that  250,000  young people  would  be  moved  into  work  by  the  next  election,  and  the  New  Deal  for Lone  Parents  set  a  target  of  70%  in  work  by  2010.  Additional  New  Deals  were then  added  for  partners  of  the  unemployed  (in  effect  women),  persons  with disabilities,  those  over  age  fifty,  and  the  long-term  unemployed.  The  pro¬ grams  for  youth  and  the  long-term  unemployed  were  effectively  workfare schemes,  participation  being  compulsory  in  order  to  claim  benefits  (Taylor- Gooby  and  Larsen  2004,  69).  The  other  programs  were  voluntary. Learning  has  been  a  constant  theme  in  international  discussions  of  em¬ ployability  and  was  at  the  core  of  New  Labour’s  approach  to  new  social  risks too.  The  green  paper  The  Learning  Age:  A  Renaissance  for  a  New  Britain  (1998) encouraged  workers  to  invest  in  their  own  training  and  learning  throughout their  lives,  with  some  financial  support  from  the  state.  Spending  on  learn¬ ing  would  be  an  arm  in  the  fight  against  childhood  poverty,  helping  parents to  upgrade  skills  and  to  ensure  that  children  did  not  follow  their  parents along  the  low-skill  road.  Improving  skills  was  closely  linked  to  welfare  re¬ form.  For  example,  single  parents  were  targeted  in  the  strategy  Skills  for  Life, and  basic  skills  counseling  became  part  of  their  New  Deal  (Dobrowolsky  and Jenson,  2005).  While  the  New  Deals  offered  some  basic  skill  training,  the major  focus  in  this  strand  of  the  analysis  is  on  learning  by  children.  “The  seed of  inequality  in  adulthood  is  denial  of  opportunity  in  childhood.  Education is  the  most  important  transmission  mechanism  — people  with  few  skills  and qualifications  are  much  less  likely  to  succeed  in  the  labour  market”  (H.M. Treasury  1999,  7).  Thus  the  “skills  agenda”  would  include  a  heavy  dose  of  in¬ vestment  in  schooling. Because  Britain  is  a  liberal  welfare  state,  albeit  a  “modernizing”  one,  New Labour  in  its  responses  to  the  new  social  risks  demonstrated  a  continuing preference  for  market  solutions.  Three  kinds  of  important  programs  work  at the  margin  of  markets.  The  first  set  of  programs  was  designed  to  “make  work pay,”  and  they  operated  at  the  margins  of  the  labor  market.  These  were  of three  types:  increases  in  the  minimum  wage;  policies  holding  down  benefits for  those  out  of  work,  to  increase  their  incentives  to  seek  work;  and  supple¬ ments  to  earned  incomes. With  respect  to  linkages  between  unemployment  programs  and  ALMP, Clasen  and  Clegg  describe  Britain  as  being  no  less  forceful  than  Denmark  in coordinating  access  to  benefits  and  policy  institutions,  represented,  for  ex- 254  Jenson ample,  by  the  Jobcentres  Plus  that  deal  with  both  the  unemployed  and  those in  receipt  of  social  assistance  benefits.  This  effort  to  create  a  single  point  of entry  is  part  of  “the  transition  of  UK  labour  market  policy  from  an  emphasis on  unemployment  to  an  increasing  emphasis  on  ‘worklessness’”  (Clasen  and Clegg  2006,  204).  In  large  part  the  accent  has  been  on  reduced  access  to  un¬ employment  insurance,  job  searching,  and  some  training,  as  noted  above  re¬ garding  the  various  New  Deals. The  redesign  and  enrichment  of  benefits  for  the  low-income  employed  and their  families  came  in  the  form  of  various  tax  credits  and  benefits,  some  tar¬ geting  low-income  workers  and  some  intended  to  help  families  with  children. The  Child  Benefit  and  the  Child  Tax  Benefit  are  available  to  adults  caring for  children,  the  latter  being  income-tested.  In  addition,  some  non-parental childcare  costs  are  addressed  by  the  Working  Tax  Credit.  In  other  words, much  of  the  redesigned  social  spending  is  work-tested,  child-tested,  or  both. New  Labour’s  Manifesto  (2005)  promised  that  “tailored  help,  especially  for lone  parents,  is  key,  but  we  are  also  committed  to  making  work  pay— with  a guaranteed  income  of  at  least  £258  per  week  for  those  with  children  and  in full-time  work.” A  second  type  of  child-oriented  program  stressed  improving  access  to childcare.  Again  the  goal  was  market-shaping.  Over  the  years  of  Labour  gov¬ ernment  childcare  has  always  been  treated  as  a  support  for  working  parents.20 On  this  issue  the  British  government  continued  to  be  much  less  convinced  than many  other  countries  are  that  educational  care  of  high  quality— and  more than  part-time  nursery  school  — is  good  for  all  children  (Mahon  2006).  New Labour  always  had  clear  ideas  about  the  needs  of  children  who  are  at  risk  of suffering  from  childhood  poverty:  they  need  superior  publicly  supported  ser¬ vices  to  compensate  for  disadvantages  at  home.  Sure  Start,  a  neighborhood- based  program  targeting  disadvantaged  children,  was  the  expression  of  this prong  of  the  National  Childcare  Strategy  launched  in  1997.  For  the  rest,  how¬ ever,  the  government  continued  to  promise  parental  “choice.”  It  preferred  to “rely  on  private  mechanisms  through  the  expansion  of  childcare  tax  credits rather  than  the  development  of  public  childcare  facilities”  (Daguerre  2006, 222). Third,  New  Labour  innovated  with  a  policy  instrument  for  providing  mar¬ ket  access:  asset  building.  Not  long  after  the  election  of  2002  Blair  described his  vision  of  welfare  reform.  In  a  speech  he  saved  his  greatest  enthusiasm  and his  most  upbeat  description  of  the  future  for  one  idea:  “But  if  we  are  serious about  transforming  the  welfare  state,  our  strategy  has  to  be  about  more  than helping  people  into  work  and  relieving  poverty.  To  enable  people  to  be  inde¬ pendent  and  make  their  own  choices,  they  need  the  back-up  of  having  some European  Center-Left  Parties  255 savings  in  the  bank  or  a  nest-egg.  Money  put  aside  changes  your  horizons. It  makes  you  plan,  brings  responsibility,  offers  protection  and  opportunity. And  I  want  to  ensure  that  those  on  lower  incomes— and  the  next  generation  — can  share  those  advantages”  (Blair  2002). Such  notions  about  the  wide  range  of  benefits  from  fostering  savings  and the  acquisition  of  assets  are  the  purest  expression  of  the  social  investment perspective.  The  Treasury  had  already  been  working  on  the  idea,  floated  in the  white  paper  Savings  and  Assets  for  All  (2001).  In  presenting  the  white paper,  Gordon  Brown  suggested  that  the  initiatives  had  the  potential  of  “cre¬ ating  a  democracy  where  wealth  ownership  is  genuinely  open  to  all,”  and  the first  policy  experiment  was  with  the  Child  Trust  Fund,  a  long-term  savings and  investment  account.  The  government  provides  a  lump  sum  to  each  child, and  the  package  includes  financial  education  for  children,  intended  to  create the  “saving  culture.” New  Labour  clearly  responded  to  the  new  social  risks.  In  doing  so  it  ar¬ rived  at  rhetorical  flourishes  not  all  that  different  from  those  of  the  Swedish Social  Democrats.  Recalling  the  promise  in  2005  that  “Sweden  will  be  the best  of  countries  to  grow  up  in,”  Labour’s  Children’s  Plan  (2007)  opens  with the  statement:  “By  2020  we  want  England  to  be  the  best  place  in  the  world  to grow  up.”21  In  contrast  to  both  Sweden  and,  as  we  will  see,  Germany,  much less  attention  has  gone  to  the  needs  of  the  frail  elderly.22 In  postwar  social  policy,  services  for  the  frail  elderly  were  provided  by local  authorities  based  on  need  and  means  testing.  Under  pressure  from  the disability  rights  movement,  made  up  primarily  of  young  activists  who  pro¬ moted  independent  living  for  the  disabled,  and  seduced  by  the  cost-control promises  of  in-home  rather  than  residential  care  as  well  as  by  the  discourses of  “choice”  so  dear  to  neoliberalism,  the  Conservatives  instituted  a  series  of measures  to  enable  care  services  in  the  home  (Ungerson  and  Yeandle  eds. 2007,  5, 188).  In  1996  this  basket  of  policies  was  expanded  to  include  “cash- for-care,”  or  direct  payments  to  the  disabled  to  allow  them  to  assemble  a  care package  themselves.  Persons  over  sixty-five  were  excluded  from  this  program until  2000,  when  the  Labour  government  extended  access  to  them,  so  that they  could  also  receive  direct  payments  in  order  to  put  together  their  pre¬ ferred  care  packages  (Ungerson  and  Yeandle  eds.  2007, 115.)  The  benefits  are needs  tested  and  scaled  to  financial  resources  (LeBihan  and  Martin  2006,  42). Still,  participation  in  the  payments-for-care  program  remains  low,  and  Brit¬ ain  does  not  shine  internationally  as  a  provider  of  care  services  for  the  frail elderly. Instead,  and  in  line  with  its  driving  theme  of  “social  investment,”  the Labour  Party  in  office  concentrated  on  increasing  employment  through 256  Jenson activation  strategies  and  programs  of  human  capital  (from  the  early  years through  post-secondary  education).  Adults  and  their  needs  for  training  and retraining  were  a  preoccupation,  though  one  often  justified  as  a  means  to ending  child  poverty,  and  in  particular  to  increasing  the  employment  rates  of single  parents.  In  contrast  to  Sweden,  and  somewhat  unexpectedly  for  such  a pure  case  of  the  social  investment  thematic,  parents  have  not  lost  their  place as  policy  targets.  They  remain  linked  to  their  children,  who  have  become nonetheless  political  actors:  “Children  cannot  be  the  forgotten  constituency of  politics;  parents  put  their  children  first  and  they  deserve  support  from  gov¬ ernment”  (Labour  Party  Manifesto  2005,  79). Germany:  Rethinking  the  Risk  Structure Our  aim  is  to  pursue  a  holistic  policy  for  families,  senior  citizens,  women  and  youth which  promotes  and  reinforces  solidarity  between  the  generations  and  therefore  of society  as  a  whole.  We  want  to  encourage  families  to  have  more  children,  and  we want  a  stronger  role  for  the  family  in  society.  We  want  to  make  it  clear  that  without children,  Germany  has  no  future. —Coalition  Agreement  2005 Any  analysis  of  the  center-left’s  response  to  new  social  risks  in  Germany  must take  into  account  the  strong  structuring  effects  of  previous  policy  choices, many  of  them  initiated  by  left  governments  or  grand  coalitions  in  which  the Social  Democrats  played  a  key  role.  As  a  policy  process  in  which  corporatist political  relations  as  well  as  Bismarckian  social  insurance  policy  regimes  have played  a  key  role,  the  emphasis  in  studies  of  the  German  case  is  often  on  sta¬ bility  and  blockages  to  change.  Nonetheless,  like  other  European  countries Germany  has  experienced  major  changes  in  labor  markets  as  well  as  in  family and  employment  policy  in  the  last  decade.  These  reforms  have  been  often  in¬ stituted  by  the  Social  Democratic  Party  (SPD)  in  power,  either  in  coalition with  the  Greens  or,  after  2005,  with  the  Christian  Democratic  Union  (CDU) and  others  in  the  Grand  Coalition.  One  dimension  of  these  changes  has  been  a solid  focus  on  demography,  which  has  been  shaping  much  social  policy  (thus the  choice  of  quotation  above). In  confronting  one  of  the  new  social  risks  — social  care  for  the  frail  elderly— Germany  was  an  early  innovator,  though  the  innovations  relied  on  the  tradi¬ tional  policy  instruments  of  social  insurance.  In  1994  the  government,  led  by the  CDU,  instituted  long-term  care  insurance,  a  proposal  which  had  also  been pushed  by  the  SPD  (Morel  2006,  233-34).  In  addition  to  relieving  fiscal  pres¬ sures  in  government  finances,  the  goal  of  the  new  program  was  to  promote European  Center-Left  Parties  257 family-based  care  by  recognizing  and  subsidizing  it  (Ungerson  and  Yeandle eds.  2007, 138-39)-  Thus  even  in  this  innovation  the  difficulties  that  Germany has  faced  in  moving  away  from  the  male  breadwinner  model,  enshrined  in  so much  of  the  German  social  architecture  after  1945,  are  evident.  But  much  of the  deadlock  has  been  recently  removed  by  the  actions  of  the  current  Grand Coalition  government,  headed  by  Angela  Merkel  since  November  2005. With  a  traditionally  strong  industrial  sector,  highly  regulated  labor  mar¬ kets,  and  low  rates  of  women’s  employment,  Germany  has  had  an  employment structure  characterized  by  a  large  proportion  of  permanent,  full-time  em¬ ployment.  Nonetheless  the  industrial  sector  has  shrunk,  women  have  entered the  labor  market,  and  non-standard  employment— particularly  part-time  em¬ ployment— has  increased.  The  result  has  been  more  “mini-jobs,”  low-skill  em¬ ployment,  and  working  poor  (Aust  and  Bonker  2004,  33-34).  These  changes have  not  gone  unnoticed,  of  course,  and  they  have  been  vigorously  debated for  two  decades  now.  The  controversy  has  turned  on  two  issues:  atypical  em¬ ployment  and  adjustments  to  the  welfare  state.23  The  center-left  and  trade unions  were  on  the  side  of  protecting  long-term  employment  and  opposed plans  by  Helmut  Kohl’s  right-wing  government  to  deemphasize  fixed-term employment  and  accept  even  more  mini-jobs.  The  consequences  singled  out for  attention  by  the  center-left  were  those  for  pensions  in  particular.  With  re¬ gard  to  the  low-skilled,  a  lively  debate  within  policy  communities  turned  on whether  to  “make  work  pay”  by  supplementing  (subsidizing)  the  earnings  of low-waged  jobs.  Opposed  by  unions  and  some  academic  economists  and  sup¬ ported  by  others,  the  center-left  government  after  1998  contented  itself  with a  few  pilot  projects.  The  third  prong  of  debate  about  labor  market  policy  has been  the  interface  between  unemployment  insurance  and  social  assistance, with  the  center-left  proposing  a  “modernized”  welfare  state  that  promotes activation  (Seeleib-Kaiser  and  Fleckenstein  2007,  437). Despite  opposition  from  trade  unions  and  state  and  local  governments, the  second  government  led  by  Schroder  adopted  measures  that  added  up “to  a  substantial  transformation  of  German  labour  market  policy”  (Aust  and Bonker  2004,  46).  Among  these  were  “job  centers”  modeled  on  Britain’s  one- stop  locations  for  job  seekers  (Seeleib-Kaiser  and  Fleckenstein  2007,  431-32). Social  assistance  and  unemployment  benefits  were  merged  for  many  without jobs,  thereby  reducing  the  pool  of  unemployed  who  could  count  on  replace¬ ment  income;  they  received  a  much  less  generous  benefit,  similar  in  amount to  the  earlier  social  assistance  rates.24  One  result  was  to  widen  the  cleavage between  insiders  with  jobs  or  full  insurance  benefits  and  the  rest,  whose  ac¬ cess  was  to  means-tested  unemployment  or  job-seeking  assistance.  Nonethe¬ less,  full-scale  activation  efforts  of  the  Danish  or  British  type  were  applied 258  Jenson only  to  the  unemployed  under  twenty-five.  Social  Democrats’  hopes  to  do more  were  hampered  by  the  constitutional  division  of  powers,  which  assigns responsibility  for  “active”  and  “passive”  measures  to  different  levels  of  gov¬ ernment  (Clasen  and  Clegg  2006,  202). In  large  part  these  policy  stances  adopted  by  the  center-left  reflect  a  long¬ term  process  of  change  in  party  philosophy.  “Although  intellectually  the  So¬ cial  Democrats  had  recognised  the  limits  of  Keynesian  policies  in  the  mid- 1970s,  they  more  or  less  continued  to  follow  the  traditional  Social  Democratic policy  path  in  terms  of  economic  and  employment  policies  until  the  mid- 1990s”  (Seeleib-Kaiser,  van  Dyk,  and  Roggenkamp  2005,  21).  Thus  change dates  from  the  second  half  of  the  1990s,  just  as  in  Britain.  By  1998  the  Social Democrats  (and  the  Greens)  were  campaigning  on  the  position  that  deficit- financed  economic  stimulation  was  impossible  and  social  insurance  contribu¬ tions  (the  heart  of  a  Bismarckian  welfare  regime)  had  to  be  limited,  all  to  stay competitive  in  the  global  economy.  The  market  was  also  rehabilitated  as  a social  mechanism.  As  Blair’s  and  Schroder’s  Third  Way  manifesto  of  1999  put it,  “we  need  to  apply  our  politics  within  a  new  economic  framework,  mod¬ ernised  for  today,  where  government  does  all  it  can  to  support  enterprise  but never  believes  it  is  a  substitute  for  enterprise.  The  essential  function  of  mar¬ kets  must  be  complemented  and  improved  by  political  action,  not  hampered by  it.  We  support  a  market  economy,  not  a  market  society.”25 If  change  has  been  slow  but  steady  with  respect  to  the  new  social  risks  of low-wage  work  and  unemployment,  the  same  is  now  less  true  of  social  care, both  for  the  elderly  and  children.  In  both  cases,  though,  it  has  been  gov¬ ernments  led  by  Christian  Democrats  that  have  brought  about  the  most  far- reaching  reform. In  the  Federal  Republic  of  Germany  the  risk  of  long-term  care  until  the 1990s  was  covered  by  a  means-tested  social  assistance  program  of  last  re¬ sort  and  was  a  local  government  responsibility.  But  local  authorities  found  it increasingly  difficult  to  meet  rising  demand,  and  they  turned  to  the  central government  to  take  responsibility  for  care  of  the  frail  elderly.  There  was  also, as  we  have  noted,  some  earlier  mobilization  for  such  a  program  by  the  Social Democrats.  The  Care  Insurance  Act  (1994)  is  a  compulsory  insurance  regime that  provides  basic  benefits  to  those  in  need  of  care,  as  assessed  by  an  expert team  that  includes  doctors,  nurses,  and  social  workers.  Benefits  may  be  used in  conjunction  with  personal  resources  or  social  assistance  and  may  be  taken in  cash  or  in  services.  The  incentive  structure  of  the  program  is  to  increase  re¬ liance  on  home  care  and  informal  care.  The  recipient  has  full  control  over  its disbursement.26  The  universal  insurance  scheme  covers  approximately  90% of  the  population  (Morel  2006,  234). European  Center-Left  Parties  259 The  focus  in  the  German  scheme,  in  contrast  to  those  of  some  Nordic  coun¬ tries  (Jenson  and  Jacobzone  2000),  was  intended  to  satisfy  the  needs  of  the frail  elderly,  and  much  less  attention  was  paid  to  informal  caregivers  (mostly female  family  members).  While  informal  caregivers  do  receive  some  social security  rights,  the  recipients’  preference  is  by  far  for  in-home  care  (71%)  and within  that  for  cash  benefits  (73%)  rather  than  formal  services  (Morel  2006, 243).  This  means  that  the  domestic  economy  of  benefit  sharing  remains  pri¬ vate  and  unknown. Family  policy  is  the  other  area  of  major  change  in  Germany,  which  is finally  moving  away  from  the  male  breadwinner  model  and  toward  accept¬ ing  the  need  for  public  intervention  to  ensure  better  reconciliation  of  work and  family.  Until  well  into  the  1990s  policy  design  had  favored  stay-at-home parents.  A  childcare  allowance  provided  extended  benefits  to  parents— read mothers— who  remained  out  of  the  labor  force  for  three  years.  The  lack  of non-parental  childcare  for  infants  and  toddlers  as  well  as  school  days  that ended  very  early  made  it  difficult  to  combine  work  and  parenting  even  when children  were  of  school  age.  The  tax  system  penalized  a  move  from  part-time to  full-time  work  (Gottfried  and  O’Reilly  2002,  44-45).  Overall  Germany  was characterized  by  both  low  rates  of  female  labor  force  participation  and  the third-lowest  fertility  rate  in  the  EU-15. In  the  election  that  brought  the  Red-Green  coalition  led  by  Gerhard  Schro¬ der  to  office  in  1998,  three  of  the  four  main  themes  in  the  SPD  party  platform had  to  do  with  macroeconomic  and  labor  market  policy;  the  fourth  was  im¬ proving  family  policies  (Seeleib-Kaiser  and  Fleckenstein,  2007,  437).  Parental leave  was  significantly  reshaped  in  2001  so  as  to  increase  flexibility.  Both  par¬ ents  may  take  leave.  They  may  do  so  at  the  same  time,  or  they  may  split  the leave  in  different  combinations  and  at  different  times,  until  the  child  turns eight.  Parents  also  gained  the  right  to  work  part-time  during  the  first  two  years after  a  child’s  birth.  A  second  wave  of  reform  in  2005  introduced  an  earnings- related  parental  benefit,  providing  a  standard  period  of  twelve  months  and 67%  of  the  previous  net  income  of  the  parent  taking  leave  (capped  at  €1,800/ month).  By  including  two  months  of  paid  benefits  with  a  “use  it  or  lose  it” provision,  the  design  provides  clear  encouragement  for  the  second  parent (read  fathers)  to  take  some  leave  (Daly  and  Seeleib-Kaiser  2008,  5). For  a  number  of  years  the  Social  Democrats  had  advocated  better  supply  of childcare,  a  stance  in  line  with  their  preference  for  providing  services  rather than  simply  income  transfers  (Huster,  Benz,  and  Boeckh  2008,  20).  The  Day Care  Development  Act  of  2005  required  municipalities  to  provide  a  childcare space  for  all  children  under  the  age  of  three  whose  parents  were  in  work  or in  education  or  training.  Then  the  Grand  Coalition  government  in  the  spring 260  Jenson of  2007  promised  to  increase  publicly  financed  or  subsidized  care  to  fully meet  demand  by  2013.  That  year  as  well  was  targeted  for  introduction  of  an individual  entitlement  to  childcare  for  every  child.  In  other  words  the  male breadwinner  model  had  tumbled,  and  Germany’s  childcare  guarantee  mimics that  of  the  child-centered  Swedish  model. Short  but  well-paid  parental  leaves  and  generous  childcare  provision  rep¬ resent  responses  to  new  social  risks.  Much  more  than  in  Sweden  or  Britain, the  German  responses  have  been  driven  by  fear  of  risk  of  declining  fertility, as  a  report  to  the  European  Union  on  child  poverty  clearly  reveals:  “Under the  guiding  idea  that  Germany  needs  ‘more  children  in  the  families  and  more families  in  society,’  the  federal  government  identifies  three  priorities  with  re¬ gard  to  children,  youths  and  families  for  the  current  legislative  period  (2005- 2009):  support  of  young  parents  during  the  family  formation  phase  (see  the Day  Care  Development  Act  and  the  new  Parental  Benefit  Act),  strengthen¬ ing  the  bond  between  the  generations  (see  the  new  federal  model  program ‘multigeneration  facilities’),  and  more  attention  to  be  paid  to  children  ‘born on  the  dark  side  of  life’  (meaning  children  who  grow  up  under  difficult  social and  economic  conditions)”  (Huster,  Benz,  and  Boeckh  2008,  18).  Many  ana¬ lysts  attribute  the  demographic  challenge  in  Germany  directly  to  the  long¬ standing  commitment  in  social  policy  design  to  the  male  breadwinner  model and  lack  of  attention  until  recently  to  reconciling  work  and  family.  Families were  forced  to  choose  between  having  two  incomes  and  having  children. THESE  THREE  PATTERNS  of  response  by  center-lefts  to  new  social  risks,  par¬ ticularly  family  poverty  and  labor  market  exclusion,  have  been  generated  by the  parties’  understanding  of  the  new  social  risks  and  their  sometimes  enthu¬ siastic,  sometimes  reluctant  embrace  of  the  proposition  that  modernization of  social  policy  is  necessary.  The  second  half  of  the  1990s  was  a  key  moment for  all  three  parties,  and  indeed  almost  all  European  center-left  parties.  The harsh  recession  at  the  beginning  of  the  decade  and  the  political  space  offered by  stumbling  right-wing  governments  provided  an  opening  for  proclaiming their  commitment  to  modernization.  Sometimes  the  announcement  was  dra¬ matic,  as  in  Britain  when  Tony  Blair  declared  that  New  Labour  had  arrived, or  when  he  and  Gerhard  Schroder  trumpeted  their  manifesto  for  a  third  way. Sometimes  the  rhetoric  was  more  restrained,  as  center-left  parties  in  Sweden and  Germany  attempted  to  reassure  their  long-time  constituents  and  part¬ ners,  especially  in  the  unions,  that  change  was  necessary  to  maintain  com¬ mitments  to  long-standing  values. There  was  therefore  a  political  imperative  to  “modernize.”  But  just  as European  Center-Left  Parties  261 pressing  was  the  policy  challenge  arising  from  recognition  of  the  new  social risks  themselves.  There  was,  it  must  be  said,  no  significant  political  mobiliza¬ tion  by  those  most  affected  by  the  new  social  risks.27  Rather,  sensitivity  to  the challenges  came  primarily  from  within  social  policy  bureaucracies  and  the policy  experts  affiliated  with  center-left  parties.  What  was  to  be  done  about the  costs  as  well  as  the  dwindling  supply  of  social  care?  With  women’s  em¬ ployment  essential  to  the  modern  service  economy  as  well  as  an  imperative of  contemporary  social  relations,  who  would  look  after  young  children  and the  swelling  ranks  of  the  frail  elderly?  How  could  more  working-age  adults be  brought  into  employment,  and  which  activation  models  worked  best? This  chapter  has  documented  that  in  most  cases  answers  to  these  questions were  found  within  initial  policy  trajectories  structured  by  left  politics  during the  trente  glorieuses.  While  it  is  hard  to  account  for  the  responses  to  new  social risks  as  the  result  of  contemporary  mobilization  by  the  elderly,  parents,  or  the poor,  it  is  easy  to  see  how  the  politics  of  the  “old  left”  of  the  years  since  1945 continues  to  influence  the  ways  the  new  social  risks  are  addressed.  Choices about  benefits  and  services  frequently  echoed  those  made  in  the  1950s  and 1960s,  in  terms  of  generosity  as  well  as  policy  design.  Swedish  Social  Demo¬ crats’  early  response  to  what  were  “old  risks”  of  labor  market  shortages  and the  need  to  encourage  higher  female  employment  rates  helped  to  keep  down some  of  the  indicators  of  costly  new  social  risks,  because  parental  leaves  and childcare  services  were  already  in  place.  Nonetheless  the  traditional  solu¬ tion  of  a  job  for  everyone  is  less  effective  these  days,  as  Sweden  struggles with  poverty  and  joblessness  among  single-parent  families  as  well  as  young people.  This  problem  is  rising  in  importance  and  seems  intractable  to  classic solutions.  It  blots  the  Swedish  copybook,  as  does  the  foot  dragging  on  care for  the  frail  elderly.  New  Labour  too  continues  its  residualist  tradition,  with public  programs  filling  gaps  left  by  market  failures  for  those  at  the  margins of  society.  By  dint  of  harping  on  social  investments,  New  Labour  managed to  make  a  dent  in  child  poverty,  although  many  of  the  structural  patterns  of the  new  social  risks  — such  as  low  wages  and  youth  exclusion  — remained  in place.  No  more  than  the  Swedish  Social  Democrats  had  New  Labour  found “the”  solution  to  the  new  social  risks. One  of  the  three  cases  does  provide  significant  novelty.  The  German  So¬ cial  Democrats  stonewalled  before  directly  addressing  the  new  social  risks, caught  as  they  were  between  their  allies,  their  own  ideology,  and  an  im¬ ploding  Bismarckian  insurance-based  regime.  The  result  today  is  that  first the  Red-Green  governments  and  now  the  Grand  Coalition  in  which  the  So¬ cial  Democrats  participate  have  abandoned  some  of  the  fundamental  prin- 262  Jenson ciples  of  the  post-1945  model  concerning  the  male  breadwinner  family  or  the insurance-based  provision  of  rights  and  benefits.  Regarding  the  male  bread¬ winner  model,  German  family  policy  has  drawn  close  to  that  of  the  social democrats.  As  for  insurance-based  rights  and  benefits,  the  movement  seems to  be  in  the  direction  of  solutions  favored  by  liberal  welfare  regimes  and  away from  earned  entitlements  (Palier  2010).  Center-lefts’  responses  to  new  social risks,  in  other  words,  may  lead  them  down  roads  first  mapped  in  the  heyday of  social  democracy,  but  may  also  take  them  over  quite  unfamiliar  terrain. Notes 1.  This  chapter  relies  on  the  widely  used  concept  of  “welfare  regime,”  first  devel¬ oped  by  Gosta  Esping-Andersen  (1990).  The  United  States  as  well  as  most  of  the  other English-speaking  countries  fall  into  the  liberal  category,  while  the  Nordic  countries  are classified  as  social  democratic,  and  most  of  the  continental  European  ones  as  corporat- ist,  sometimes  termed  Bismarckian. 2.  UNICEF  2007,  6,  found  that  the  ranking  of  children  living  in  poverty  in  twenty- one  countries  placed  the  United  States  dead  last,  the  United  Kingdom  second  from  the bottom,  and  Ireland  in  eighteenth  place. 3.  See  the  data  reported  by  Howard  (this  volume)  as  well  as  the  comparison  of twenty-one  OECD  countries  in  Castles  (2005,  table  1,  416). 4.  Even  more  problematic  is  that  they  mask  an  increasing  reliance  on  policy  instru¬ ments  such  as  negative  income  taxes  and  “tax  breaks  for  social  purposes.” 5.  “Social  protection”  is  the  European  term  used  to  encompass  everything  from health  to  pensions,  unemployment  benefits,  social  assistance  (“welfare”  in  American English),  employment  support  and  protections,  maternity  and  parental  benefits,  and family  allowances. 6.  For  studies  relying  on  these  definitions  see  Esping-Andersen,  Gallie,  Hemerijk, and  Myles  2002;  Jenson  2004;  Bonoli  2005;  and  Bonoli  2006. 7.  Goldhammer  and  Ross  (this  volume)  describe,  for  example,  French  labor  mar¬ ket  activation  policies,  and  Cronin  (this  volume)  does  the  same  for  Britain.  Ross (this  volume)  considers  labor  market  policies  in  the  EU.  In  their  manifesto  Europe: The  Third  Way  (1999)  Tony  Blair  and  Gerhard  Schroder  included  a  chapter  entitled “An  Active  Labour  Market  Policy  for  the  Left”  (on  http:yywww.socialdemocrats.org/ blairandschroeder6-8-99.html,  consulted  15  July  2008). 8.  The  content  and  implications  of  this  manifesto  for  a  “third  way”  are  discussed  in detail  in  Green-Pedersen,  van  Kersbergen,  and  Hemerijk  2001  and  Seeleib-Kaiser  and Fleckenstein  2007,  438. 9.  All  the  documents  of  the  Swedish  Social  Democratic  Party  referred  to  here  are available  at  http: //www.socialdemokraterna.se/Internationellt/Other-languages. 10.  “An  important  side  objective  of  Swedish  active  labour  market  policy  has  always been  to  mitigate  the  moral  hazard  problems  of  a  generous  unemployment  insurance: European  Center-Left  Parties  263 by  making  payment  of  unemployment  compensation  conditional  on  accepting  regu¬ lar  job  offers  or  placement  offers  in  ALMPs  from  the  public  employment  offices,  active labour  market  policy  has  been  used  as  a  work  test  for  the  recipients  of  unemployment compensation”  (Calmfors,  Forslund,  and  Hemstrom  2002,  4). 11.  The  analysis  and  details  in  the  next  two  paragraphs  are  from  Daune-Richard  and Mahon  2001. 12.  Party  Program  of  the  Social  Democratic  Party,  adopted  by  the  Party  Congress  in Vasteras,  6  November  2001, 15. 13.  For  the  long  list  of  programs  over  time  see  Calmfors,  Forslund,  and  Hemstrom 2002,  5-7. 14.  Alongside  two  mentions  of  the  “elderly”  in  SAP’s  program  of  2001  were  thirty- two  going  to  children. 15.  Because  of  the  more  generous  benefits  available  in  the  “golden  age”  of  its  welfare regime,  Sweden  remains  an  example  of  a  country  in  which  access  to  services  is  still higher  than,  for  example,  in  southern  Europe  or  Britain  (LeBihan  and  Martin  2006, 45). 16.  According  to  UNICEF  (2000),  21%  of  Swedish  children  live  with  one  parent,  the highest  rate  among  the  twenty-two  countries  it  studied  (the  United  States  was  at  16%). 17.  Drawing  on  Esping-Andersen,  Gallie,  Hemerijk,  and  Myers  (2002),  Pontusson (this  volume)  identifies  this  child-centered  social  investment  strategy  as  a  core  ele¬ ment  of  the  current  social  democratic  project.  It  is  worth  noting,  however,  that  a  policy focus  on  “investing  in  children”  appeared  in  the  mid-1990s  in  liberal  welfare  regimes as  well  (Jenson  and  Saint-Martin  2006). 18.  In  addition  to  the  specific  sources  mentioned  in  this  section,  much  of  the  analy¬ sis  is  from  Dobrowolsky  and  Jenson  2005. 19.  On  his  prime  ministerial  website  the  emphasis  on  children  was  clear:  “Mr  Brown sums  his  own  beliefs  up  as:  ‘Every  child  should  have  the  best  start  in  life,  that  every¬ body  should  have  the  chance  of  a  job,  that  nobody  should  be  brought  up  suffering  in poverty.  I  would  call  them  the  beliefs  that  you  associate  with  civilisation  and  dignity.’” http://www.numbeno.gov.uk/output/Page12037.asp,  consulted  17  July  2008. 20.  For  example,  in  the  party’s  manifesto  (2005),  consideration  of  childcare  is  con¬ centrated  in  the  chapter  “Families:  Support  at  Work  and  at  Home.” 21.  This  document  is  “The  Children’s  Plan.  Building  Brighter  Futures”  (December 2007),  available  from  the  Stationery  Office  and  on  http://www.dfes.gov.uk/publica tions/childrensplan/,  consulted  19  July  2008.  The  quote  is  on  page  15. 22.  The  election  manifesto  of  2001,  for  example,  did  mention  the  need  to  support caregivers,  but  the  overwhelming  focus  on  the  needs  of  the  elderly  was  with  regard  to pensions  and  income.  The  balance  in  the  manifestos  of  1997  and  2005  was  the  same. 23.  The  rest  of  this  paragraph  is  from  Aust  and  Bonker  2004,  42. 24.  These  reforms,  known  as  Hartz  IV,  created  a  basic  benefit  which  provides  low- end  security  for  jobseekers  and  the  long-term  unemployed.  The  changes  are  described and  explained  by  Seeleib-Kaiser  and  Fleckenstein  (2007)  as  the  product  of  direct  in¬ fluence  of  British  policy  ideas  and  policy  imitation. 264  Jenson 25.  See  “Europe:  The  Third  Way”  on  http^www.socialdemocrats.org/blairand schroeder6-8-99.html,  consulted  15  July  2008. 26.  For  further  details  see  Jenson  and  Jacobzone  2000  and  Ungerson  and  Yeandle eds.  2007, 137-47. 27.  This  seeming  political  puzzle  is  identified  by  Bonoli  (2005,  433). Immigration  and  the  European  Left Sofia  A.  Perez In  altering  the  population  of  a  state,  immigration  has  consequences  for  many of  the  conditions  that  center-left  governments  have  historically  sought  to  ad¬ dress.  Employment  and  competition  in  the  labor  market,  the  promotion  of skills,  and  the  achievement  of  greater  income  equality  in  a  society  are  all likely  to  be  affected  by  the  arrival  of  a  significant  number  of  newcomers. Focusing  on  Western  Europe,  an  area  that  has  become  a  key  destination  for migrants  from  around  the  world  in  the  past  three  decades,  this  chapter  con¬ siders  how  center-left  governments  have  responded  to  the  political  pressures created  by  large  scale  international  migration  since  the  cold  war.  It  is  hypothe¬ sized  that  the  left  faces  distinct  political  dilemmas  in  dealing  with  immigra¬ tion,  dilemmas  that  reflect  a  potential  conflict  at  the  electoral  level  between the  universalistic  values  that  represent  the  left’s  main  ideological  appeal  and its  commitment  to  promote  the  interests  of  some  of  its  core  domestic  con¬ stituencies.  The  move  to  restrict  immigration  in  Europe  during  the  last  three decades,  often  under  governments  of  the  left,  seems  to  lend  support  to  this hypothesis.  However,  as  will  be  discussed,  the  policies  toward  immigration under  governments  of  the  center-left  in  Europe  have  also  varied  substantially across  countries,  suggesting  that  the  intensity  of  those  electoral  dilemmas may  depend  on  other  factors,  such  as  the  structure  of  national  economies  and the  characteristics  of  different  European  welfare  states. We  begin  with  a  discussion  of  the  particular  political  dilemmas  that  im¬ migration  presents  for  the  left  and  then  go  on  to  a  brief  description  of  the major  trends  in  the  historical  evolution  of  immigration  in  Europe  over  the last  three  decades.  These  trends  can  be  linked  to  the  three  phenomena  em¬ phasized  in  this  volume:  the  end  of  rapid  post-war  economic  growth  during the  1970s,  the  end  of  the  cold  war,  and  the  intensification  of  globalization. Based  on  cross-country  quantitative  data,  we  find  that,  on  average  govern- 266  Perez ments  of  the  left  have  been  at  least  as  likely  to  restrict  immigration  in  Europe as  governments  of  the  right.  Nevertheless,  we  see  very  significant  differences across  countries,  with  center-left  governments  in  some  countries  pursuing very  expansive  immigration  policies  while  in  others  they  have  opted  clearly to  pursue  policies  that  restrict  immigration  in  practice.  In  the  following  pages we  explore  how  the  left,  when  in  government,  has  responded  to  the  phe¬ nomenon  of  large  scale  migration  from  outside  the  EU  in  four  of  the  Union’s largest  member  states:  Germany,  the  United  Kingdom,  Italy,  and  Spain.  One common  trend  that  we  see  across  these  countries  is  that  center-left  govern¬ ments  have  sought  to  recast  the  immigration  debate  by  altering  the  bases on  which  foreigners  are  admitted  to  fit  other  national  economic  objectives, such  as  economic  growth  and  the  promotion  of  better  skills.  They  have  often counted  on  segments  of  businesss  as  an  ally  in  this  effort.  Yet  in  some  coun¬ tries  (notably  Germany  among  our  cases)  they  have  encountered  significant opposition  from  within  their  own  ranks  and  ample  segments  of  the  elector¬ ate,  while  in  others  they  have  pursued  very  expansive  immigration  policies. The  chapter  concludes  by  offering  a  possible  explanation  for  these  differences in  immigration  policy  and  considers  what  they  tell  us  about  the  wider  impli¬ cations  of  immigration  for  the  European  left. Immigration  and  Left  Partisanship Unlike  other  aspects  of  globalization  such  as  financial  integration,  trade  com¬ petition,  and  the  rise  of  the  service  economy,  immigration  is  rarely  consid¬ ered  an  issue  with  clear  partisan  implications.  Setting  aside  an  important literature  on  the  rise  of  the  new  radical  right  (e.g.,  Betz  1993;  Kitschelt  with McGann  1995),  scholarship  on  the  politics  of  immigration  in  Europe  has tended  to  emphasize  factors  that  apply  equally  across  party  lines.  Based  on her  influential  study  of  France  and  Britain,  Jeannette  Money,  for  instance,  has argued  that  immigration  is  primarily  a  matter  of  local  politics,  proposing  an “electoral  geography”  perspective  according  to  which  governments  of  what¬ ever  ideology  will  opt  to  curtail  immigration  whenever  electoral  districts  in which  native  citizens  compete  economically  with  immigrants  for  jobs  and public  resources  become  crucial  to  the  outcome  of  national  elections  (Money 1999).  One  implication  that  can  be  taken  from  her  findings  is  that  immigra¬ tion  is  fundamentally  neutral  from  a  partisan  perspective,  with  the  exception of  its  possible  contribution  to  the  rise  of  the  radical  right.  Other  authors  have further  added  to  this  view  by  noting  that  early  efforts  to  restrict  immigra¬ tion  in  Europe  during  the  1960s  and  1970s  were  promoted  with  equal  inten¬ sity  by  politicians  of  both  left  and  right.  Thus  Schain  (2006)  has  documented Immigration  and  the  European  Left  267 how  Communist  Party  politicians  in  France  were  among  the  first  to  promote efforts  to  restrict  immigration,  and  Karapin  (1999)  points  to  anti-immigrant popular  mobilization  in  key  electoral  districts  in  Britain  and  Germany  to  ex¬ plain  the  decision  by  governments  of  both  left  and  right  to  restrict  immigra¬ tion  laws  from  the  1960s  on. To  observe  that  both  left  and  right  governments  have  pushed  for  restrict¬ ing  immigration  in  Europe,  or  for  that  matter  that  immigration  preferences tend  to  be  specific  to  locality,  does  not  obviate  the  possibility  that  parties of  the  left  and  of  the  mainstream  right  face  fundamentally  different  politi¬ cal  dilemmas  in  deciding  upon  policies  involving  immigration.  Indeed,  while arguments  in  defense  of  the  rights  of  immigrants  are  commonly  associated with  the  left,  there  are  at  least  two  reasons  to  believe  that  immigration  cre¬ ates  particular  electoral  difficulties  for  the  left  and  hence  that  governments of  the  left  have  particular  incentives  to  restrict  immigration.  The  first  reason is  that  immigration  has  different  economic  impacts  on  different  segments  of the  electorate  upon  which  the  left  relies.  As  a  number  of  political  economists have  pointed  out,  the  costs  and  benefits  of  immigration  accrue  unequally  to different  income  segments  of  the  population.  Immigration  tends  to  weaken the  labor  market  position  of  native  low-skilled  workers  while  improving  that of  high-skilled  workers  and  professionals  whose  labor  productivity  and  cost of  living  are  improved  by  a  larger  supply  of  low-skilled  and  low-wage  workers (Scheve  and  Slaughter  2001).  Given  that  low-skilled  workers  also  represent the  prime  beneficiaries  of  publicly  subsidized  housing,  healthcare,  and  edu¬ cation,  and  that  they  are  more  likely  to  find  themselves  living  in  proximity  to low-skilled  immigrants,  competition  in  jobs  carries  over  to  competition  over such  public  resources  and  space.  To  the  extent  that  voters  view  immigration in  terms  of  their  rational  economic  self-interest  and  that  parties  of  the  left must  put  together  an  electoral  coalition  spanning  low-skilled  workers,  high- skilled  workers,  and  professionals,  the  left  is  likely  to  face  an  electoral  trade¬ off  over  immigration.  Moreover  other  economic  trends,  such  as  the  rise  of  the service  economy  and  associated  efforts  to  make  labor  markets  more  flexible (for  instance  the  recent  Hartz  reforms  in  Germany)  are  likely  to  aggravate these  electoral  trade-offs  by  reducing  traditional  forms  of  labor  market  secu¬ rity  for  the  working  class  in  Europe. In  addition  to  the  division  over  immigration  policy  that  derives  from  the differing  labor  market  positions  of  the  center-left’s  potential  electorate,  po¬ litical  economists  also  postulate  another  way  in  which  immigration  can  be expected  to  represent  a  particular  problem  for  parties  of  the  left.  To  the  extent that  the  immigration  of  low-skilled  workers  (the  primary  recipients  of  social transfers)  changes  the  income  distribution  so  as  to  push  former  recipients  up 268  Perez the  relative  income  scale  (turning  them  into  median  voters),  the  preference of  the  median  voter  may  well  move  toward  lower  spending  levels  (Nannestad 2007).  If  so,  immigration  would  represent  a  serious  threat  to  the  ability  of  the center-left  to  protect  the  European  welfare  state,  and  with  it  a  centerpiece  of its  raison  d’etre. While  economists  suggest  that  immigration  is  likely  to  divide  the  center- left’s  electorate  along  skill  and  income  levels,  these  economic  issues  appear to  divide  the  population  of  advanced  industrialized  countries  along  the  same lines  as  the  cultural  cleavage  between  left-libertarian  and  authoritarian- populist  values  which  appears  to  have  emerged  as  a  major  feature  of  the electoral  space  in  which  center-left  parties  now  operate  (Kitschelt  1994;  Kit- schelt  with  McGann  1995).  As  Kitschelt’s  work  suggests,  labor  market  differ¬ ences  such  as  the  new  multiplicity  of  work  experiences  among  the  left’s  elec¬ torate  (with  male,  manual  workers  threatened  by  globalization  tending  to fall  in  the  new  authoritarian  camp  and  professionals  with  higher  educational levels  and  communicative  skills  tending  toward  the  left-libertarian  camp) may  translate  into  other  issues  of  cultural  identity  and  definition.  The  effect may  be  to  harden  antagonistic  worldviews  among  the  electorate  to  the  point of  rendering  the  actual  individual  economic  impact  of  immigration  a  second¬ ary  matter.  This  cultural-identitarian  dimension  of  immigration  cannot  be eluded  by  the  left  because  any  choice  to  restrict  immigration  (or  the  rights  of immigrants)  in  order  to  address  the  impact  on  native  workers  requires  some implicit  or  explicit  justification  for  limiting  social  solidarity  based  on  iden¬ tity.  Resort  to  such  justification  may  undermine  the  perceived  ideological  co¬ herence  of  the  left,  thus  threatening  one  of  its  key  tools  in  mobilizing  voters: the  appeal  to  universal  values.  At  the  very  least,  it  is  likely  to  alienate  the left-libertarian  segment  of  the  center-left’s  electorate,  contributing  to  parti¬ san  schisms  such  as  that  between  Social  Democrats  and  Greens  in  Germany or  between  the  Socialist  Party  and  alternative  left  candidacies  seen  in  recent French  presidential  elections.1 Both  economic  analyses  pointing  to  how  immigration  affects  different  sets of  voters  and  cultural  analyses  of  the  attitudinal  trends  characterizing  Euro¬ pean  electorates  in  the  post-Fordist  period  thus  suggest  that  the  European left  is  likely  to  face  considerable  problems  in  defining  its  stance  on  immigra¬ tion  in  the  electoral  space  in  which  it  operates.  Given  the  possible  tensions  in immigration  policy  preferences  among  the  center-left’s  electorate,  how  have center-left  parties  in  practice  addressed  the  question  of  immigration  and  im¬ migration  policy  in  Europe  in  the  last  decades? Immigration  and  the  European  Left  269 Immigration  and  the  Left  in  Europe:  A  Brief  Periodization Setting  aside  migratory  moves  due  to  postwar  expulsions,  the  history  of  post¬ war  immigration  in  Europe  can  be  divided  broadly  into  four  periods.  The  first, lasting  from  the  1950s  to  the  economic  crisis  of  1973,  saw  significant  levels  of immigration  into  the  richer  states  of  Western  Europe  through  guest  worker recruitment  programs  designed  to  alleviate  labor  shortages  and  Britain’s  and France’s  preferential  treatment  of  former  colonial  subjects.  The  second  period was  marked  by  the  abrupt  ending  of  active  worker  recruitment  schemes  and the  curtailment  of  lax  citizenship  provisions  for  former  colonial  subjects  (the latter  starting  in  Britain  in  the  early  1960s).  This  left  only  two  modalities  of immigration  into  most  states  of  Western  Europe— family  reunification  and asylum  laws— which  were  often  defended  by  courts  and  public  administra¬ tions  in  the  face  of  government  efforts  to  move  to  a  de  facto  goal  of  zero  im¬ migration.  The  third  period,  beginning  roughly  with  the  end  of  the  cold  war in  1989,  was  marked  by  sharp  increases  in  immigration  through  those  two remaining  avenues.  It  would  end  a  decade  later  with  a  radical  toughening  of asylum  laws  across  the  EU.  Led  by  Germany,  EU-15  member  states  rescinded their  acceptance  of  asylum  petitions  for  those  arriving  through  a  “safe  third country”  (a  condition  that  applied  to  virtually  all  arrivals  into  the  EU-15  by land  and  many  by  air).  Family  reunification  criteria  were  also  toughened  by several  countries  (including  Germany),  resulting  in  very  low  net  immigra¬ tion,  or  even  a  decline  in  the  immigrant  population  in  many  countries.  The most  recent  period  has  also  been  marked  by  the  “securitization”  of  immigra¬ tion  policy  following  the  September  11  attacks  and  a  new  emphasis  on  bor¬ der  control  in  the  face  of  new,  more  organized  forms  of  illegal  immigration through  EU’s  southern  and  eastern  borders. However,  as  figure  1  makes  clear,  the  move  to  restrict  immigration  since 1989  has  not  been  uniform  across  Western  Europe.  Some  countries,  includ¬ ing  most  strikingly  Britain,  Spain,  and  Italy,  experienced  very  large  inflows  of immigrants  from  outside  the  EU  until  the  world  financial  crisis  in  2007.2  In¬ deed,  the  EU-15  area  as  a  whole  is  estimated  to  have  seen  an  increase  of  new residents  from  outside  the  area. What  role,  if  any,  have  parties  of  the  left  had  in  this  recent  history  of  im¬ migration  in  Europe  and  in  the  divergence  we  observe  in  the  decades  preced¬ ing  the  economic  crisis?  Considering  the  question  from  a  historical  perspec¬ tive,  the  first  observation  is  that  early  postwar  immigration  regimes  across Western  Europe  did  not  seem  to  have  had  any  particularly  partisan  charac¬ ter.  Work-based  immigration,  or  “guest-worker,”  programs  that  represented the  main  avenue  for  immigration  into  the  richer  states  of  continental  Europe 270  Perez Figure  l.  Number  of  foreign  residents  by  country,  1989-2006  (figures  from  Eurostat). during  the  1950s  and  1960s  were  instituted  by  Christian  Democrats  in  Ger¬ many  and  the  Netherlands,  by  Gaullists  in  France,  and  by  Social  Democrats in  Sweden  (Toro-Morn  2004).  They  were  designed  to  recruit  labor  tempo¬ rarily  without  offering  a  path  to  citizenship,  and  social  democratic  parties and  labor  unions  alike  were  willing  to  go  along  with  this  notion  of  recruiting foreign  workers  who  would  not  enjoy  full  social  and  political  rights.  On  the other  hand,  in  Britain  both  Labour  and  Conservative  governments  supported generous  access  for  former  British  colonial  subjects  without  tying  it  to  work until  1962  (see  Hansen  1999).  And  in  France,  where  the  left  remained  out  of office  throughout  this  period,  governments  dominated  by  the  center-right embraced  a  similarly  generous  policy  toward  former  colonial  subjects  from North  Africa. At  the  time  of  the  oil  shocks  of  the  1970s,  the  left  was  in  a  preeminent position  across  much  of  Europe.  Social  democratic  governments  in  Sweden, Germany,  and  the  Netherlands  took  the  lead  in  ending  worker  recruitment schemes,  often  in  direct  response  to  pressure  from  labor  unions.3  Meanwhile, British  Labour  governments  took  measures  to  further  tighten  the  restrictions on  Commonwealth  immigration  that  had  first  been  introduced  by  the  Conser¬ vatives  in  1962.4  Indeed,  in  the  period  after  the  oil  shock  immigration  policy across  most  of  Western  Europe  seemed  to  reflect  a  new  consensus  between center-left  and  mainstream  right  parties  to  stop  the  influx  of  foreigners  and the  transformation  of  European  societies  in  a  multicultural  direction.  No  less an  internationalist  than  Willy  Brandt  would  declare  in  January  1973  that  it had  “become  necessary  to  think  carefully  about  when  our  society’s  ability  to take  up  [foreigners]  is  exhausted,  and  when  sense  and  responsibility  require Immigration  and  the  European  Left  271 a  halt.”5  With  the  exception  of  Britain,  the  consensus  was  reflected  in  what appears  in  hindsight  to  have  been  an  unspoken  agreement  between  main¬ stream  left  and  right  to  end  work-based  immigration  but  not  to  politicize  the broader  question  of  Europe’s  increasingly  multicultural  character  as  a  result of  past  immigration.  In  many  parts  of  Europe,  from  France  to  Austria  and Denmark,  this  modus  vivendi  was  eventually  challenged  by  the  electoral  rise of  anti-immigrant  parties  in  the  1980s,  which  led  sections  of  the  mainstream right  to  call  for  restrictions  on  immigrant  rights,  often  in  the  language  of  law and  order  (France’s  “Peyrefitte  law”  of  1981  and  the  “Pasqua  laws”  of  1986 and  1993  are  prime  examples).  In  other  places— notably  Germany— the  un¬ spoken  agreement  appeared  to  hold  until  the  asylum  crisis  of  the  early  1990s. The  sharp  rise  in  asylum  seekers  that  followed  the  outbreak  of  conflict  in the  Balkans  as  the  cold  war  came  to  an  end  posed  a  challenge  particularly  to the  European  left.  Many  of  its  historic  leaders  regarded  the  right  to  asylum  as a  key  guarantee  against  the  kind  of  political  persecution  experienced  during fascism.  As  a  consequence,  in  places  such  as  France  and  Germany  left  party politicians  often  sided  with  courts  that  blocked  early  restrictions  imposed  by governments  of  the  right.  In  the  end,  however,  the  combined  pressure  of  anti¬ immigrant  popular  mobilization  and  increased  politicizing  of  the  issue  by the  radical  and  later  mainstream  right  led  center-left  governments  to  accept a  radical  curtailment  of  asylum  rights,  first  in  France  during  the  1980s,  then in  Germany  in  1993,  then  in  Germany’s  neighbor  states.  In  2005  the  German principle  of  rejecting  asylum  seekers  who  had  passed  through  a  safe  third country  was  finally  adopted  as  the  common  guideline  of  EU  member  states. To  be  sure,  asylum  was  the  most  wrenching  issue  for  parties  of  the  left  in Europe.  Yet  the  record  suggests  that  in  practice,  if  not  in  discourse,  the  leader¬ ship  of  left  parties  in  many  European  states  also  seconded  a  stance,  most  often enunciated  by  politicians  on  the  right,  of  restricting  net  immigration  to  zero. Starting  in  the  1990s  many  European  governments  toughened  requirements for  family  reunification  visas,  the  last  significant  avenue  for  legal  immigra¬ tion  into  Europe  after  restrictions  on  asylum  had  been  passed.  The  means  of doing  so  varied  from  lowering  the  age  up  to  which  children  could  join  their parents  (to  twelve  by  Germany,  fifteen  by  Austria),  to  raising  the  age  at  which marriage  takes  place  for  a  valid  spousal  application  (to  twenty-four  by  Den¬ mark,  twenty-one  by  the  Netherlands),  to  increasing  the  sponsor’s  income  or housing  requirements,  as  was  done  in  France  and  the  Netherlands.  In  addi¬ tion  to  these  new  legal  restrictions,  there  is  widespread  agreement  that  immi¬ gration  is  highly  susceptible  to  many  policies  that  go  well  beyond  the  formal conditions  for  entry  and  residence  in  a  country.  These  range  from  simple  ad¬ ministrative  delays  in  the  processing  of  visas  to  the  conditions  under  which 272  Perez foreigners  are  allowed  to  obtain  employment,  access  to  healthcare  services, education,  and  other  social  services  or  benefits.  Many,  though  not  all,  coun¬ tries  in  the  EU  toughened  these  conditions  during  the  1990s  and  early  2000s.6 Given  the  many  ways  governments  can  seek  to  restrict  immigration,  it  is difficult  to  assess  the  overall  character  of  immigration  policy  pursued  by  a country  under  governments  of  different  stripes  by  only  looking  at  legal  re¬ quirements  for  residency.  One  alternative  way  to  consider  the  question  is  to compare  levels  of  immigration  under  governments  of  the  left  and  govern¬ ments  of  the  right.  A  simple  test  that  pools  annual  figures  available  from Eurostat  for  eleven  member  states  for  1989  through  2006  suggests  that  the average  annual  increase  in  the  number  of  foreigners  living  in  a  country  as  a percentage  of  the  population  under  governments  of  the  left  was  just  half  of what  it  was  under  other  regimes.  When  the  data  are  adjusted  by  subtracting annual  inflows  of  asylum  seekers  from  the  annual  change  in  the  number  of foreigners,  the  results  are  similar:  an  average  increase  of  0.14%  under  gov¬ ernments  of  the  left  versus  0.23%  under  governments  of  the  center  or  right. A  more  refined  regression  analysis  of  the  impact  of  left  government  on  the annual  increase  in  immigrant  proportion,  controlling  for  key  pull  and  push factors  such  as  growth,  unemployment,  time-period  (introduced  to  control for  external  events  in  countries  of  origin  such  as  the  Balkan  crisis)  and  social spending,  also  shows  left  government  to  be  associated  with  lower  levels  of immigration  in  Europe  than  governments  not  controlled  by  the  left.7 However,  as  any  visual  analysis  of  developments  within  countries  shows (see  figure  1),  in  spite  of  these  overall  results  there  are  clear  differences  in  the extent  to  which  governments  have  restricted  immigration  across  Europe.  In many  countries  (including  Germany,  France,  and  the  smaller  members  of  the EU-15)  there  has  been  a  decisive  trend  to  restrict  immigration,  and  that  trend appears  more  acute  under  governments  of  the  left.8  Indeed,  it  is  this  set  of countries  that  are  responsible  for  the  overall  results  cited  above.  By  contrast, in  three  European  countries  (Britain,  Spain,  and  Italy)  governments  of  the  left allowed  for  large  inflows  of  immigrants  through  2006,  and  in  one  case  (Brit¬ ain)  this  represented  a  marked  departure  from  the  previous,  right-wing  gov¬ ernments.  To  explore  what  this  might  tell  us  about  the  politics  of  immigration in  Europe,  we  next  consider  the  experiences  of  these  three  countries  along¬ side  that  of  Germany,  the  country  that  arguably  has  taken  the  most  restrictive turn  in  its  immigration  regime  over  the  last  decade,  a  period  coinciding  with the  center-left’s  tenure  in  power. Immigration  and  the  European  Left  273 Diverging  Choices:  Immigration  Policy  under  the  Center-Left in  Germany,  the  United  Kingdom,  Italy,  and  Spain Germany Germany  has  long  been  one  of  the  premier  destinations  for  immigrants  in Europe.  At  12.9%,  the  proportion  of  its  population  that  was  foreign  born  in 2005  was  equal  to  that  of  the  United  States  and,  until  recently,  the  second- highest  in  the  EU  (only  Austria,  with  a  foreign-born  population  of  13.5%, had  a  higher  percentage  in  2005).9  Nonetheless,  immigration  did  not  consti¬ tute  a  major  point  of  contention  between  the  postwar  right  and  left  until  the 1980s.  The  German  Social  Democratic  Party  (SPD)  showed  few  differences in  its  approach  to  immigration  from  the  mainstream  of  the  Christian  Demo¬ cratic  Party  (CDU)  during  Germany’s  economic  miracle  years.  Both  the  CDU and  the  SPD  backed  the  recruitment  of  foreign  guest  workers  with  limited rights  of  residence  in  the  1960s,  and  the  CDU  supported  the  ending  of  the program  when  the  SPD  declared  a  recruitment  ban  on  foreign  workers  in 1973,  thereby  effectively  ending  work-based  immigration.  In  the  subsequent period  the  leadership  of  both  the  CDU  and  the  SPD  supported  the  view  that Germany  was  “not  a  land  of  immigration”  (a  phrase  most  often  associated with  Helmut  Kohl  but  previously  deployed  by  Helmut  Schmidt).10  This  was also  reflected  in  both  SPD  and  CDU  governments’  commitment  to  Germany’s principle  of  ius  sanguinis  for  citizenship  status,  which  precluded  large  num¬ bers  of  children  of  guest  workers  born  in  Germany  from  attaining  citizenship. In  all  these  ways  Germany’s  postwar  immigration  policy  reflected  a  consen¬ sus  among  the  center-left  and  center-right  that  immigration  was  acceptable as  an  economic  imperative  but  that  there  was  a  social  limit  on  the  extent  to which  Germany  could  integrate  foreigners.  This  position  appears  to  have  re¬ flected  a  strong  fear  on  the  part  of  the  German  political  elite  of  the  poten¬ tial  for  xenophobic  political  mobilization  among  the  German  public  (Karapin 1999).11  Hence  before  the  1980s  there  was  little  politicizing  of  the  issue  at  the national  level  (Zaslove  2007). What  would  ultimately  threaten  this  cross-elite  consensus  was  the  ar¬ rival,  beginning  in  the  late  1970s,  of  a  significant  number  of  political  asylum seekers  from  places  like  Afghanistan,  Ethiopia,  Turkey,  and  Vietnam  (Kara¬ pin  1999).  Both  the  SPD  and  the  FDP  remained  formally  committed  to  Article 16  of  Germany’s  Basic  Law  (1949),  which  allowed  to  asylum  seekers  whose applications  had  been  rejected  at  the  administrative  level  a  strong  right  to appeal  deportation  through  the  German  courts.  Yet  anti-immigrant  mobili¬ zation  by  far-right  groups  in  the  Federal  Republic’s  southern  regions  led  seg¬ ments  of  the  CDU  and  the  CSU  to  push  for  stricter  asylum  laws  in  the  course 274  Perez of  the  national  elections  of  1980.  In  the  run-up  to  the  elections  the  regional government  of  Baden-Wiirttemberg,  then  controlled  by  the  CDU,  and  the  CSU government  of  Bavaria  announced  their  own  restrictions  on  asylum  seekers, a  move  later  seconded  by  the  SPD  mayor  of  Essen.  These  decisions  were  in¬ spired  by  local  protests  against  the  settlement  of  asylum  seekers  in  particu¬ lar  localities  and  neighborhoods.  The  threat  that  such  popular  mobilization would  spread  led  Schmidt’s  government  to  pass  special  visa  requirements for  citizens  of  Afghanistan,  Ethiopia,  and  Sri  Lanka  just  before  the  elections. However,  stronger  measures  were  for  the  time  precluded  by  the  constitu¬ tional  status  of  Germany’s  asylum  law,  which  could  only  be  changed  by  a two-thirds  majority  vote  in  the  Bundestag. It  would  only  be  with  the  arrival  of  far  larger  numbers  of  asylum  seekers in  the  early  1990s  that  the  SPD  would  agree  to  give  Kohl’s  government  the necessary  parliamentary  support  for  such  a  constitutional  reform.  An  amend¬ ment  in  1993  of  Article  16  voided  the  right  of  asylum  for  those  having  passed through  a  “safe  third  country”  on  their  way  to  Germany— in  practice,  a  vast majority  of  cases.  At  the  same  time  asylum  seekers,  who  had  already  been  ex¬ cluded  from  obtaining  work  in  Germany,  were  shifted  from  the  protection  of the  Federal  Social  Assistance  Act  to  a  separate  social  assistance  regime  that provided  fewer  cash  benefits  along  with  food  vouchers,  a  measure  that  clearly stigmatized  this  part  of  the  immigrant  population.  SPD  support  for  such  radi¬ cal  measures  to  restrict  asylum  applications  appears  to  have  been  motivated by  the  extensive  wave  of  anti-foreigner  violence  that  occurred  after  German unification,  which  peaked  with  3,365  attacks  on  foreigners  in  the  first  half  of 1993,  and  the  subsequent  wave  of  intra-German  migration  (Human  Rights Watch  1994;  Karapin  1999).  The  virtual  closure  of  the  asylum  route  of  immi¬ gration  into  Germany  is  reflected  in  the  sharp  curtailment  of  the  previously rising  number  of  foreigners  residing  in  Germany  from  1994  on  (see  figure  1). After  returning  to  power  in  1998  the  political  left  in  Germany  took  two major  steps  intended  to  create  a  new  immigration  regime  that  would  be  po¬ litically  more  tenable.  First,  with  the  rate  of  net  inflows  of  foreign  residents slowing  to  a  halt,  and  responding  to  growing  concern  over  the  integration of  second-generation  immigrants,  the  Red- Green  coalition  led  by  Gerhard Schroder  campaigned  on  a  promise  to  reform  Germany’s  century-old  law conferring  citizenship  only  on  the  basis  of  ancestry  rather  than  birth.  The new  law,  adopted  in  1999,  made  it  possible  for  the  children  of  immigrants born  in  Germany  and  meeting  certain  conditions  to  apply  for  German  citizen¬ ship.  Indeed,  in  its  original  proposals  the  government  sought  to  make  possible such  applications  without  requiring  applicants  to  renounce  their  existing  citi¬ zenship,  a  matter  crucial  to  the  offspring  of  Turkish  and  Polish  immigrants  for Immigration  and  the  European  Left  275 whom  abandoning  their  traditional  nationality  implied  giving  up  inheritance rights  in  their  parents’  country  of  origin.  In  the  end  Schroder’s  government was  dissuaded  from  insisting  on  the  possibility  of  dual  citizenship  by  the  out¬ come  of  an  election  in  Hesse,  where  the  CDU  successfully  used  the  nationality law  as  a  wedge  issue  to  win  control  of  the  regional  government.12  The  new citizenship  law  passed  in  2000  nevertheless  held  great  symbolic  importance, for  it  shattered  the  principle  that  Germany  was  not  a  land  of  immigration. This  alone  was  seen  as  a  step  forward  in  promoting  the  social  absorption  of second-generation  immigrants.  Yet  because  of  the  exclusion  of  dual  citizen¬ ship,  it  resulted  in  citizenship  applications  by  only  a  fraction  of  Germany’s disenfranchised  second-generation  immigrants  (around  750,000  of  the  origi¬ nal  3  million  predicted  by  the  government).13 Secondly,  Schroder’s  government  attempted  to  pass  a  new  immigration law  that  would  have  reopened  the  door  for  work-based  immigration,  al¬ though  only  for  highly  skilled  workers.  The  so-called  Schily  law  (named  after the  coalition’s  interior  minister,  Otto  Schily),  aimed  to  alter  the  skill  profile of  immigrants  by  significantly  toughening  the  standards  for  family  reunifica¬ tion  (the  one  remaining  traditional  avenue  for  immigrants)  while  replacing the  ban  on  work-based  immigration  with  a  points  system  that  would  have  al¬ lowed  residence  permits  for  highly  qualified  workers  in  areas  in  which  Ger¬ man  employers  faced  labor  shortages.14  The  resumption  of  labor  immigration was  backed  heavily  by  German  business  groups  which  put  strong  pressure  on both  the  SPD  and  CDU  in  favor  of  the  law  (Ette  2003).  On  the  other  hand,  a toughening  of  family  reunification  criteria  (in  particular  a  lowering  of  the  age up  to  which  children  could  join  their  parents  from  sixteen  to  twelve  years) was  advocated  by  both  the  SPD  and  the  Christian  Democratic  opposition, which  argued  that  the  age  should  be  lowered  to  ten  years.  Family  reunifica¬ tion  was  held  to  be  responsible  for  the  low-skill  profile  of  Germany’s  immi¬ grant  population  because  it  necessarily  built  on  the  low-skill  character  of  the earlier  guest-worker  policy  and  therefore  largely  perpetuated  its  results.  The law  also  created  new  integration  requirements  in  the  form  of  language  tests for  the  extension  of  residency  permits. Although  the  policy  was  legislated  by  the  Red-Green  government  in  2002, it  was  successfully  challenged  in  court  on  a  procedural  matter  by  the  CDU, which  argued  adamantly  against  any  reestablishment  of  work-based  immi¬ gration  and  any  expansion  of  the  criteria  for  political  asylum.  The  final  ver¬ sion  of  the  law,  passed  in  2004  with  the  support  of  the  CDU  in  the  upper house,  excluded  the  SPD’s  centerpiece  — the  points-based  system  of  labor  im¬ migration.  It  thus  maintained  the  ban  on  work-based  immigration,  allowing only  for  three  exclusions:  one-year  visas  for  foreign  students  after  they  fin- 276  Perez ished  their  studies  in  Germany;  permanent  residence  permits  for  top-level scientists  and  managers;  and  temporary  residence  permits  for  self-employed foreigners  investing  over  one  million  Euros  in  designated  economic  activities (Munz  2004).  As  a  concession  to  the  Green  Party,  it  did  include  gender-  and non-state-based  persecution  as  criteria  for  refugee  status,  although  not  politi¬ cal  asylum.15  The  SPD  government’s  major  objective,  to  create  an  immigration policy  regime  that  would  alter  the  profile  of  immigrants  from  low-skilled  to high-skilled  was  thus  blocked,  leaving  simply  an  even  more  restrictive  immi¬ gration  regime  than  the  one  Germany  had  already  adopted  in  1993. The  United  Kingdom By  contrast  to  Germany,  Britain’s  initial  postwar  immigration  regime  was not  driven  primarily  by  economic  considerations  but  by  geopolitical  ones. After  the  war  Labour  passed  the  British  Nationality  Act  of  1948,  which  turned British  subjecthood  into  British  citizenship,  giving  a  large  number  of  former colonial  subjects  an  automatic  right  to  migrate  to  the  United  Kingdom.  Yet far  being  from  a  partisan  measure,  this  generous  immigration  policy  repre¬ sented  a  straight  continuation  of  pre-war  policy,  which  had  aimed  to  pro¬ tect  Britain’s  preeminence  within  the  Commonwealth  in  a  postcolonial  era through  the  creation  of  Commonwealth  citizenship  (Hansen  1999;  Karatani and  Goodwin-Gill  2003).  The  permissive  stance  toward  Commonwealth  im¬ migration  implied  in  Labour’s  nationality  act  thus  enjoyed  the  full  support  of the  Conservative  Party,  which  in  turn,  after  returning  to  power  in  the  1950s, would  allow  the  arrival  of  many  former  colonial  subjects  for  permanent settlement  in  the  United  Kingdom. This  liberal  consensus  on  postcolonial  immigration  would  be  shattered by  the  outbreak  of  anti-foreigner,  and  specifically  anti-black,  violence  at  the end  of  the  1950s,  which  was  seized  upon  by  a  populist  wing  of  the  Conser¬ vative  Party,  epitomized  by  Enoch  Powell  (Karapin  1999).  In  response  to  a large  number  of  petitions  for  immigration  controls  from  local  party  chap¬ ters,  Harold  Macmillan’s  government  passed  the  first  significant  step  toward immigration  restriction  with  the  first  Commonwealth  Immigration  Act  of 1962,  which  subjected  the  right  to  settle  in  Britain  to  government  issuance of  a  skill-based  work  permit.  Although  Labour  initially  opposed  the  measure and  then  worked  to  have  it  protect  the  right  of  dependents  to  accompany holders  of  work  permits,  it  engaged  in  a  dramatic  about-face  on  immigration policy  after  winning  elections  in  1964.  The  new  government  of  Harold  Wilson sharply  restricted  the  number  of  work  vouchers,  entirely  abolishing  the  cate¬ gory  of  unskilled  labor  and  significantly  reducing  that  of  skilled  workers  in Immigration  and  the  European  Left  277 1965.  In  1968  it  passed  the  second  Commonwealth  Immigration  Act,  with  the aim  of  preventing  the  immigration  of  Kenyan  Asians.  The  new  act  for  the  first time  distinguished  between  “patrial”  British  citizens  (those  of  British  birth  or descent)  and  other  Commonwealth  citizens,  thereby  bringing  nonwhite  im¬ migration  to  Britain  to  a  virtual  end  (Hansen  1999).16  At  the  same  time  Wilson sought  to  balance  this  anti-liberal  turn  in  immigration  policy  by  introducing anti-discrimination  legislation  in  the  Race  Relations  Act  (1968). If  British  Labour,  like  center-left  parties  elsewhere  in  Europe,  took  a  popu¬ list  stance  in  restricting  immigration  during  the  1970s,  it  has  played  a  very different  role  over  the  last  decade.  As  figure  1  illustrates,  after  more  than  a  de¬ cade  of  sharp  decline  in  the  number  of  foreigners  living  in  Britain  during  the Thatcher  years  (and  only  a  modest  reversal  of  this  trend  in  the  first  half  of  the 1990s),  the  Labour  victory  of  1997  set  the  stage  for  a  significant  increase  in immigration  into  Britain  (most  of  it  from  non-EU  states).  Taking  the  view  that immigration  could  be  beneficial  to  Britain’s  economic  modernization  when and  where  it  supported  economic  activity,  the  government  of  Tony  Blair  set out  on  a  two-pronged  strategy  of  expanding  the  issuance  of  new  work  per¬ mits  for  third-country  foreigners  while  at  the  same  time  moving  to  deter  asy¬ lum  applicants  whom  it  identified  as  a  burden  on  Britain’s  purse.  In  a  white paper  titled  “Fairer,  Faster  and  Firmer:  A  Modern  Approach  to  Immigration and  Asylum”  (1998)  the  new  government  decried  “backlogs,  inadequate  con¬ trol  resources,  and  outdated  procedures”  in  the  existing  system  of  asylum  re¬ view,  which  made  “it  extremely  difficult  to  deal  firmly  with  those  who  have no  right  to  be  here”  (Home  Office  1998,  paragraph  3.3).  At  the  same  time  it began  to  increase  the  number  of  work  permits  granted  for  those  seeking  em¬ ployment  in  key  sectors.  In  2002  Labour  introduced  the  Highly  Skilled  Mi¬ grant  Programme,  arguing  that  legitimate,  work-based  immigration  could bring  “huge  benefits:  increased  skills,  enhanced  levels  of  economic  activity, cultural  diversity  and  global  links”  (Home  Office  2002,  9).  It  also  increased visas  for  low-skilled,  casual  work.  In  the  following  year  Blair  promised  to halve  new  asylum  applications  while  moving  Britain  to  a  points-based  system of  immigration.  “Operating  at  different  ends  of  the  employment  spectrum,” all  of  these  initiatives  were  intended  “to  improve  the  supply  of  labour  to  the United  Kingdom  economy,  to  ‘meet  the  challenge’  of  a  globalizing  environ¬ ment”  (Walters  2004,  239).  The  effect  was  a  sharp  upward  turn  in  the  num¬ ber  of  foreign  citizens  residing  in  Britain,  from  just  under  2  million  in  1996 to  almost  3.5  million  in  2006,  the  overwhelming  majority  non-EU  citizens (OECD  2007e). 278  Perez Spain  and  Italy Britain’s  move  to  managed,  skill-based  migration  under  Blair  represents  one of  the  major  turns  in  European  immigration  policy  in  the  last  decades.  None¬ theless,  two  other  member  states  that  in  the  past  were  major  sources  of  emi¬ gration  to  the  rest  of  Europe  — Italy  and  Spain  — account  for  a  much  greater share  of  the  expansion  in  immigration  that  the  EU  has  experienced  over  the last  two  decades.  Italy’s  registered  immigrant  population  rose  in  1989-2006 from  just  under  half  a  million  to  over  two  and  a  half  million.17  Spain’s  trans¬ formation  has  been  even  more  spectacular.  In  just  over  a  decade  the  country has  seen  immigration  (measured  in  terms  of  resident  foreign  citizens)  rise from  marginal  levels  (under  400,000  in  1991)  to  the  highest  level  in  the  EU  in proportion  to  total  population.  By  2008  foreign  citizens  residing  in  Spain,  at over  five  million,  represented  just  over  11%  of  the  population  (El  Pals,  20  June 2008). This  dramatic  rise  of  immigration  into  the  two  southern  member  states  is often  attributed  to  the  restrictive  turn  in  other  EU-15  states  and  to  the  difficul¬ ties  that  Spain  and  Italy  have  had  in  controlling  illegal  immigration  because of  shortcomings  in  border  control  and  a  lack  of  internal  controls  on  the  em¬ ployment  of  illegal  migrants.  Scenes  of  boatloads  of  African  migrants  arriving in  Lampedusa,  the  Canary  Islands,  or  Spain’s  southern  coast,  and  of  the  dra¬ matic  human  tragedies  often  associated  with  their  attempts,  dominate  press coverage  of  the  phenomenon.  Yet  however  dramatic  and  significant,  illegal arrivals  by  sea  represent  a  small  fraction  of  immigration  in  the  two  countries (19,900  for  Italy  in  2007,  18,000  for  Spain  according  to  the  UNHCR).18  The dramatic  increases  in  registered  immigration  in  fact  stem  from  clear  choices on  the  part  of  the  Spanish  and  Italian  governments  that  have  produced  a  far more  liberal  stance  on  immigration  than  what  is  now  prevalent  in  the  north¬ ern  states  of  the  EU-15.  The  key  features  of  this  liberal  stance  in  the  two  coun¬ tries  have  been  (1)  permissive  family  reunification  rules,  (2)  generous  terms for  the  issuance  of  work  permits  in  sectors  deemed  to  have  particular  labor needs,  (3)  the  extension  of  social  rights  to  both  legal  and  irregular  immi¬ grants,  and  (4)  repeated  amnesties  for  irregular  migrants  who  can  show  em¬ ployment.  While  different  in  some  significant  ways  (in  particular  with  regard to  the  use  of  immigration  amnesties),  the  immigration  regimes  developed and  maintained  by  the  two  southern  member  states  thus  bear  a  significant  re¬ semblance  to  the  more  expansive  work-based  immigration  regime  introduced in  Britain. One  way  in  which  the  Spanish  and  Italian  cases  nonetheless  are  different from  the  British  is  that  the  policies  allowing  for  large-scale  immigration  in Immigration  and  the  European  Left  279 the  two  southern  states  have  been  carried  out  with  almost  equal  intensity by  governments  of  the  left  and  the  right.  This  is  particularly  striking  in  Italy, where  governments  of  the  right  in  the  last  two  decades  have  included  the Northern  League,  a  party  formation  with  an  explicit  stance  against  immigra¬ tion  whose  leaders  often  engage  in  xenophobic  appeals.  When  the  right  has been  in  power  in  Italy,  its  pattern  has  been  to  pass  tough  and  even  jarring “law  and  order”  measures  that  make  headlines  (most  recently  the  discrimina¬ tory  treatment  applied  to  Romanian  gypsies),  without  actually  restricting  the overall  levels  of  immigration.  Thus  Silvio  Berlusconi’s  government  of  2001 expanded  the  total  yearly  quota  for  third-country  (non-EU)  migrants  from 89,000  in  2001  to  170,000  in  2006  (Cuttitta  2008).19  And  the  Bossi-Fini  law that  it  passed  in  2002  (which  required  the  expulsion  of  immigrants  whose residence  permits  had  not  been  renewed,  and  for  the  first  time  linked  new residence  permits  to  the  prior  attainment  of  work  contracts)  was  accompa¬ nied  by  the  largest  immigration  amnesty  Italy  had  ever  seen.  It  resulted  in  the legalization  of  almost  all  of  the  700,000  immigrants  who  applied  (Migration Policy  Institute  2004).  Meanwhile  in  Spain,  the  center-right  Partido  Popular passed  its  own  amnesties  for  illegal  immigrants  in  1996,  2000,  and  2001  and in  the  process  approved  approximately  400,000  applications  (Maas  2006). If  governments  of  the  right  have  thus  been  surprisingly  liberal  in  their immigration  policies  in  Italy  and  Spain,  the  left  has  generally  gone  further. In  Italy  the  center-left  in  2006  successfully  ran  on  a  platform  of  easing  the immigration  restrictions  that  had  been  imposed  by  the  Bossi-Fini  law.  Ro¬ mano  Prodi’s  government  subsequently  adopted  an  open-door  immigration policy,  abolishing  the  requirement  of  prior  work  contracts  for  the  granting of  residence  permits.  And  while  Italy  sparked  controversy  across  the  EU  in 2007  when  it  legislated  the  expulsion  of  EU  immigrants  charged  with  violent crime  (a  measure  taken  in  response  to  popular  outcry  over  a  spike  in  crime attributed  to  Romanian  immigrants),  its  policies  for  granting  residence  and work  permits  to  foreign  applicants  remained  among  the  most  liberal  ever seen  in  the  EU  (Chaloff  2005).  In  Spain  the  Socialist  government  that  took office  in  2004  went  on  to  pass  Spain’s  most  generous  immigration  legislation yet,  granting  full  access  to  healthcare,  education,  and  other  social  services to  both  legal  and  illegal  immigrants,  and  passing  an  amnesty  regularizing the  status  of  over  600,000  further  immigrant  residents  who  could  prove  that they  had  employment. 280  Perez Implications  and  Conclusions As  the  cases  discussed  above  suggest,  there  have  been  ample  differences  in the  stances  toward  new  immigration  taken  by  governments  of  the  left  in Europe  in  the  last  two  decades.  Germany’s  SPD  in  1993  went  along  with  a constitutional  revision  that  set  the  stage  for  a  toughening  of  asylum  rules not  only  in  Germany  but  across  the  EU.  Later,  when  in  government,  it  at¬ tempted  to  shift  to  a  selective,  skills-based  immigration  regime  that  would have  raised  the  skill  profile  of  Germany’s  immigrant  population  (an  attempt at  which  it  failed  owing  to  opposition  from  the  Christian  Democrats).  And while  the  Red-Green  coalition  government  sought  to  improve  the  integration of  second-generation  immigrants  by  changing  German  citizenship  law,  it  also toughened  criteria  for  family  reunification,  the  principal  remaining  channel for  low-skill  immigration  into  Germany,  and  introduced  new  requirements for  the  renewal  of  residence  permits.  The  result  has  been  a  virtual  freeze  on net  immigration  into  Germany  over  the  last  decade. In  sharp  contrast  to  this  turn  in  Germany,  New  Labour  in  Britain  opened the  doors  of  the  British  labor  market  to  new  immigrants  from  outside  the EU.  At  the  same  time,  it  shifted  immigration  into  Britain  from  a  rights-based system  to  a  skills-based  system  that  gave  access  to  those  types  of  migrants demanded  by  British  business,  both  at  the  high  and  the  lower  ends  of  the skills  spectrum.  Under  Blair’s  leadership  the  Labour  government  rejected  the notion  (which  seemed  to  prevail  in  Germany)  that  there  is  a  necessary  trade¬ off  between  allowing  more  immigrants  and  achieving  successful  social  inte¬ gration;  it  opted  instead  to  facilitate  labor  market  access  for  the  spouses  and children  of  those  workers  recruited  under  the  new  points-based  system,  bet¬ ting  that  this  would  also  mean  more  successful  integration.  Only  in  the  face  of a  worsening  electoral  outlook  and  heightened  anger  from  labor  unions  at  the large  inflow  of  low-skilled  workers  did  Gordon  Brown’s  government  choose to  restrict  the  immigration  of  third-country  nationals  who  fell  outside  the high  skills  category,  promising  500,000  new  “British  jobs  for  British  workers” just  as  the  first  signs  of  the  world  financial  crisis  appeared  ( Guardian ,  10  Sep¬ tember  2007). Finally,  in  Italy  and  Spain,  the  two  countries  accounting  for  the  largest increases  of  third-country  immigration  into  the  EU  over  the  last  decade, both  left  and  right  governments  have  chosen  to  allow  high  levels  of  immi¬ gration.  While  governments  of  the  right  (in  particular  in  Italy)  have  sought to  counteract  the  perception  of  this  reality  through  headline-catching  “law and  order”  measures,  left  parties  have  distinguished  themselves  primarily  by extending  social  rights  to  immigrants,  including  non-regularized  ones,  as  a Immigration  and  the  European  Left  281 way  to  promote  integration.  In  both  countries  governments  have  made  ample use  of  amnesties  to  bring  illegal  migrants  into  the  formal  economy,  and  in Spain  the  first  government  of  Jose  Luis  Rodriguez  Zapatero  made  healthcare available  to  all  residents,  regardless  of  their  residency  status.  On  the  other hand,  in  both  Italy  and  Spain  as  in  Britain,  governments  of  the  left  have  been able  to  garner  the  support  of  both  business  and  the  labor  unions  for  their immigration-friendly  policies  by  basing  the  issuance  of  new  work  permits  to immigrants  on  a  selective  system  favoring  those  sectors  facing  labor  short¬ ages,  ranging  from  the  low-skill  construction  and  domestic  work  sectors  to information  technology. If  parties  of  the  center-left  can  be  expected  to  face  similar  electoral  con¬ flicts  over  immigration  policy  on  theoretical  grounds,  how  are  we  to  account for  the  observed  differences  in  their  immigration  policy  choices,  in  particu¬ lar  as  regards  overall  levels  of  immigration?  One  common  explanation,  the presence  or  absence  of  an  electorally  viable  radical  right,  does  not  account for  the  variation  among  the  four  cases  examined  above:  the  radical  right  did not  represent  a  serious  electoral  threat  in  national  or  even  regional  elections in  Germany,  whereas  it  does  have  significant  electoral  weight  in  Italy  and even  participates  in  government.  Nor  can  the  choices  be  attributed  to  the existing  levels  of  the  immigrant  population,  given  that  Germany’s  share  of immigrants,  while  high,  had  been  surpassed  by  that  of  Spain  as  early  as  2004, when  the  Socialist  government  chose  to  pass  yet  another  amnesty  and  expand the  social  rights  of  illegal  immigrants. A  different  and  more  convincing  explanation  of  the  contrast  between  the German  SPD’s  choice  in  favor  of  immigration  restriction  and  the  more  liberal stances  of  center-left  governments  in  Britain,  Spain,  and  Italy  would  focus  on the  ways  immigrants  are  economically  integrated  in  the  different  countries. Looking  first  at  the  labor  market,  one  striking  contrast  between  Germany  and the  other  three  countries  is  the  wide  range  in  their  gaps  between  the  unem¬ ployment  rate  for  immigrants  and  the  rate  for  the  native  population.  In  2005 unemployment  in  Germany  stood  at  17.5%  for  foreign-born  men  and  10.6% for  native-born  men,  and  at  16%  for  foreign-born  women  and  10%  for  native- born  women.  In  the  United  Kingdom  and  Spain  these  gaps  were  consider¬ ably  smaller:  in  the  United  Kingdom  there  was  a  difference  of  only  2.8%  for men  and  3.4%  for  women;  in  Spain  only  2.5%  for  men  and  1.5%  for  women. In  Italy  the  situation  was  slightly  different:  unemployment  was  a  bit  higher for  native-born  men  (6.2%)  than  for  foreign-born  men  (6%),  though  the  rate for  foreign-born  women  was  somewhat  lower  than  for  native-born  women. Still,  the  contrast  with  Germany  is  striking.  Moreover,  in  both  Spain  and  Italy the  labor  market  participation  rates  of  foreigners  was  considerably  better 282  Perez than  that  of  native-born  citizens:  in  Italy,  81.6%  compared  to  69.4%  for  men, 46.7%  compared  to  45.3%  for  women;  in  Spain,  79.5%  compared  to  74.4%  for men,  60.4%  compared  to  50%  for  women  (OECD  2007c). The  reasons  for  this  poor  labor  market  performance  of  immigrants  in Germany  are  complex.  They  seem  to  include  obstacles  to  labor  market  inte¬ gration  by  foreigners  and  their  children  that  are  created  by  German  legisla¬ tion,  the  low  skill  profile  of  the  immigrant  population  compared  to  the  na¬ tive  population  (an  inheritance  from  the  low-skill  focus  of  the  guest-worker program),  and  the  poor  performance  of  the  German  economy,  compared  to the  other  three  economies,  at  generating  low-skill  employment  (Constant and  Zimmermann  2005).  The  last  of  these  features  also  implies  that  the  left in  Germany  faces  a  particularly  acute  conflict  between  the  interests  of  its low-skilled  electorate  and  immigrants.  Thus  it  is  noteworthy  that  precisely when  it  introduced  its  first  new  immigration  law,  Schroder’s  government  was seeking  to  reduce  the  high  unemployment  level  among  low-skilled  workers through  radical  reforms  of  the  labor  market,  including  the  introduction  of more  flexible  employment  contracts  in  the  service  sector  and  major  cuts  in unemployment  pay.  The  so-called  Hartz  reforms  were  highly  controversial, threatening  the  SPD’s  internal  integrity.  In  this  context  slowing  the  inflow  of new,  low-skilled  workers  must  have  appeared  as  a  good  way  to  ease  tensions in  the  labor  market,  and  with  it  the  potential  electoral  cost  of  the  labor  mar¬ ket  reforms. While  all  of  this  may  explain  why  the  center-left  in  Germany  would  be under  particular  pressure  to  restrict  immigration,  it  does  not  explain  why similar  governments  in  the  other  three  countries  would  not  also  act  on  such pressure.  Here  it  must  be  said  that  Britain’s  managed  migration  policy,  even before  Brown’s  clampdown  on  low-skilled,  third-country  immigration,  was structured  so  as  to  allow  the  government  to  keep  a  grip  on  the  political  ten¬ sion  that  immigration  might  create  among  its  voters.  By  limiting  immigration to  either  high-growth  or  high-skill  sectors,  the  managed  migration  policy  also allowed  the  government  to  limit  immigration  in  lower-growth  sectors,  where it  might  have  had  a  more  obvious  impact  on  lower-skilled  native  workers. An  alternative  explanation  for  Labour’s  original  open-door  policy  may  be the  weakness  of  British  labor  unions,  which  were  in  a  poor  position  to  resist Blair’s  new  open-door  policy  toward  migrants  in  the  face  of  consistent  pres¬ sure  from  British  business  in  favor  of  a  more  liberal  immigration  policy.  In¬ deed,  the  outbreak  of  wildcat  strikes  protesting  the  hire  of  Italian  and  Por¬ tuguese  workers  in  British  oil  refineries  and  energy  companies  in  early  2009 illustrates  the  weakness  of  organized  labor  in  influencing  the  Labour  govern¬ ments’  immigration  policy  and  the  consequent  sense  of  frustration  among Immigration  and  the  European  Left  283 blue-collar  workers.  However,  it  would  be  difficult  to  make  a  similar  case for  Italy,  where  unions  mobilized  politically  against  the  immigration  restric¬ tions  imposed  by  the  Bossi-Fini  law,  or  Spain,  where  Zapatero’s  government has  based  immigration  policy  on  tripartite  agreements  and  where  the  unions participate  in  setting  annual  immigration  quotas.20  Looking  at  the  actions of  unions  with  regard  to  immigration  policy  in  the  latter  two  countries,  it  is noteworthy  that  their  position  on  immigration  has  remained  generally  very favorable  (Watts  2002). There  is  another  characteristic  which  the  United  Kingdom  shares  with  Italy and  Spain  and  which  sets  all  three  countries  apart  from  Germany  and  other continental  EU  members:  the  United  Kingdom’s  liberal  welfare  state  is  quite weak  in  the  provision  of  services  such  as  childcare  and  elder  care  (Unger- son  2003).  And  for  different  reasons,  so  are  the  Spanish  and  Italian  welfare states.21  Consequently,  in  all  three  countries  there  is  high  demand  for  cheap immigrant  labor  both  from  institutional  employers  such  as  nursing  homes and  hospitals  and  from  private  households.  Comprehensive  data  on  such  em¬ ployment  are  difficult  to  attain.  Yet  there  is  evidence  in  all  three  countries  of the  important  role  that  immigrants  play  in  providing  these  services.  In  the United  Kingdom,  for  instance,  a  high  proportion  of  nurses  and  elder  care  pro¬ viders  are  from  the  Philippines  (Lyon  and  Glucksman  2008).  In  Italy  34%  of the  almost  700,000  immigrants  regularized  during  the  amnesty  of  2002  ap¬ plied  on  the  basis  of  employment  in  domestic  work,  and  according  to  one  re¬ port  immigrants  account  for  over  43%  of  domestic  employment.  And  in  Spain that  figure  is  believed  to  be  above  52%  (Eiro  Online  2006,  2007). This  role  of  (primarily  female)  immigration  in  the  provision  of  key  ser¬ vices  is  important  because  it  suggests  that  significant  segments  of  the  center- left’s  electorate,  including  in  particular  median-income  households  which have  become  increasingly  dependent  on  two  incomes  (which  require  exter¬ nal  help  with  child  or  elder  care  in  the  absence  of  publicly  provided  care  ser¬ vices)  will  have  a  very  concrete  personal  interest  in  a  liberal  immigration regime.  That  the  rise  of  female  immigration  has  coincided  with  a  rise  of  (na¬ tive)  female  labor  market  participation  rates  in  the  two  southern  European countries  attests  to  the  importance  that  immigrant  labor  plays  in  the  role of  many  two-income  families  (Chaloff  2005).  In  all  three  countries  (Britain, Italy,  and  Spain)  immigration  thus  compensates  median-income  households for  the  shortcomings  of  a  residual-liberal  or  late  and  not  fully  developed  wel¬ fare  state.  This  tendency  not  only  turns  immigrants  into  a  functional  substi¬ tute  for  more  comprehensive  social  provision.  It  also  creates  an  infrastruc¬ ture  of  personal  contacts  that  is  likely  to  counter  anti-immigrant  sentiment  in the  relatively  affluent  segment  of  the  left’s  electorate  — a  segment  that  might 284  Perez otherwise  turn  to  welfare  chauvinism.  By  contrast,  where  care  services  are provided  by  the  state  either  publicly  or  by  allowing  mothers  to  stay  out  of  the job  market  through  generous  family  allowances,  this  type  of  private  stake  in immigration  is  likely  to  be  lacking. These  observations  also  speak  to  the  broader  relationship  between  im¬ migration  and  welfare  states.  Whereas  economists  have  tended  to  interpret lower  levels  of  social  spending  and  redistribution  in  countries  such  as  the United  States  as  a  consequence  of  ethnic  diversity— and  hence  a  lack  of  social cohesion  (Alesina,  Glaeser,  and  Sacerdote  2001)  — the  recent  experiences  of Britain,  Italy,  and  Spain  suggest  an  opposite  causal  relationship:  that  higher immigration  is  encouraged  by  lower  levels  of  social  provision  because  it  com¬ pensates  for  shortcomings  in  the  welfare  state.  This  relationship  means  that  a correlation  between  lower  social  spending  and  ethnic  diversification  need  not necessarily  reflect  any  inherent  conflict  between  multiculturalism  and  gen¬ erous  welfare  spending  but  rather  an  effect  of  low  social  spending  on  rates  of immigration.  On  the  other  hand,  moves  to  restrict  immigration  in  Germany and  elsewhere  among  the  corporatist  welfare  states  of  northern  Europe  may have  more  to  do  with  the  failure  to  integrate  immigrant  populations  into  the labor  market,  which  in  turn  is  more  likely  to  turn  them  into  welfare  recipi¬ ents.  Restrictions  on  the  acquisition  of  citizenship  for  the  children  of  immi¬ grants,  limitations  on  family  reunification,  and  restrictions  on  labor  market access  to  family  members  who  join  legal  immigrants— all  represent  barriers to  labor  market  integration,  and  they  may  create  the  social  dependence  that is  seen  to  spark  welfare  chauvinism  in  places  such  as  Germany. All  this  suggests  that  how  immigration  affects  parties  of  the  left  is  likely to  depend  on  how  immigrants  are  integrated  into  the  labor  market  and  on how  the  arrival  of  newcomers  interacts  with  the  characteristics  of  European welfare  states  (whether  immigrants  are  rendered  welfare  state  dependents by  laws  meant  to  discourage  them  from  arriving  in  the  first  place,  or  whether they  act  as  functional  substitutes  for  citizens  but  without  access  to  social  poli¬ cies).  The  environment  will  be  shaped  by  the  choices  of  parties  on  the  right to  politicize,  or  not  to  politicize,  the  immigration  issue.  But  it  will  also  be shaped  by  the  politics  of  the  welfare  state  (although  in  much  more  complex ways  than  simple  theories  of  welfare  chauvinism  would  have  it),  the  charac¬ teristics  of  labor  and  product  markets  (both  matters  of  government  regula¬ tion),  and  past  policies  that  have  affected  the  characteristics  of  the  immigrant population  and  its  degree  of  economic  and  social  integration.  In  this  regard past  German  governments  of  both  left  and  right,  which  have  insisted  on  re¬ stricting  long-term  avenues  of  integration  (including  paths  to  citizenship  for the  children  of  immigrants  and  the  ability  of  asylum  seekers  to  obtain  em- Immigration  and  the  European  Left  285 ployment),  seem  to  have  created  a  climate  in  which  it  has  been  more  difficult for  the  left  to  advance  a  new  type  of  immigration  policy  in  recent  years  — more  so  than  for  governments  of  the  left  in  the  other  three  countries. This  discussion  of  how  the  politics  of  immigration  differ  for  center-left parties  across  Europe  does  not  answer  the  question  of  whether  large-scale immigration  places  the  left  at  a  consistent  electoral  disadvantage  vis-a-vis parties  of  the  right.  The  electoral  tensions  that  immigration  creates  specifi¬ cally  for  the  left  may  mean  that  the  issue  can  easily  be  exploited  by  parties on  the  right  for  electoral  gain  and  at  little  political  risk.  In  particular  in  coun¬ tries  where  an  anti-immigrant  far  right  has  emerged  (such  as  Italy,  discussed above,  and  France),  it  can  be  argued  that  the  mainstream  right  has  success¬ fully  exploited  the  issue  to  its  advantage  in  the  face  of  a  left  hamstrung  by its  internal  tensions.22  In  Italy,  for  instance,  mobilization  of  anti-immigrant sentiment  played  an  important  role  in  the  right’s  return  to  power  in  2001, even  though  Berlusconi  went  on  to  oversee  a  substantial  increase  in  legal  im¬ migration  levels  while  appeasing  his  populist  partners  through  tougher  de¬ portation  standards  and  new  requirements  for  legal  immigration  enshrined in  the  Bossi-Fini  law.  Nicolas  Sarkozy’s  victory  over  Segolene  Royal  in  2007 has  been  at  least  partially  attributed  to  his  tough,  often  controversial  stance on  immigration  and  immigrants,  or  the  children  of  immigrants.23  And  in  Ger¬ many  the  staunch  commitment  of  the  CDU  and  the  CSU  to  block  plans  for  a new,  skilled-based  labor  immigration  policy  has  been  credited  with  helping to  bring  about  the  Christian  Democrats’  sequence  of  regional  electoral  vic¬ tories  in  Hesse  in  1999  and  then  2003,  Lower  Saxony  in  2003,  and,  most  im¬ portantly,  North  Rhine-Westphalia  in  2005.  The  last  of  these  brought  down the  last  Red-Green  state  government  and  prompted  the  federal  elections  that brought  an  end  to  the  left  coalition  government.24 However,  while  politicizing  immigration  may  indeed  create  tensions  for the  left  and  thus  tend  to  work  predominantly  in  favor  of  the  right  in  the  short term,  it  is  not  costless  or  unproblematic  for  the  mainstream  right.  An  uncom¬ promising  stance  on  immigration,  such  as  that  pursued  by  segments  of  the CDU  and  CSU  during  the  years  of  the  Red-Green  coalition,  can  result  in  ideo¬ logical  tensions  within  the  right  as  well.  Such  tensions,  both  between  differ¬ ent  CDU  regional  leaders  and  between  the  party  and  church  organizations, were  evident  during  the  prolonged  negotiations  of  a  compromise  between Schroder’s  government  and  the  CDU  after  the  failure  of  the  first  Schily  law.25 Mainstream  right  parties  face  their  own  tensions  over  immigration  because business,  one  of  its  key  constituencies,  typically  favors  more  open  immigra¬ tion  policies.  This  was  evidenced  both  in  Germany,  where  business  organiza¬ tions  lobbied  aggressively  in  favor  of  Schroder’s  efforts  to  reopen  work-based 286  Perez immigration,  and  in  Italy,  where  business  opposed  the  requirement  imposed by  Bossi-Fini  of  prior  work  contracts  for  residence  permits.26  Tough  talk  on immigration  by  right-wing  politicians  is  thus  less  likely  to  result  in  immigra¬ tion  restrictions  during  periods  of  right-wing  government  than  the  electoral rhetoric  of  the  right  might  imply.  And  this  may  ease  the  political  pressure  on the  left  that  political  victories  by  the  center-right  in  the  context  of  increased global  migration  flows  might  otherwise  produce. The  examples  considered  here  suggest  that  although  there  is  a  real  poten¬ tial  for  the  European  right  to  mobilize  anti-immigrant  sentiment  (note  the electoral  success  of  the  Northern  League  in  an  area  of  Italy  whose  industrial economy  depends  greatly  on  immigrant  labor),  the  left  is  not  therefore  locked into  an  inescapable  choice  between  restricting  immigration  and  permanent electoral  defeat.  In  Spain  (2008)  and  Britain  (2001  and  2005)  the  left  suc¬ ceeded  electorally  after  implementing  very  liberal  immigration  policies  and running  in  the  face  of  efforts  by  the  right  to  politicize  the  issue.  And  in  Italy the  left  won  in  2006  after  running  on  a  promise  to  lift  a  measure  imposed by  the  first  Berlusconi  government  to  require  work  contracts  for  the  issuance of  new  residence  permits.  In  Germany,  on  the  other  hand,  the  political  pres¬ sure  to  restrict  immigration  appears  largely  to  be  a  function  of  the  low-skill profile  of  early  immigrant  labor  recruitment  policies  coupled  with  the  coun¬ try’s  unique  problems  in  creating  jobs  for  low-skilled  workers.  And  something similar  may  be  true  for  France. While  we  note  these  differences,  it  is  also  striking  that  in  all  four  of  the countries  considered  here  governments  of  the  left  have  actively  sought  to shape  the  profile  of  their  immigrant  populations  in  ways  that  fit  the  perceived needs  of  their  economies,  in  particular  by  raising  the  skills  level  of  the  labor force.  Indeed,  while  these  efforts  are  now  being  copied  by  the  right  (for  in¬ stance  Sarkozy’s  government  in  France),  the  move  to  conform  immigration policy  to  other  economic  policy  goals  (in  particular  the  raising  of  the  skills profile  of  the  EU’s  labor  force)  is  one  in  which  governments  of  the  center-left have  played  a  leading  role,  two  examples  being  Blair’s  “managed  migration” model  and  Schroder’s  efforts  to  introduce  a  points-based  system.  One  way  to understand  these  initiatives  is  as  an  effort  by  the  center-left  to  counteract  the electoral  dilemmas  that  immigration  tends  to  create  by  reducing  the  extent to  which  immigration  affects  the  most  vulnerable  in  society. Nonetheless,  choosing  this  sort  of  pragmatism  over  a  rights-based  ap¬ proach  to  immigration  may  be  problematic  in  other  respects.  At  the  very least  it  poses  a  serious  question  as  to  how  the  European  left  will  reconcile  its definition  of  borders  among  peoples  and  its  commitment  to  universal  human rights.  It  also  cannot  be  overlooked  that  the  choice  to  promote  high-skilled Immigration  and  the  European  Left  287 migration  into  the  EU  to  ease  electoral  tensions  and  resolve  Europe’s  demo¬ graphic  problems  presents  a  serious  moral  dilemma.  Any  further  efforts  to draw  human  capital  away  from  labor-exporting  poorer  countries  are  likely to  have  their  own  negative  impact  on  precisely  those  areas  of  the  world  from which  economic  migrants  in  general  seek  to  flee.  Thus  efforts  to  alter  the politics  of  immigration  in  Europe  by  getting  the  “right”  kinds  of  immigrants not  only  places  left  governments  in  an  awkward  moral  position.  It  may  also indirectly  help  to  perpetuate  the  conditions  in  poorer  countries  that  have produced  large-scale  immigration  in  the  first  place,  along  with  the  resulting dilemmas  from  which  parties  of  the  left  are  seeking  to  escape. Notes 1.  Inglehart  (1971)  links  post-materialism  to  the  emergence  of  a  cosmopolitan  po¬ litical  identity  and  sense  of  social  solidarity. 2.  After  the  last  two  EU  enlargements,  many  of  the  traditional  EU  member  states also  experienced  significant  immigration  from  new  EU  member  states,  including Poland  and  Romania.  The  distinction  here  is  drawn  because  intra-EU  migration  can¬ not  be  directly  restricted  beyond  a  transition  period  that  follows  a  home  country’s  ac¬ cession  to  the  EU.  Most  of  the  leeway  for  controlling  immigration  that  EU  governments have  involves  immigrants  who  are  not  citizens  of  other  EU  member  states. 3.  See  for  instance  Hammar  1999,  174,  on  Sweden,  Campbell  ed.  1992,  451-56,  on Switzerland,  and  Castles  1986. 4.  The  Commonwealth  Immigrants  Act  (1962),  passed  by  a  Conservative  gov¬ ernment,  made  the  right  of  abode  for  Commonwealth  citizens  contingent  upon  a government-issued  work  permit.  After  coming  to  power  in  1964  Labour  continued  and intensified  the  Conservatives’  move  by  drastically  cutting  work  vouchers  and  passing the  Commonwealth  Immigrants  Act  (1968),  which  sought  to  halt  the  influx  of  migrants from  African  Commonwealth  states. 5.  Regierungserklarung  des  zweiten  Kabinetts  Brandt/Scheel  vom  18.  January  1973 (Bonn:  Presse-  und  Informationsamt  der  Bundesregierung,  1973),  46.  Author’s  transla¬ tion. 6.  In  Germany,  for  example,  access  to  the  labor  market  was  eliminated  for  those seeking  asylum  decisions  at  the  same  time  as  cash  benefits  were  cut.  The  immigra¬ tion  bill  of  2002  (see  more  below)  also  required  schools,  doctors,  and  officials  to  pass on  information  about  possibly  illegal  migrants,  eliminated  access  to  publicly  funded healthcare  for  those  overstaying  their  visa  and  their  dependents,  and  even  reduced legal  immigrants’  access  to  benefits  such  as  child-rearing  family  allowances. 7.  The  results  and  methods  are  available  in  Perez  and  Fernandez-Albertos  2009. 8.  Annual  figures  for  France  are  not  available,  but  just  a  comparison  of  the  census data  on  the  number  of  foreigners  residing  legally  in  France  every  five  years  suggests that  the  trend  there  has  been  toward  zero  net  growth  in  the  number  of  foreigners  re- 288  Perez siding  legally  in  France,  and  that  this  did  not  change  during  years  of  Socialist  govern¬ ment. 9.  The  share  of  the  population  in  Germany  and  Austria  that  was  foreign  born  well outranked  that  of  France  (8.1%)  and  even  Britain  (9.7%)  in  2005.  See  OECD  2oo7e. 10.  See  Maier-Braun  2006.  Schmidt  made  the  statement  at  a  press  conference  on 11  November  1981. 11.  The  perception  that  German  society  would  not  be  able  to  integrate  Muslim  im¬ migrants  in  particular  was  often  articulated  by  the  chancellor,  including  in  some  of his  later  recollections  of  this  period.  See  “Altkanzler  Schmidt:  Die  Anwerbung  von Gastarbeitern  war  falsch Frankfurter  Allgemeine  Zeitung,  24  November  2004.  See  also “Helmut  Schmidt:  Multikulturelle  Gesellschaft  ‘Illusion  von  Intellektuellen,’”  Die  Zeit, 22  April  2004. 12.  Roger  Cohen,  “Schroeder’s  New  Politics  Tripped  Up  by  Hesse  Voters,”  New  York Times,  8  February  1999. 13.  This  figure  is  calculated  by  subtracting  the  pre-2000  level  of  roughly  50,000 naturalizations  per  year  from  the  higher  figures  in  the  six  years  following  the  new  citi¬ zenship  law  before  naturalization  figures  returned  to  their  historical  path. 14.  For  details  on  the  course  of  the  negotiations  of  the  first  Schily  Law  see  the monthly  EFMS  (Europaisches  Forum  fur  Migrationsstudien)  Migration  Reports  for October  2001  to  June  2002. 15.  The  addition  of  these  new  criteria  was  also  mandated  by  an  EU  directive.  For more  details  on  the  second  immigration  law  taking  effect  on  1  January  2005  see  the EFMS  Migration  Report  for  July  2004. 16.  The  restrictive  turn  in  Labour’s  stance  on  immigration  is  widely  attributed  to  the lessons  drawn  from  an  unexpected  defeat  in  the  Labour  stronghold  district  of  Smeth¬ wick  to  a  Conservative  candidate  running  on  an  anti-immigrant  platform  in  1964  (see Karapin  1999).  According  to  Hansen  (1999)  it  also  reflected  “a  triumph  of  Callaghan’s strand  of  Labour  ideology— nationalist,  anti-intellectual,  indifferent  to  international law  and  obligation  and  firmly  in  touch  with  the  social  conservatism  of  middle-  and working-class  Britain”  (822). 17.  Estimates  of  Italy’s  illegal  immigrant  population  vary  widely,  from  as  few  as 200,000  to  one  million  (Jandl  2008). 18.  “Mission  by  Sea  over  Illegal  Migrants,”  Economist,  3  May  2008. 19.  The  number  of  permits  issued  consistently  exceeds  the  quotas,  which  are  used  to negotiate  controls  on  illegal  immigration  with  sending  countries. 20.  In  Italy  the  immigrant  offices  of  the  labor  unions  play  an  important  role  in  facili¬ tating  the  integration  of  immigrants;  their  work  includes  sanctioning  the  applications for  residence  permits  of  “self-employed”  immigrants  (see  Veikou  and  Triandafyllidou 2004).  In  Spain  annual  quotas  for  work-based  immigration  are  set  after  consultation with  employers  and  unions. 21.  Some  authors  attribute  this  to  the  “familial”  underpinning  of  social  policy  in these  countries.  Yet  this  explanation  seems  to  be  contradicted  by  far  higher  levels  of public  daycare  provision  and  by  an  important  increase  in  Spain  in  recent  years  in  pub- Immigration  and  the  European  Left  289 lie  spending  on  early  childcare.  Other  explanations  include  the  high  level  of  spending on  old-age  pensions  in  Italy  and  the  relatively  late  development  of  a  comprehensive welfare  state  in  Spain  during  a  period  of  fiscal  retrenchment. 22.  I  thank  George  Ross  for  putting  this  point  to  me. 23.  See  David  Rieff,  “Battle  over  the  Banlieues,”  New  York  Times  Magazine,  15  April 2007,  and  “Immigration:  Malaise  et  surenchere  ,”  Le  Monde,  20  March  2007. 24.  Markus  Deggerich,  “Einwanderung:  Die  Angst  der  Parteien  vor  der  Wahl,”  Der Spiegel,  30  January  2001. 25.  See  for  instance  EFMS  Migration  Report,  January  and  February  2003;  Ette  2003, 410-46;  and  Charles  Hawley,  “Letter  from  Berlin:  German  Conservatives  Bicker  over Integration  (Again),”  Der  Spiegel  Online  International,  2  January  2008.  Another prominent  example  is  offered  by  the  conflict  between  the  French  interior  minister, Charles  Pasqua,  and  the  social  affairs  minister,  Simone  Weil,  which  resulted  in  a  seri¬ ous  rift  within  Edouard  Bahadur’s  government  in  1993.  See  Hollifield  1999. 26.  EFMS  Migration  Reports,  March  2001  and  January  2002;  Ette  2003;  and  Migra¬ tion  News  (University  of  California,  Davis)  8,  no.  4  (October  2002). The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left A  Political  Family  under  Construction Jean-Michel  De  Waele  and  Sorina  Soare The  destruction  of  the  Berlin  Wall  has  had  an  influence  well  beyond  the  po¬ litical  boundaries  of  former  “people’s  democracies,”  directly  challenging  left and  center-left  parties  all  over  the  world.  The  most  common  forecast  of  the early  1990s  was  that  “socialism  was  dead  and  that  none  of  its  variants  could be  revived”  (Dahrendorf  1990,  38).  Eastern  Europe  during  the  following  years thus  rapidly  became  a  breeding  ground  for  neoliberal  and  pro-market  ideas and  an  endemic  “allergy”  to  the  left.  The  main  dilemma  that  the  new  democ¬ racies  faced  was  how  to  bolster  the  legitimacy  of  their  new  regimes.  Anti¬ communist  elites  advocated  total  condemnation  of  the  past,  with  “lustration laws”  to  purge  remnants  and  reminders  of  it  that  were  based,  it  would  seem, on  an  underestimate  of  how  completely  Marxist  ideologies  had  disappeared (Hermet  and  Marcou  1998;  Mink  and  Szurek  1998;  Teitel  2000;  Letki  2002; Stan  2002;  David  2003).  An  astute  observation  about  Bulgaria  works  for  the entire  region,  save  the  Czech  Republic:  “None  of  [Marxism’s]  postulates,  its main  policy  recommendations  such  as  central  planning,  completely  admin¬ istratively  controlled  prices,  obligatory  employment,  state  property,  collec¬ tivism,  proletarian  dominance  through  one-party  rule,  were  left  standing” (Ganev  2005,  444).  This  was  also,  of  course,  a  moment  when  the  western  left faced  its  own  crisis  because  of  the  end  of  Fordism,  shifting  class  structures and  the  weakening  of  class,  changing  voting  trends,  the  coming  of  “post¬ materialist”  rivals,  and  the  crisis  of  the  welfare  state  (Callaghan  and  Tun- ney  2001,  63).  Some  scholars  even  argued  that  the  end  of  the  twentieth  cen¬ tury  could  make  traditional  socialism  and  even  social  democracy  impossible everywhere  (Przeworski  and  Sprague  1986). The  direction  and  extent  of  Eastern  European  transformations  were  also much  constrained  by  the  prospect  of  joining  the  European  Union.  Demo¬ cratic  politics  were  essential  for  membership  in  the  EU,  and  this  obliged  the The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  291 post-communist  lefts  to  declare  more  or  less  complete  allegiance  to  market- oriented  programs  in  ways  which  disregarded  traditional  left  concerns  (Agh 2004).  These  constraints  also  seemed  likely  to  prevent  new  lefts  from  emerg¬ ing  and  to  hasten  the  departure  of  older  ones.  Parties  of  the  left  and  center- left  in  central  and  eastern  Europe  were  thus  left  to  transform  themselves  in  an inhospitable  environment,  and  very  few  observers  or  participants  anticipated the  resurrection  of  communist  parties.  Thus  while  in  Romania  the  National Salvation  Front  (FSN)  and  in  Bulgaria  the  Bulgarian  Socialist  Party  (BSP),  suc¬ cessor  parties  to  the  communists,  managed  to  stay  in  power  after  1989  and even  win  the  first  free  elections,  in  most  other  places  the  past  was  brutally rejected.  Successor  parties  in  Poland,  Hungary,  and  Czechoslovakia  all  lost their  first  electoral  contests.  Yet  after  starting  as  an  endangered  species,  these successor  parties  would  in  fairly  short  order  become  stunning  success  stories.1 Democratization  also  brought  traditional  social  democracy  back  to  life after  years  in  exile.  Parties  such  as  the  Czech  Social  Democratic  Party  (CSSD), the  Romanian  Social-Democratic  Party  (PSDR),  and  the  Hungarian  MSzDP were  good  examples.  These  parties  had  been  repressed  or  forcibly  incorpo¬ rated  into  Soviet-sponsored  communist  parties  after  the  Communists  seized power  in  the  late  1940s.  Forty  years  later,  in  the  first  democratic  elections,  they seemed  set  for  a  political  comeback.  Their  success  proved  limited,  because weak  organizations  and  inexperienced  leaderships  hampered  their  visibility and  limited  their  electoral  relevance  (Waller  1995,  478).  They  were  in  most cases  destined  to  disappear  during  the  1990s  or  merge  with  ex-Communist rivals.  The  exception  was  the  Czech  Social  Democrats  (CSSD),  which  be¬ came  one  of  the  most  stable  center-left  parties  in  the  region.  Another  group of  hybrid  or  highly  specific  and  localized  left  parties  emerged,  like  Smer  in Slovakia,  led  by  Robert  Fico,  a  charismatic  former  reform-Communist.  And some  parties  like  the  Communist  Party  of  Bohemia  and  Moravia  (KSCM),  its Slovak  counterpart  the  Party  of  the  Democratic  Left  (SDL),  and  the  Romanian Socialist  Labor  Party  (PSM),  chose  not  to  drop  their  old  ideology  and  instead made  but  minor  programmatic  revisions  to  fit  the  new  democratic  institu¬ tional  framework.  The  Czech  party  has  been  the  only  success  story  in  this category. This  chapter  surveys  the  post-communist  left  or  center-left  spectrum  in Bulgaria,  the  Czech  Republic,  Hungary,  Poland,  Romania,  and  Slovakia.  Its main  goal  is  to  assess  whether  the  evolution  of  these  parties  will  be  marked by  a  long  and  quiet  path  toward  lasting  success  or  rather  enduring  weakness, indicated  by  their  current  electoral  problems.  In  light  of  these  questions,  the bulk  of  the  chapter  focuses  on  electoral  results  from  the  early  1990s  through 2008.  Later  we  shall  consider  internal  and  external  stimuli  leading  to  the  re- 292  De  Waele  and  Soare invention  of  parties  more  generally  in  the  region  and  reflect  upon  the  likeli¬ hood  of  their  long-term  success. Before  we  begin  our  analysis  we  need  to  clarify  certain  conceptual  issues. At  a  comparative  level  we  see  a  distinct  evolutionary  pattern.  During  the initial  post-communist  transition  at  the  start  of  the  1990s,  the  political  con¬ text  blocked  the  emergence  of  parties,  either  left  or  right,  with  real  ideolo¬ gies  that  translated  into  programs  and  policies  for  well-defined  electorates. Instead  these  were  years  of  high  politics,  when  debates  were  about  the  past, the  large  changes  to  be  undertaken,  and  the  positions  of  different  countries in  international  affairs.  In  these  conditions  both  right  and  left  became  stuck in  rhetorical  postures  with  few  clear  and  realistic  alternatives,  and  the  region embraced  a  politics  based  on  a  superficial  consensus  in  favor  of  democracy and  Europe,  in  which  most  other  problems  became  secondary. In  these  circumstances  left-of-center  parties  faced  a  threefold  rebuilding task.  Ex-communist  parties  first  had  to  demonstrate  acceptance  of  new  demo¬ cratic  rules,  including  explicit  renunciation  of  their  earlier  monopoly  status and  a  willingness  to  live  in  a  new  multiparty  world.  Next  they  had  to  carry out  organizational  restructurings  which  included  a  massive  loss  of  exist¬ ing  members,  made  more  difficult  by  the  emergence  of  a  new  generation  of leaders  whose  presence  did  not  help  public  visibility  and  recognition.  Finally, the  parties  needed  to  rebuild  their  programs,  abandoning  the  principles  of Marxism-Leninism  and  importing  ideological  platforms  from  western  Euro¬ pean  social  democrats. By  the  middle  of  the  1990s  the  return  of  left  parties  to  power  had  de¬ manded  constructing  a  new  image  as  “competent  agents  of  change”  that would  distinguish  them  from  parties  of  the  right,  using  arguments  that  it  was better  to  have  “a  steady  hand  at  the  wheel  rather  than  inexperienced  learner- drivers”  (Hough  2005,  5).  By  this  point  their  initial  weak  democratic  legiti¬ macy  seemed  for  the  moment  overcome,  and  in  all  the  countries  we  analyze, ex-communist  parties  had  begun  to  demonstrate  a  political  professionalism and  organizational  coherence  that  gave  them  substantial  claims  on  elector¬ ates.  Problems  in  the  program  persisted  nonetheless.  With  a  few  exceptions the  role  of  the  government  party  constrained  them  to  follow  rhythms  of  re¬ form  coordinated  by  the  EU  and  international  creditor  organizations.  No  mat¬ ter  what  happened  at  elections,  therefore,  political  agendas  were  dominated by  needs  to  guarantee  stabilization  that  necessitated  policies  of  economic liberalization  and  privatization  and  brought  extensive  social  costs.2  In  such  a situation,  “while  there  may  be  a  clear  social-democratic  profile  in  program¬ matic  documents  and  electoral  campaigns,  this  does  not  necessarily  have  any bearing  to  the  actual  policies  of  a  party  in  government”  (Dauderstadt,  Gerrits, and  Markus  [1999]  as  cited  in  Paterson  and  Sloam  2005,  37). The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  293 Thus  however  different  parties’  genealogies,  social  democracy  often  be¬ came  an  empty  label.  The  parties  were  caught  between  their  positions  man¬ aging  democratization  and  economic  reform  and  historic  affinities  for  taking care  of  those  less  well-off.  These  parties  also  came  to  contain  numerous  suc¬ cessful  “red”  millionaire  entrepreneurs,  and  their  policies  often  sacrificed social  commitments  for  fiscal  rectitude.  Moreover,  pro-European  positions were  often  mainly  electoral  slogans,  open  to  competing  interpretations  of  the EU’s  policies  and  its  future  that  were  vague  and  slippery.  In  brief,  with  the exception  of  the  Czech  communists  in  the  KSCM,  the  central  characteristics of  social  democracy  — its  social  values  and  its  ties  with  trade  unions  and  the working  class  — became  at  best  elements  in  campaign  rhetoric.3  “Policy  trans¬ fers”  from  western  social  democracy  were  typically  superficial  and  meant mainly  to  establish  credentials  in  the  eyes  of  European  allies.  In  this  context it  must  be  asked  whether  one  is  discussing  a  real  political  family,  with  organic links  to  the  peoples,  societies,  and  classes  whose  interests  it  purported  to  rep¬ resent.4 The  parties’  genealogical  patchwork  does  not  in  itself  preclude  a  positive answer,  but  it  does  imply  the  likelihood  of  profound  differences  between these  different  social  democrats  operating  in  different  national  party  sys¬ tems.5  Virtually  all  the  successor  parties  quickly  began  to  label  themselves “center-left,”  with  rather  more  weight  placed  on  centrism.  Ties  to  the  broader social  democratic  family  were  nevertheless  typically  used  to  demonstrate democratic  credentials  and  not  to  inform  program  or  policy.  Therefore  the family  in  general  was  a  heterogeneous  group  of  parties  who  from  the  outset renounced  commitments  to  equality  and  social  justice  in  favor  of  pragma¬ tism.  Left-wing  activism  and  a  political  culture  oriented  to  the  left  were  quite absent,  and  the  parties  came  to  be  dominated  more  by  charismatic  leaders than  by  particular  political  appeals.  The  discourses  traditionally  associated with  social  democracy  have  for  that  reason  turned  out  to  be  of  little  use  in mobilizing  supporters,  particularly  in  the  face  of  growing  competition  from populist  parties  claiming  to  defend  the  “rights  of  the  poorest  and  weakest.” Today’s  economic  crisis  has  made  even  clearer  this  long  pattern  of  conver¬ gence  between  the  left  and  the  populist  and  often  nationalist  parties,  most notably  on  issues  of  guaranteeing  minimum  social  standards. Successor  Parties:  An  Electorally  Resistant  Species? In  the  aftermath  of  1989  new  competitive  electoral  markets  boosted  domes¬ tic  and  international  confidence  in  the  democratization  process  (Linz  and Stepan  1996).  Except  in  Romania  and  Bulgaria,  during  the  first  Central  and Eastern  European  free  elections,  lefts— social  democrats,  successor  parties, 294  De  Waele  and  Soare Table  1.  Percentage  of  Votes  Cast  in  Parliamentary  Elections,  1990-2007 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994  1995 1996 Bulgaria KPB 0.7 1.5 BSP 47.2 33.1 43.5™ EVROLEV Czech  Republic KSCM 13.2 14.0 10.3 CSSD 4.1 6.5 26.4 Hungary MSZP 10.9 32.6 Poland SLD 11.9 20.4 UP 2.1 7.2 Romania PSM 3.1 2.2 PS 2.3 PDSR/PSD 66.3 27.7 21.5 PSDR 0.5 20.2 (2) 12.9 (3) PD 10.2 Slovakia KSS 0.8 2.7 SDL 13.3 14.7 10.4 (4) SMER 1.  In  coalition  with  the  Bulgarian  Agrarian  People’s  Union,  Alexander  Stanboliski,  and  Ecoglas- nost. 2.  Part  of  the  Democratic  Convention,  the  PSDR  obtains  only  ten  deputies  and  one  senator  out of  the  sixty-two  CDR  mandates. 3.  The  Social  Democratic  Alliance  unites  the  PD  and  the  PSDR. 4.  The  Party  of  the  Democratic  Left  is  part  of  the  coalition  Common  Choice,  which  also  includes the  Social  Democratic  Party  of  Slovakia,  the  Farmers  movement,  and  other  small  political  parties. 5.  Starting  with  the  2001  elections  the  Coalition  for  Bulgaria  unites  the  BSP  and  a  number  of smaller  leftist  formations  such  as  the  Party  of  Bulgarian  Social  Democrats,  the  Bulgarian  Agrarian and  others— suffered  severe  electoral  defeats,  results  that  did  not  promise brilliant  futures  (table  1).  Yet  a  brief  few  years  later  the  defeated  parties  “took advantage  of  a  . . .  political  environment  where  weak  competitors  systemati¬ cally  made  strategic  mistakes”  (Hough  2005,  4).  Left  successor  parties  were geared  toward  power,  ready  to  agree  to  programmatic  compromises,  and eager  to  occupy  central  roles  in  the  new  political  game,  which  they  soon proved  able  to  do. The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  295 1997  1998  1999  2000  2001  2002  2003  2004  2005  2006  2007 1.3 17.2® 30.9® 21.9™ 5.6 0.9 1.3 12.8 11.0 18.5 32.3 32.3 30.2 43.2 32.9 42.0 27.1 41.0 11.3 13.0® 4.7 3.9 0.7 0.2 21.5® 36.6 7.0 31.5 2.8 6.3 3.9 14.7 1.4 29.1® 13.5 People’s  Union  “Aleksander  Stambolijski,”  the  Movement  for  Social  Humanism,  and  the  Bulgarian Communist  Party. 6.  During  the  2007  elections  the  Left  and  Democrats  coalition  unites  the  Democratic  Left  Alli¬ ance,  the  Social  Democracy  of  Poland,  the  Labour  Union  and  the  Democratic  Party. 7.  Initially  part  of  the  electoral  alliance  with  the  PSD,  the  PSDR  merges  with  the  PSD  in  2001. 8.  The  Party  of  the  Democratic  Left  merges  with  the  Smer  in  2005. Source:  www.europe-politique.eu,  http:^cdp. binghamton.edu/era/searchera.html,  http://www .essex.ac.uk/elections. Growth  and  Decline  of  the  Polish  Democratic  Party In  chronological  perspective,  the  Polish  story  began  in  the  late  1980s  with  the Polish  Round  Table.  Intricate  negotiations  between  the  Polish  United  Workers Party  (PZPR),  sponsored  by  the  regime,  and  Solidarnosc  were  supposed  to lead  to  partial  liberalization  and  not  wholesale  democratic  transition.  Soli¬ darnosc  and  opposition  parties  were  allowed  to  run  for  35%  of  the  seats  in Sejm,  while  voting  for  the  upper  chamber  was  completely  open.  Despite  these precautionary  measures  “Solidarity’s  sweeping  electoral  success  sounded  the death  knell  of  communism”  (Millard  2003,  25).  By  the  end  of  1989  the  Polish 296  De  Waele  and  Soare Workers  Party  had  been  dissolved  and  Alexander  Kwasniewski  elected  the leader  of  its  successor,  the  Democratic  Left  Alliance  (SLD),  in  parallel  with  the coming  of  a  multiparty  system  and  completely  free  elections  in  1991.  Owing to  the  lack  of  credibility  of  parties  associated  with  the  past  and  the  predomi¬ nance  of  pro-market  discourses,  voters  then  gave  massive  support  to  parties opposed  to  communism,  with  the  SLD  obtaining  only  12%. After  the  post-1989  coalitions  fell  apart,  early  elections  were  called  in 1993.  With  functioning  democratic  institutions  in  place,  political  debate  was centered  around  the  introduction  of  property  rights,  the  pace  of  economic  re¬ form,  inflation,  and  unemployment.  The  SLD  and  the  agrarian  Polish  People’s Party  (PSL),  neither  of  which  disputed  the  need  for  change,  pledged  gentler economic  reforms  that  would  be  accompanied  by  increases  in  social  spend¬ ing.  The  elections,  held  under  new  electoral  laws,  thus  led  to  severe  losses for  the  other  parliamentary  parties,  while  the  SLD,  with  20%,  came  in  first and  formed  a  new  government  with  the  PSL.  The  defeat  of  the  center-right was  caused  mainly  by  hardships  tied  to  the  reforms  promoted  under  Leszek Balcerowicz,  which  had  made  voters  impatient  and  desirous  of  less  harsh reforms.  One  of  the  explicit  goals  of  the  Democratic  Left,  which  drew  its  in¬ spiration  from  the  German  SPD,  was  to  build  a  welfare  state  and  implement social  programs  robust  enough  to  provide  protection  through  the  economic transition  period  (Buras  2005,  92).  Likewise,  the  party  distinguished  itself from  others  in  the  party  system  by  its  secularist  positions,  like  those  defend¬ ing  the  rights  of  women  and  sexual  minorities. It  was  not  only  economic  problems  that  lay  behind  the  electoral  shift toward  the  ex-communists,  for  there  was  also  a  practical  issue  of  credi¬ bility.  The  Democratic  Left  (SLD)  was  an  organized  party  with  professional elites  energized  by  young  leaders  promoting  secular  values.  The  anticommu¬ nist  parties,  in  contrast,  had  discredited  themselves  with  nationalistic,  pro- Catholic  discourses  and  political  amateurism.  The  “pro-SLD”  air  du  temps continued  into  the  presidential  elections  of  1995,  which  saw  Lech  Walesa,  the historical  leader  of  Solidarnosc,  face  off  against  the  SLD  leader  Aleksander Kwasniewski,  who  won  a  surprising  victory  with  51%  of  the  vote. After  this  a  pattern  of  regular  electoral  rotation  seemed  to  take  over.  De¬ spite  continuous  economic  reforms  and  Poland’s  image  as  Eastern  Europe’s economic  “tiger,”  the  next  elections  in  1997  were  won  by  Solidarity  Elec¬ toral  Action  (AWS).  Four  years  later,  with  16%  unemployment  and  very high  budget  deficits,  voters  focused  on  the  ills  of  the  Polish  economy  and turned  sharply  against  the  center-right  coalition.  The  results  were  a  lim¬ ited  victory  for  the  reformed  communists  and  the  complete  removal  of  the AWS  from  Parliament.  The  Democratic  Left  (SLD),  in  alliance  with  the  small The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  29 7 Table  2.  Membership  of  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  Parties Individual Membership Total National Membership Individual Membership as  Percentage of  National Membership Bulgaria1 BSP 2002- 210,000 444,700 47.2 2003 Czech  Republic2 KSCM 1993 350,000 545,000 64.2 1999 160,000 319,800 50 CSSD 1993 13,000 545,000 2.4 1999 18,000 319,800 5.6 Hungary2 MSZP 1993 59,000 165,300 35.7 1999 39,000 173,600 22.5 Poland2 SLD 2000 87,000 326,500 26.7 UP 2000 5,000 326,500 1.5 Romania3 PSD 2001 309,714 — 2003 300,000 1,735,430 17.3 2002 699,431 — 2004 607,412 — PD 1998 135,288 — 2002 117,000 1,735,430 6.7 Slovakia2 SDL 1994 27,600 127,500 21.7 2000 21,223 165,277 12.9 Sources:  1.  Spirova  2005,  606;  2.  Mair  and  Van  Biezen  2001, 17-18;  3.  Soare  and  Preda  2008,  79. center-left  Labor  Union  and  the  People’s  Party,  formed  the  new  governing  co¬ alition. Starting  in  the  mid-1990s  the  SLD  focused  most  on  macro-policy  issues  and on  reinforcing  its  organization  under  the  leadership  of  Leszek  Miller  (Millard 2003,  36).  For  almost  a  decade  no  other  party  could  match  the  SLD  either  in territorial  strength  or  in  membership  (table  2).  This  pattern  was  not  peculiar to  Poland,  and  scholars  have  often  pointed  to  ex-communist  parties’  superi¬ ority  in  membership,  territorial  organization,  and  material  resources  (Szczer- biak  1999;  Szczerbiak  2001;  Van  Biezen  2003;  Lewis  2003).  Most  new  parties tended  to  be  concentrated  in  urban  areas  and  among  a  young  and  educated electorate,  but  the  SLD  had  a  socially  broader  and  more  widespread  network. In  its  internal  life  the  leader  was  the  party’s  major  cornerstone.  In  time,  the party  gradually  consolidated  an  image  of  pragmatism  that  looked  more  to  its 298  De  Waele  and  Soare voters  than  its  members  (Buras  2005,  88).  In  the  longer  run,  however,  the  fra¬ gility  and  superficiality  of  its  organizational  structure  and  clientelistic  rela¬ tionships  between  leaders  and  members  weakened  the  party’s  electoral  grip. Corruption  became  systemic  and  a  series  of  scandals  rocked  the  party,  in¬ ducing  a  hemorrhage  of  members  and  the  creation  of  a  splinter  party,  Polish Social  Democracy  (SdPl). In  2005  the  Democratic  Left  (SLD)  was  therefore  moved  to  restate  its  offi¬ cial  stance:  “We  want  a  Poland  that  is  just,  democratic,  tolerant ....  Poland must  be  a  country  for  everyone,  and  not  just  for  the  chosen  few.  We  want a  strong  and  efficient  state  in  equalizing  opportunities  for  Poles,  sensitive to  human  pain,  exploitation  and  inequality.  We  want  a  Poland  that  is  open, European  and  proud  of  its  history,  treated  without  falsification  and  conceal¬ ment.  We  want  a  Poland  that  does  not  forget  the  achievements  of  45  years  of the  People’s  Republic  and  without  nationalistic,  right-wing  fictions.”6  Social policy  proposals,  Pro-Europeanism,  and  anti-nationalist  arguments  were  thus central  to  the  program.  Electoral  results  nonetheless  confirmed  the  relative decline  of  the  SLD  that  had  been  identified  in  various  pre-election  surveys. The  collapse  of  the  coalition  led  by  Jaroslaw  Kaczynski  led  to  early  elec¬ tions  in  2007  and  seemed  to  offer  a  chance  for  redemption  to  the  SLD.  The final  competition  was  between  the  Law  and  Justice  (PiS)  and  Civic  Platform (PO)  parties,  while  the  SLD  and  other  left-of-center  parties  formed  a  new grouping,  the  Left  and  Democrats  (LiD),  which  to  its  dismay  obtained  merely 13.15%  of  the  votes  (fifty-five  seats  in  the  Sejm  and  none  in  the  Senate). More  than  twenty  years  after  the  Berlin  Wall  fell,  the  Polish  left  is  at  a crossroads  in  a  political  landscape  where  the  right  is  now  predominant.  Popu¬ list  parties  have  challenged  the  center-left’s  credibility,  while  internal  con¬ flicts  and  scandals  have  progressively  undermined  it.  Despite  efforts  in  2007 to  forge  a  coherent  message  and  Kwasniewski’s  personal  comeback,  the  LiD clearly  needs  both  programmatic  and  organizational  reshaping.  The  coalition and  its  constituent  parties  have  had  consistent  problems  creating  an  iden¬ tity  for  themselves,  even  if  they  have  continued  to  advertise  their  interest  in policies  tied  to  work  and  social  rights,  secularization,  and  building  a  social Europe. The  Hungarian  Socialist  Party:  Constancy  and  Compromise Hungary  was  the  second  communist  state  to  breathe  the  air  of  democracy. Liberalization  had  started  after  the  Budapest  revolt  of  1956  with  the  aban¬ donment  of  Stalinist  positions  on  social  matters  and  the  implementation  of cautious  economic  reforms  to  enlarge  and  consolidate  the  legitimacy  of  the The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  299 regime.  Despite  these  changes,  beneath  the  official  consensus  an  opposi¬ tion  quickly  organized,  and  by  1987  the  monopoly  of  the  Hungarian  Socialist Workers’  Party  (MSzMP)  had  been  broken.  The  Hungarian  Democratic  Forum (MDF)  was  created,  followed  by  the  Alliance  of  Free  Democrats  (SzDSz)  and the  Hungarian  Civic  Union  (FIDESZ)  (Pittaway  2003,  58).  The  Hungarian  case is  thus  unusual  because  the  reformed  successor  party  “emerged  before  the collapse  of  the  state  socialism  and  not  after  .  .  .  and  played  a  very  active  and instrumental  role  in  bringing  down  the  former  system”  (Agh  1995,  492).  By the  end  of  the  1980s  a  widening  gap  had  isolated  hardliners  among  the  com¬ munists  (MSzMP),  Janos  Kadar  had  been  removed  from  the  leadership,  and almost  one-third  of  the  Central  Committee  had  been  replaced. Negotiations  in  June  1989  between  the  democratic  opposition  and  the ruling  Communist  Party  led  to  the  first  free  elections  in  1990.  By  September 1989  the  Hungarian  Socialist  Party  (MSzP)  had  become  the  successor  to  the Communist  Party,  carrying  over  a  majority  of  the  party  elite,  rank  and  file, and  resources  (Van  Biezen  2003, 124).  Continuity  gave  the  party  an  important advantage  in  territorial  network,  financial  assets,  and  real  estate.  But  there was  a  break  at  the  organizational  level.  The  new  MSzP  adopted  a  flexible  or¬ ganizational  model  based  on  secret-ballot  voting  and  decentralized  selection procedures  (Agh  1995,  493).  Thus,  “in  line  with  the  party’s  aspiration  to  bury the  organizational  model  of  the  past . . .  the  MSzP  was  quite  loosely  organized and  its  organizational  structure  scarcely  formalized”  (Van  Biezen  2003, 125). Membership  was  never  the  top  priority  of  the  new  party  (table  2),  in  part  be¬ cause  only  about  2%  of  the  Hungarian  electorate  belongs  to  any  party.  The ironic  effect  was  to  make  its  membership  relatively  large,  the  typical  mem¬ ber  being  “middle-aged,  male,  urban,  and  intellectual”  (Agh  1995,  498).  Pro¬ grammatically  the  MSzP’s  prime  concern  at  first  was  to  advocate  free-market policies  and  prove  its  loyalty  to  the  new  regime.  Especially  after  its  comeback in  1994  the  Socialists  (MSzP)  were  the  promoters  of  market  reforms  based  on austerity  and  rapid  privatization.  Their  foreign  policy  from  the  beginning  was open  and  internationalist,  replete  with  anti-nationalistic  and  Europhile  state¬ ments,  and  they  worked  to  separate  themselves  from  the  nationalism  regu¬ larly  promoted  by  their  opponents,  mainly  the  Civic  Union  (FIDESZ). Like  other  countries  in  the  region,  in  the  early  1990s  Hungary  experi¬ enced  the  perverse  consequences  of  economic  reform.  Despite  support  by the  Democratic  Forum  (MDF)  for  gradual  economic  transformation,  the  coun¬ try’s  transition  proved  difficult.  GDP  declined  and  there  was  a  deterioration  in living  standards.  Conflicts  inside  the  government  and  the  amateurism  of  new, non-communist  elites  accentuated  the  climate  of  distrust.  In  the  elections  of 1994,  held  during  an  economic  slump,  the  Socialist  Party’s  organizational  net- 300  De  Waele  and  Soare work  and  its  renewed  party  elite  attracted  ordinary  voters  and  even  seduced its  former  enemy,  the  Alliance  of  Free  Democrats  (SzDSz).  Like  its  Polish counterpart,  the  main  successor  party  used  its  policymaking  and  administra¬ tive  experience  as  key  assets  (Grzymala-Busse  2002,  138).  But  once  back  in power  it  was  obliged  by  international  lenders  to  cut  social  spending;  and  in the  years  that  followed,  Hungary  had  one  of  the  highest  unemployment  rates in  the  entire  post-communist  region.  During  its  time  in  power,  allied  with  the liberals  in  SzDSz,  the  party  thus  became  the  advocate  of  austerity  and  worked to  dismantle  the  institutions  of  the  state  economy.7  These  economic  reforms eventually  paid  off,  and  by  1997  GDP  had  started  to  rise.  The  credibility  of  the MSzP  government  was  nonetheless  hurt  by  austerity  and  corruption  scandals while,  in  parallel,  the  opposition  had  already  begun  to  reorganize. The  electoral  campaign  in  1998  was  dominated  by  the  charisma  and  popu¬ lism  of  Viktor  Orban,  the  leader  of  FIDESZ.  Until  a  few  weeks  before  the  elec¬ tions  the  Socialists  seemed  likely  to  be  reelected,  but  the  party  won  only  134 seats  versus  148  for  FIDESZ.  The  MSzP  held  on  to  33%  of  the  vote  and  its  domi¬ nance  in  traditional  industrialized  districts,  but  opposition  unity  made  the difference.  Whereas  in  1994  fragmentation  of  the  right  had  helped  the  center- left,  four  years  later  a  unified  opposition  blocked  its  reelection.  In  2002  and again  in  2006  FIDESZ,  which  was  becoming  a  standard  center-right  party, and  the  MSzP  progressively  reinforced  their  electoral  power  while  the  other parties  were  falling  apart.8  In  an  almost  bipolar  electoral  market  in  2002,  the MSzP  in  alliance  with  the  Free  Democrats  (SzDSz)  gathered  a  limited  ma¬ jority  with  198  seats.  The  same  formula  worked  in  2006,  and  the  MSzP-SzDSz coalition  won  210  seats  in  Parliament. After  the  forced  resignation  of  Prime  Minister  Peter  Medgyessy,  the  Social¬ ists  installed  the  young  businessman  Ferenc  Gyurcsany,  one  of  the  richest men  in  Hungary,  as  its  leader.  Under  his  stewardship  the  party  adopted  a Blairite  “third  way”  agenda.  The  MSzP  soon  joined  an  exclusive  club  of  post¬ communist  parties  to  have  won  two  successive  elections  while  in  govern¬ ment.  Despite  numerous  scandals  and  riots  in  Budapest  in  2006,  the  MSzP seems  to  be  the  healthiest  left  party  in  the  region,  despite  organizational underdevelopment  and  an  ambiguous  programmatic  posture  between  cen¬ trism  and  liberal  policies. The  Hungarian  Socialists  (MSzP)  have  thus  been  in  office  for  more  than half  of  the  two  decades  of  post-communism,  and  they  are  one  of  the  most pro-European  parties  in  the  region,  with  a  history  of  compromise  between an  inherited  left  culture  and  an  ambition  to  win  elections.  Still,  the  future  re¬ mains  in  doubt.  Confronted  with  one  of  the  largest  budget  deficits  in  the  re¬ gion,  especially  after  2000,  the  party  has  been  forced  to  shift  policies  so  as  to The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  301 lower  public  spending,  a  policy  that  led  to  growing  criticism  among  its  sup¬ porters.  This  tense  situation  worsened  after  the  crisis  of  2006  and  especially in  2009  under  the  new  prime  minister  Gordon  Bajnai,  who  was  obliged  to  re¬ duce  wages,  raise  taxes,  and  cut  social  spending.  In  these  conditions  Jobbik (Movement  for  a  Better  Hungary),  a  right-wing  nationalist  party  that  had only  been  founded  in  2002,  became  more  and  more  important  and  registered a  significant  advance  in  the  European  elections  of  June  2009. Common  Origins  and  Divergent  Paths:  The  Czechoslovakian  Case Czechoslovakia  was  the  third  country  in  Eastern  and  Central  Europe  to be  swept  up  in  the  wave  of  democratization.  Besides  the  challenges  of  the “double  transitions”  to  democracy  and  free-market  capitalism,  the  country also  faced  a  serious  nationality  question  (Kuzio  2001).  After  a  “velvet  revo¬ lution,”  the  “velvet  divorce”  put  an  end  to  one  of  the  most  important  states in  the  entire  region  (De  Waele  1998,  49).  Czechoslovakia  has  been  regularly depicted  as  the  region’s  only  genuine  democracy  before  communism,  and ironically  it  was  the  one  country  where  the  Communist  Party  had  been  a  rele¬ vant  political  force  before  1948.  It  was  known  also  for  a  strong  social  demo¬ cratic  tradition  linked  to  the  Czechoslovak  Social  Democratic  Worker’s  Party (CSDSD)  and  Czechoslovak  Social  Democracy  (CSD).  In  Slovakia,  in  contrast, a  traditionally  rural  economy  and  the  strength  of  the  Catholic  Church  had prevented  the  emergence  of  a  strong  pre-war  left  party. In  1946  the  Czechoslovak  Communist  Party  (KSC)  had  won  38%  of  the votes  and  then  occupied  most  ministerial  posts.  Despite  this,  in  February  1948 the  party  chose  to  seize  power  in  brutal  fashion.  Twenty  years  later  troops from  five  Warsaw  Pact  countries  repressed  the  Prague  Spring  and  ended the  party’s  and  the  nation’s  attempts  to  reform  from  within.  The  once  well- rooted  ruling  party  then  experienced  a  progressive  decrease  in  membership. The  party  had  1.79  million  members  in  1948-49,  1.38  million  in  the  mid- 1950s,  and  only  1.17  million  by  the  1970s,  the  lowest  number  since  the  coup of  1948.  By  1987  party  membership  had  gone  back  up  to  1.61  million  (Stoica 2005,  703),  but  despite  this,  strong  demonstrations  in  1988  culminated  in  six weeks  of  protest  in  November  and  December.  In  the  same  period  the  Slovak branch  of  the  party  developed  a  softer  version  of  communism:  “far  away  from both  party  supervision  and  decision-making,  the  then  Young  Turks  from  the Bratislava-based  Institute  of  Marxism-Leninism,  Peter  Weiss  and  Pavol  Kanis, had  organized  seminars  to  discuss  the  social  and  economic  problems  of  so¬ ciety”  and  effectively  created  a  reformed  party  (Haughton  2005, 179).  These same  young  communist  leaders  would  be  in  charge  of  the  party  after  the  Vel- 302  De  Waele  and  Soare vet  Revolution.  The  bloodless  overthrow  of  the  communist  regime  initially gave  power  to  the  Civic  Forum  (OF)  and  the  Public  against  Violence  (VPN), while  the  former  ruling  party  remained  practically  unchanged  and  “retained much  of  its  orthodox  profile  in  both  ideological  and  organizational  terms, with  the  hardliners  within  the  party  successfully  withstanding  pressure  for change”  (Van  Biezen  2003, 136).  The  first  free  elections  in  June  1990  brought sweeping  victory  to  movements  and  parties  opposed  to  the  old  regime.  At the  same  time  divisions  between  Slovaks  and  Czechs  deepened,  and  after  the elections  of  1992  leaders  in  Prague  and  Bratislava  declared  the  dissolution  of the  former  Czechoslovak  Republic. No  fewer  than  twenty-two  parties  and  movements  registered  for  the  first free  elections.  Despite  everything  in  its  past,  the  Communist  Party  finished second  with  almost  14%  of  the  votes  (table  2).  The  Social  Democrats  (CSSD), who  had  been  forcibly  merged  with  the  Communists  but  were  now  newly  in¬ dependent,  failed  at  the  national  level  to  reach  the  5%  threshold  required  to win  parliamentary  representation  in  the  country’s  proportional  electoral  sys¬ tem  (Van  Biezen  2003,  135).  Initially  hesitating  between  functioning  within the  Civic  Forum  and  establishing  an  independent  political  organization,  the CSSD  in  the  early  1990s  was  strongly  divided.  Those  favoring  collaboration with  Civic  Forum  managed  to  win  several  seats  under  that  label.  Their  oppo¬ nents,  led  by  Jiri  Horak,  controversially  chose  to  collaborate  with  dissident communists  expelled  from  the  party  in  1968.  The  effect  was  to  cause  turmoil in  a  party  run  by  anticommunist  dissidents.  Still,  Horak’s  openness  to  collabo¬ ration  with  other  leftist  leaders  reinforced  the  party  as  an  independent  politi¬ cal  force  after  Civic  Forum  broke  apart  in  1991  and  allowed  it  to  prosper. The  parliamentary  campaign  of  1992  was  taken  up  by  economic  issues and  disagreements  about  the  future  of  the  federation,  whose  breakdown  they nourished.  In  the  Czech  half  of  the  former  country  a  coalition  between  the new  Civic  Democratic  Party  (ODS),  led  by  the  free-market  enthusiast  Vaclav Klaus,  and  the  Christian  Democratic  Party  (KDS)  won  thirty-seven  seats.  A left  bloc  led  by  the  former  communists  (KSCM)  won  thirty-five  and  the  Social Democrats  (CSSD)  sixteen.  In  the  Slovak  half  the  elections  were  won  by  the successor  party  to  the  communists,  the  Party  of  the  Democratic  Left  (SDL).  At this  point  the  former  communists  in  the  Czech  half  of  the  republic,  the  Com¬ munist  Party  of  Bohemia  and  Moravia  (KSCM),  as  it  was  known  since  1989, came  under  internal  pressure  to  change  (De  Waele  1998,  60).  “Soft-liners,” represented  by  the  chairman  Jiri  Svoboda,  were  keen  to  promote  a  smooth transformation  to  the  post-communist  era,  but  strong  reluctance  from  the base  and  hardliner  control  over  the  organization  limited  their  attempts.  Svo¬ boda  was  forced  to  resign  and  the  party  held  on  to  its  orthodoxy  under  Miro- The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  303 slav  Grebenfcek  (Handl  2005).  In  a  subsequent  document  the  KSCM  publicly rejected  the  practices  of  former  regimes  but  also  put  strong  emphasis  on  its “aim  to  create  a  modern  socialist  society,  which  will  guarantee  real  and  last¬ ing  freedom  and  equality,  regardless  of  property  and  social  status.  This  con¬ cept  is  based  on  Marxism  and  an  open  dialogue  with  new  ideas  and  experi¬ ences.  Communists  have  always  actively  striven  to  defend  and  promote  the interests  of  the  exploited,  the  restricted,  and  the  oppressed  classes.”9  Thus while  in  the  rest  of  the  region  Marxism  seemed  to  have  vanished,  it  remained alive  in  the  Czech  Republic.  Organizationally  the  former  communists  pre¬ served  broad  territorial  coverage  but  rapidly  lost  membership— by  1991  they had  about  750,000  members  (Van  Biezen  2003, 139),  by  1999  about  130,000, and  by  2008  only  77, 115.10  More  than  two  decades  after  1989  the  party’s core  membership  consists  of  male  pensioners,  with  15%  active  blue-collar workers.  The  majority  of  members  have  but  a  modest  education,  and  only 10%  have  university  degrees.  Party  statutes  continue  to  emphasize  the  active involvement  of  ordinary  party  members:  “Membership  of  the  Czech  Commu¬ nist  Party,  moreover,  is  not  restricted  to  activities  in  the  public  realm  but  also extends  to  the  private  and  requires  a  dedication  to  personal  and  political  in¬ volvement”  (Van  Biezen  2003, 142).  The  extent  of  this  involvement  has  been considerable,  a  pattern  also  characteristic  of  the  Social  Democrats  (CSSD). Both  parties’  linkages  with  members  and  interest  organizations  have  there¬ fore  been  higher  than  for  other  Czech  parties.11 After  the  “velvet  divorce”  took  effect  in  1993  it  was  clear  that  communists would  maintain  key  positions  in  the  Czech  Republic,  even  if  they  were  ostra¬ cized  by  other  parties.  In  addition,  the  Social  Democrats  (CSSD)  began  to gather  increasing  support.  The  leadership  of  the  Social  Democrats  changed at  its  Congress  of  February  1993,  and  its  new  leaders  emerged  as  strong  oppo¬ nents  of  the  privatization  by  vouchers  promoted  by  Vaclav  Klaus,  which aimed  at  rapid  and  massive  redistribution  of  state  property.  The  party  also  in¬ creased  its  credibility  by  unequivocally  refusing  to  cooperate  with  the  former communists  (KSCM).  By  its  promotion  of  gentler  economic  reforms,  it  was progressively  recognized  as  a  left  alternative  and  thereby  reinforced  its  elec¬ toral  appeal. In  the  mid-1990s  Czech  economic  results  were  regarded  as  miraculous  be¬ cause  of  rapid  privatization  with  low  unemployment  and  inflation.12  These achievements  provided  the  setting  for  the  elections  of  1996,  which  produced a  vote  of  confidence  in  Klaus’s  government  and  its  call  for  a  market  economy inspired  by  Thatcherism  (Orenstein  1995,  184).  The  government  had  been strongly  shaken  by  the  strikes  of  1995,  including  actions  by  professors,  doc¬ tors,  and  railway  workers  which  served  to  garner  support  for  the  social  policy 304  De  Waele  and  Soare positions  of  the  Social  Democrats  (CSSD)  and  to  lend  credence  to  the  criti¬ cisms  of  the  Communists  (KSCM).  The  campaign  of  1996  was  thus  dominated by  such  social  and  economic  issues.  The  parties  of  the  left  were  able  to  expand their  electoral  base,  particularly  in  rural  areas,  but  the  right  (ODS)  was  none¬ theless  able  to  hold  on  to  its  support  in  the  cities  and  among  retired  voters. Despite  this  favorable  context  the  successor  party’s  appeal  remained  lim¬ ited,  and  it  won  only  10.3%.  During  this  entire  period  the  party  adhered  to its  communist  credo,  including  Pan-Slavism  and  Russophilia.  It  also  advo¬ cated  continued  collaboration  with  what  remained  of  the  array  of  communist states— Cuba,  China,  and  North  Korea  — and  other  opponents  of  “American imperialism”  like  Milosevic’s  Yugoslavia  and  Saddam  Hussein’s  Iraq  (Handl 2005,  126).  The  leaders  and  supporters  of  the  not-so-former  Communists (KSCM)  were  apparently  nostalgic  for  the  ancien  regime  and  eager  to  protest and  punish  the  compromises  of  the  Social  Democrats  (CSSD)  (Handl  2003,  4). The  party’s  biggest  challenge  remained  its  aging  and  shrinking  electoral  base, and  despite  some  modest  modernizing  efforts,  the  organization  attracted  few voters  in  the  election  of  1996.13 The  Social  Democrats  (CSSD)  won  almost  27%,  putting  them  just  behind the  Civic  Democrats  (ODS).  But  the  economic  situation  then  changed  very quickly,  and  the  Czech  Republic  fell  into  a  deep  recession.  The  unexpected resignation  of  Klaus,  the  ODS  leader,  who  had  been  implicated  in  a  financial scandal,  deepened  the  political  crisis.  The  Social  Democrats  won  the  elections in  1998  with  32.3%  of  the  votes,  while  the  communists  won  11%.  Refusing  to collaborate  with  the  successor  party,  the  Social  Democratic  leader  formed  a minority  government  bolstered  by  an  agreement  guaranteeing  opposition  in¬ volvement  in  all  major  decisions.  The  party  (CSSD)  maintained  its  strength in  the  elections  of  2002,  and  its  new  leader,  Vladimir  Spidla,  then  formed  a coalition  government  with  the  Christian  Democrats  and  the  Freedom  Union, again  refusing  collaboration  with  the  communists,  who  nevertheless  won 18.5%  and  thereby  increased  their  number  of  seats  in  the  lower  chamber  from twenty-four  to  forty-one.  During  their  extended  period  in  office  the  Social Democrats  (CSSD)  sought  to  consolidate  their  middle-class  and  public-sector supporters  and  progressively  moved  toward  the  center,  a  shift  that  became official  under  its  new  leadership.  This  repositioning  nevertheless  weakened the  party  in  the  presidential  elections  in  2003  and  the  European  elections  in 2004;  now  plagued  by  scandals  and  a  blurred  identity,  the  Social  Democrats (CSSD)  lost  in  2006,  while  the  communist  KSCM  declined  to  12.8%.  Twenty years  after  the  cold  war’s  end  the  Czech  political  landscape  remained  deeply marked  by  the  same  ideological  confrontation  between  Social  Democrats  and The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  305 former  and  largely  unreformed  Communists  that  had  emerged  soon  after  the breakup  of  Czechoslovakia  (Handl  2003,  7). In  Slovakia  the  Party  of  the  Democratic  Left  (SDL)  was  the  successor  and heir  to  the  once  powerful  Communist  Party.  Starting  in  the  early  1990s  it undertook  a  process  of  internal  and  programmatic  reassessment.  At  the  same time  the  Social-Democratic  Party  of  Slovakia  (SDSS),  a  historical  party  led by  Dubcek  himself,  was  reborn.  The  more  hardline  Communist  Party  (KSS) briefly  won  several  seats  in  Parliament,  but  from  the  outset  the  ability  of  the new  Democratic  Left  (SDL)  to  adapt  and  the  positive  effects  of  its  role  in  rural Slovakia  reinforced  its  credibility.  Moreover,  the  harsh  economic  reforms  an¬ nounced  by  President  Vaclav  Havel  promised  difficulty  for  what  there  was  of Slovak  industry;  in  consequence,  “The  pro-reform,  anticommunist  consensus was  far  less  clear”  in  Slovakia  than  in  the  Czech  Republic  (Grzymala-Busse 2002, 151). In  the  elections  of  1992  the  Democratic  Left  (SDL)  obtained  14.7%,  the hardliners  (KSS)  less  than  1%.  Both  left  parties  were  successfully  challenged by  the  People’s  Party,  or  Movement  for  a  Democratic  Slovakia  (HZDS),  led by  Vladimir  Meciar  (Haughton  2005,  180).  Initially  a  reaction  against  the right-leaning  pronouncements  of  the  government  dominated  by  the  Public Against  Violence  Party  (VPN),  the  People’s  Party  program  was  an  eclectic blend  of  social  policies,  nationalism,  and  populism  that  directly  challenged the  Democratic  Left  (SDL)  in  its  core  constituencies  (Williams  2003,  50). In  the  face  of  this  challenge  “the  SDL  saw  its  commitment  to  democracy  as the  main  distinction  between  itself  and  the  HZDS,”  and  the  key  feature  of its  program  became  a  formal  and  explicit  commitment  to  democratic  loy¬ alty  rather  than  a  more  typical  social  democratic  identity  (Grzymala-Busse 2002,  151).  Like  other  successor  parties  the  Democratic  Left  (SDL)  “engaged in  an  acknowledged  and  deliberative  emulation  of  programmatic  and  politi¬ cal  ideas  from  Western  social-democratic  parties,  the  Socialist  International and  the  Party  of  European  Socialists”  (Handl  and  Leska  2005,  106).  As  the party  chairman  Weiss  declared,  “we  are  for  the  market  mechanisms  and  plu¬ ral  democracy  ...  we  do  not  want  to  be  an  ideological  party”  (Weiss,  quoted by  Grzymala-Busse  2002,  152).  Yet  the  effort  was  largely  superficial,  for  the party  really  saw  itself  as  more  liberal  than  the  People’s  Party,  while  its  free- market  statements  progressively  distanced  it  from  the  trade  unions  that  had been  attracted  to  its  populist  discourse  and  program. Aiming  to  broaden  its  electoral  appeal,  the  Democratic  Left  (SDL)  took part  in  the  elections  as  the  main  member  of  the  Common  Choice  coalition formed  by  the  Greens,  the  Social  Democrats,  and  the  Farmers’  Movement. 306  De  Waele  and  Soare The  coalition  strategy  backfired  and  obscured  the  party’s  visibility,  “muddy¬ ing  the  party’s  image  and  program  in  the  mind  of  the  electorate”  (Haughton 2005,  185).  Common  Choice  won  only  10.41%  of  the  vote,  while  its  populist rivals  (HZDS)  became  the  main  party  in  the  Slovak  republic  with  34.95%. The  hardline  KSS  did  worse,  obtaining  less  than  3%.  Typical  voters  for  Com¬ mon  Choice  were  young,  urban,  and  highly  educated,  with  a  predominance of  state  employees.14 Four  years  later,  in  1998  the  People’s  Party  (HZDS)  obtained  27%  of  the votes,  an  unsatisfactory  result  for  a  party  with  limited  coalitional  potential. A  centrist  coalition  — made  up  of  the  Democratic  Union,  the  Christian  Demo¬ cratic  Movement,  the  Democratic  Party,  the  Green  Party,  and  the  SDSS  com¬ bined  in  the  Slovak  Democratic  Coalition  (SDK)  — won  26.33%;  the  Demo¬ cratic  Left  SDL  won  just  under  15%  and  the  unreformed  KSS  less  than  3%. The  SDK  leader  became  prime  minister  and  the  Democratic  Left  (SDL)  joined in  the  government  coalition,  in  which  it  promoted  a  series  of  aggressively pro-market  reforms  and  thus  alienated  its  traditional  left  electorate  (Haugh¬ ton  2005, 185).  The  party  was  riven  by  debates  between  a  “Third  Way,”  with proposals  for  economic  stabilization  that  its  enemies  claimed  were  inspired by  the  IMF  and  Milton  Friedman,  and  more  orthodox  socialists  who  favored building  a  strong  welfare  state  (Handl  and  Leska  2005, 114).  This  second  posi¬ tion  won  out,  but  not  without  leaving  deep  scars.  At  the  same  time,  during  the coalition  of  1998-2004  the  party  was  plagued  by  scandals,  something  that seemed  a  common  denominator  in  the  entire  post-communist  political  spec¬ trum.  In  this  context  one  of  the  best-known  party  leaders,  Robert  Fico,  left  the SDL  to  form  the  Smer  (Direction),  whose  original  name  included  the  phrase “Third  Way,”  illustrating  Fico’s  Blairite  programmatic  inspiration.  Like  New Labour,  Smer  sought  a  “modern”  social  democratic  balance  between  equal opportunities  and  liberal  economics. In  the  elections  of  2002  the  Democratic  Left  (SDL)  suffered  a  major  de¬ feat,  securing  just  1.36%  of  the  votes  while  the  former  communists  in  the  KSS registered  their  highest  score  in  the  post-communist  elections  with  6.32%. These  elections  indicated  how  much  the  party  had  been  marginalized,  while the  recently  created  Smer  broke  through  with  13.46%  of  the  vote  (Handl  and Leska  2005).  Three  years  later  Smer  became  the  catalyst  for  a  unification  of the  Slovak  left,  merging  with  the  Democratic  Left  (SDL),  the  Social  Demo¬ cratic  Alternative  and  the  historic  Social  Democrats  (SDSS).  In  this  format Smer  won  the  elections  of  2006,  taking  50  of  150  seats.  Surprisingly,  the  party then  formed  a  coalition  with  the  former  ally  on  the  right  of  the  People’s  Party, the  SNS,  leading  it  to  be  suspended  temporarily  from  the  Party  of  European Socialists  (PES),  the  EU-level  social  democratic  organization. The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  307 “Once  a  Big  Party”: The  Rapid  Decline  of  the  Romanian  Social  Democratic  Party It  is  widely  acknowledged  that  the  annus  mirabilis  after  the  Wall  fell  had more  limited  effects  in  Romania  than  in  the  rest  of  the  region,  particularly since  the  Romanian  Communist  Party  (PCR)  continued  in  power.  The  suc¬ cessor  National  Salvation  Front  (FSN),  under  various  appellations  like  FDSN (Democratic  National  Salvation  Front),  PDSR  (Party  of  the  Romanian  Social- Democracy),  and  the  current  PSD  (Social  Democratic  Party),  was  the  un¬ doubted  winner  of  the  events  of  December  1989.  Enjoying  organizational  su¬ periority  and  two  charismatic  leaders,  Ion  Iliescu  and  Petre  Roman,  the  FSN won  the  first  free  elections  with  more  than  66%  of  the  vote  against  a  motley collection  of  opposition  parties  — the  agrarians  (PNTCD),  the  liberals  (PNL) and  the  historic  social  democrats— which  together  barely  won  10%. In  this  first  part  of  its  new  existence  the  FSN  proclaimed  a  revolutionary identity  and  until  1993  even  refused  to  call  itself  a  party,  preferring  instead the  label  of  Front.  This  label,  which  had  strong  emotional  connotations  of official  revolutionary  origins,  legitimized  the  FSN  by  reference  “to  the  virtu¬ ous  and  unified  people”  (Soare  2004).  The  Front  recalled  the  emotional  soli¬ darity  of  the  early  days  of  the  “Revolution”  and  emphasized  a  direct  link  be¬ tween  the  demos  and  the  leaders,  a  quality  reinforced  by  its  leader  Iliescu’s paternalistic  approach  (Tismaneanu  2000, 11).  The  party’s  catch-all  discourse guaranteed  a  broad  electoral  appeal,  with  particular  penetration  among  a middle-aged  electorate  in  rural  areas  outside  the  capital  (Datculescu  1994). Benefiting  directly  from  the  former  communists’  organizational  struc¬ tures,  the  Salvation  Front  built  a  professional  political  apparatus  to  wrest  con¬ trol  over  state  institutions  and  reinforce  its  territorial  support  and  electoral strength,  while  encouraging  broad  membership  as  a  substitute  for  credibility (table  2).  For  six  years  the  FSN  squashed  its  competitors  and  profited  from its  hegemony  by  deconstructing  the  wealthy  communist  state  into  a  capillary system  of  patronage  to  reward  those  who  supported  its  positions  by  giving them  preferential  access  to  the  state’s  assets  (Soare  20o6).ls  Joining  the  FSN was  thus  not  only  an  issue  of  status  but  also  one  of  opportunity  for  economic and  professional  benefits.  An  unwritten  rule  has  existed  since  then  that  what¬ ever  the  turnover,  rival  parties  would  do  similar  things  for  their  own  benefit. Immediately  after  the  elections  of  1990  tensions  emerged  within  the  quite heterogeneous  Salvation  Front  (FSN).  Opposition  between  hardliners  and softliners  echoed  differences  in  perspectives  within  the  governing  party,  as the  visions  of  the  party’s  two  major  leaders  — Ion  Iliescu  and  Petre  Roman- clashed.  The  split  was  progressively  institutionalized  within  FSN,  and  by  1992 308  De  Waele  and  Soare two  purportedly  social  democratic  parties  had  emerged.  In  elections  that  year the  parties  together  won  nearly  40%  of  the  vote,  but  the  real  winner  was Iliescu’s  party,  the  FDSN  (which  soon  became  the  Party  of  Social  Democracy, or  PDSR).  Still,  with  fewer  than  30%  of  the  votes  and  the  refusal  of  the  Chris¬ tian  Democrats  (CDR)  to  form  an  alliance,  the  party  was  left  to  soldier  on  in a  minority  government  until  it  managed  in  1994  to  establish  the  so-called Red  Quadrilateral  Coalition  with  three  right-wing  parties:  the  Great  Roma¬ nia  Party  (PRM),  the  Party  of  the  Romanians’  National  Unity  (PUNR),  and  the small  nationalist-socialist  Socialist  Party  of  Labor  (PSM). There  were  also  traditional  social  democratic  players  during  the  first  series of  elections.  Despite  repeated  electoral  failures  in  the  1990s  due  to  unwise strategic  alliances,  the  historical  Social  Democrats  (PSDR)  succeeded  in  be¬ coming  a  regular  parliamentary  party.  In  a  landscape  dominated  by  issues of  “high  politics,”  it  was  the  only  party  interested  in  developing  a  coherent social  democratic  program.  Its  individual  electoral  weakness  and  coalitional missteps  limited  the  impact  and  visibility  of  traditional  left  culture,  however, and  in  2001  the  party  merged  with  its  larger  rival,  the  Party  of  Social  Democ¬ racy  (PDSR)  descended  from  the  largest  successor  party. Beginning  in  1993  the  FDSN/PDSR  had  begun  a  complex  programma¬ tic  realignment.  Symbolically  it  deemphasized  its  revolutionary  claims  and changed  its  name.  This  did  not  represent  a  fundamental  break  with  the  past, and  the  party’s  potential  coalition  partners  were  limited  to  other  “outcast” parties.  The  second  step  of  its  strategy  was  a  long  campaign  to  join  the  Party of  European  Socialists  and  the  Socialist  International.  By  2000,  having  been again  renamed,  as  the  Social  Democratic  Party  (PSD),  the  party  itself  initiated its  own,  internally  oriented  campaign  for  change:  it  openly  affirmed  a  social democratic  identity,  built  greater  linkages  with  trade  unions  and  a  more  de¬ veloped  organization,  and  even  introduced  new  mechanisms  for  designating electoral  candidates. From  1992  until  2005,  of  course,  the  party  faced  competition  from  a  rival successor  party.  The  Democratic  Party  (PD)  was  an  alternative  social  demo¬ cratic  group  that  came  together  around  the  reformist  leader  Petre  Roman. The  party  advertised  itself  as  a  new  social  democratic  party  inspired  by  west¬ ern  social  democracy,  and  Roman’s  personal  connections  with  leaders  like Felipe  Gonzalez  were  used  to  open  doors  in  the  European  family.  But  after electoral  failure  in  2000  and  the  election  of  a  new  leader,  now  president of  Romania,  the  PD  progressively  distanced  itself  from  international  social democratic  networks  and  also  refused  collaboration  with  the  PSD,  prefer¬ ring  instead  to  ally  with  center-right  partners.  In  2005,  in  a  major  program¬ matic  shift,  the  PD  became  a  people’s  party.  Behind  this  shift  lay  a  pragmatic The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  309 strategy  which  had  immediate  results.  Since  the  political  disappearance  of the  Christian  Democrats  (PNTCD)  in  2000,  the  EPP  — the  European  alliance  of Christian  Democratic  and  Center-Right  parties— did  not  have  a  major  Roma¬ nian  partner.  This  new  connection  was  therefore  extremely  useful  for  both the  EPP  and  the  Romanian  party.  International  visibility  and  EU  parliamen¬ tary  seats  were  prizes  for  which  the  new  party— soon  to  be  known  as  the Democratic  Liberal  Party  and  after  2007  as  the  Liberal  Democratic  Party— would  gladly  trade  in  its  social  democratic  heritage  and  identity. In  spite  of  these  strange  moves  the  electoral  results  from  1990  through 2004  suggest  that  the  Romanian  social  democratic  family  has  been  perhaps the  most  stable  in  the  post-communist  arena.  Ever  since  the  coming  of  a new  democracy,  at  least  one  supposedly  social  democratic  party  has  been  in power.  But  the  record  of  the  Romanian  social  democratic  family  also  draws attention  to  the  strategic  capacities  of  the  parties  for  adapting  to  their  en¬ vironment.  The  Liberal  Democratic  (PD)  realignment  just  discussed  is  one consequence  of  the  persistent  political  marketing  of  post-communist  social democratic  parties  and  of  a  strategy  that  has  indirectly  been  made  easier  by fluctuating  societal  cleavages.  We  have  pointed  out  elsewhere  that  in  Central and  Eastern  Europe  major  socioeconomic  divisions  have  not  been  effectively tapped  by  parties,  which  instead  have  engaged  in  clientelistic  trade-offs  be¬ tween  parties  and  local  leaders  (Soare  2004).  In  Romania  the  fragmentation of  the  social  democratic  family— both  branches  of  which  profited  organi¬ zationally  from  being  successors  to  the  communists— was  determined  more by  personal  and  factional  differences  than  by  socioeconomic  issues,  and  en¬ demic  clientelism  has  been  inimical  to  the  creation  of  strong  parties.  Partly in  consequence,  a  “once  big”  party,  the  Social  Democratic  Party  (PSD),  is currently  plagued  by  scandals  and  internal  power  struggles,  while  political patronage  has  in  the  long  run  been  of  limited  utility  as  a  substitute  for  orga¬ nization  to  a  party  in  opposition. At  the  same  time,  beginning  in  2000  the  Social  Democratic  Party  (PSD)  did launch  numerous  programmatic  documents  focused  on  questions  of  equality and  social  justice.  The  party’s  position  in  government  between  2000-2004 and  2008  limited  the  significance  of  these  issues.  It  is  significant,  though,  that the  new  program  launched  by  the  Social  Democrats  in  2006,  “A  Social  Roma¬ nia,”  proposed  “equal  chances  and  treatment  for  everyone  regardless  of  their background;  lifting  the  minimum  salary  to  the  level  of  the  minimum  pension so  that  the  low-paid  can  meet  day-to-day  living  costs;  investing  in  the  village economy;  investing  in  the  health  system;  improving  the  competitiveness  of our  economy;  ensuring  that  income  taxes  are  progressive;  improving  absorp¬ tive  capacity  of  communitarian  funds;  and  finally,  significant  investment  in 310  De  Waele  and  Soare education”  (Birchall  2007).  But  once  back  in  power  in  2008,  and  allied  with their  longtime  rivals  on  the  center-left,  the  Liberal  Democrats,  the  party  re¬ treated  from  pursuing  these  policies.16 The  Constancy  of  the  Bulgarian  Socialist  Party Influenced  by  perestroika  and  glasnost  and  pushed  by  the  Bulgarian  politi¬ cal  elite,  the  Bulgarian  Communist  Party  (bkp),  led  by  Todor  Zhivkov,  had  to open  itself  to  change  even  before  1989.  Beginning  in  the  early  1980s  young reformers  inside  the  party  quietly  promoted  a  leadership  change  (Gallagher 2003).  By  1987  the  party  had  announced  multiple-candidate  regional  elec¬ tions  as  a  sign  of  political  liberalization.  Then,  in  an  apparently  calm  situa¬ tion,  during  a  European  environmental  conference  in  Sofia  in  October  1989 street  protests  led  to  a  major  mass  demonstration  in  the  capital  city.  Unable to  control  either  the  party  or  the  situation,  and  under  scrutiny  from  the  inter¬ national  community,  Zhivkov  resigned  and  Bulgaria  began  its  tortuous  tran¬ sition  to  democracy  led  by  Mladenov,  the  former  foreign  minister.  The  BKP chose  a  social  democratic  path  to  political  redemption,  becoming  the  new Bulgarian  Socialist  Party  (BSP),  renouncing  Marxism,  and  accepting  the  mar¬ ket  economy.  It  then  proved  its  loyalty  to  the  new  regime  by  accepting  nego¬ tiations  with  the  more  anticommunist  Union  of  the  Democratic  Forces  (UDF in  English,  SDS  in  Bulgarian)  and  supporting  the  first  post-communist  free elections  (Touykova  1997,  5). As  in  Romania,  the  rigidity  of  the  Bulgarian  communist  regime  hampered the  creation  of  effective  alternative  organizations.  Noncommunist  groups lacked  the  territorial  organization  and  professional  resources  to  compete with  the  successor  party,  the  Socialists  (BSP)  (Spirova  2005,  602).  Most  of  the forty-two  organizations  competing  in  the  elections  in  1990  were  unknown  and without  widespread  support  (Karasimeneov  2004,  quoted  by  Spirova  2005, 602).  The  campaign  was  monopolized  by  the  issue  of  economic  transition, and  the  Socialists  endorsed  gradual  economic  reform  while  also  promoting the  decollectivization  of  agriculture  and  reform  of  the  banking  system.  With over  47%  of  the  votes,  they  formed  the  first  freely  elected  post-communist government  in  coalition  with  their  strongest  opponents. In  July  1991  a  new  basic  law  was  adopted,  and  elections  held  in  October were  won  by  the  Union  of  Democratic  Forces  (SDS)  with  34.4%  of  the  votes. The  Socialists  did  almost  as  well— 33.1%— but  the  party  was  at  the  moment politically  ostracized  and  without  possible  coalition  partners.  The  noncom¬ munist  coalition’s  victory  was  reinforced  by  the  philosopher  Zhelyu  Zhelev’s victory  in  presidential  elections  against  a  candidate  from  the  Socialist  Party The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  311 (BSP)  in  1992.  From  this  position  of  strength  the  SDS  then  launched  deep economic  reform,  supported  strongly  by  the  international  community.  But as  early  as  1992  the  first  signs  of  serious  social  conflict  had  appeared  in  the form  of  regular  strikes.  The  coalition  government  experienced  conflicts  be¬ tween  its  dominant  partner  and  the  Movement  for  Rights  and  Freedom  (DPS), while  the  Socialist  Party  continued  its  renewal  and  organizational  rebuild¬ ing  (Karasimeneov  1995,  579;  Touykova  1997,  5).  Statements  in  support  of the  EU  and  economic  reform  enhanced  its  national  and  international  credi¬ bility,  while  its  political  visibility  was  enhanced  by  a  functioning  organiza¬ tion  inherited  from  the  Communists  — 350,000  members  and  an  elite  of  po¬ litical  professionals  (Spirova  2005,  603).  The  party  maintained  direct  contact with  its  members  through  highly  popular  meetings  like  the  annual  May  Day celebrations.  The  party’s  strategy  was  therefore  to  attempt  to  change  and adapt  to  post-communist  challenges  while  preserving  continuity  in  its  so¬ cial  base  (Karasimeneov  1995,  581).  And  beyond  a  discursive  commitment  to promoting  a  market  economy  accompanied  by  equality  and  justice,  it  could easily  be  argued  that  in  Bulgaria,  as  in  Romania,  “the  declared  interest ...  to enhance  social  protection  was  still  not  visible  at  the  level  of  social  expendi¬ tures”  (Sotiropoulos,  Neam(u,  and  Stoyanova  2003,  661). By  the  mid-1990s  the  country  was  experiencing  an  economic  crisis,  and  in the  resulting  political  instability  President  Zhelev  dissolved  Parliament  and called  early  elections  for  1995.  The  Socialist  Party  then  used  its  organization to  advantage  against  an  opponent  plagued  with  internal  dissension  to  win  a huge  victory:  43.5%  of  the  votes  and  an  absolute  majority  in  Parliament.  “The landslide  victory  of  the  BSP  was,”  according  to  one  analyst,  “a  vote  of  hope for  change  to  more  stability  and  security”  (Karasimeneov  1995,  584).  The hopes  were  soon  undermined,  for  once  in  power  the  Socialists  were  forced to  comply  with  IMF  pressures  for  rapid  economic  reforms.  By  1996  the  Bul¬ garian  economy  faced  a  severe  financial  crisis  with  dramatic  social  costs,  a shrinking  GDP,  high  inflation,  and  a  collapsing  currency.  The  result  was  the calling  of  new  early  elections  in  1997,  at  which  point  the  Socialists  were  under fire  both  nationally  and  internally.  Events  had  called  the  party’s  commitment to  its  “social”  policies  sharply  into  question,  and  an  electorate  nostalgic  for the  security  of  the  old  regime  abandoned  the  party:  the  Socialist  (BSP)  vote dropped  to  22.5%,  while  the  liberal  Union  of  Democratic  Forces  (SDS)  won 137  seats  in  Parliament. Stability  proved  elusive,  and  the  elections  of  2001  were  dominated  by  a new  populist  party,  the  National  Movement  (NDSV),  led  by  King  Simeon  II and  campaigning  under  the  motto  “People  Are  the  Wealth  of  Bulgaria.”17  Its discourse  was  a  mixture  of  nationalistic  appeals  and  simplistic  solutions  for 312  De  Waele  and  Soare the  country  and  economic  crisis.  Claiming  messianic  legitimacy,  King  Simeon was  strongly  critical  of  traditional  political  parties  and  corrupt  institutions. The  result  was  that  both  the  liberals  (SDS)  and  the  left  (BSP)  were  roundly thrashed  and  the  National  Movement  (NDSV)  obtained  42.7%  of  the  vote.  Its success  also  proved  short-lived,  and  just  four  years  later  the  Left  Coalition for  Bulgaria,  led  by  the  Socialists,  won  the  elections  with  almost  31%.  In  the process  the  Socialists  confirmed  their  role  as  a  regular  government  party  and one  of  the  most  consistent  socialist  parties  in  the  region,  whose  strong  elec¬ toral  results  are  facilitated  by  its  stable  organization  and  broad  membership. Equally  important,  despite  the  fragmentation  of  the  left  and  center-left  after 1989,  the  Bulgarian  Socialist  Party  has  progressively  become  a  trendsetter  for the  entire  Bulgarian  political  arena  (Spirova  2005).  At  the  same  time  policy implementation  lags.  Even  if  party  documents  argue  for  raising  living  stan¬ dards,  improving  social  services,  and  enhancing  the  quality  of  healthcare  and education,  it  is  obvious  that  once  again  “this  does  not  necessarily  have  any bearing  to  the  actual  policies  of  a  party  in  government”  (Dauderstadt). Tortured  Paths  to  Redemption  and  Incomplete  Social  Democratization Told  one  after  the  other,  these  stories  are  fascinating.  After  1989  the  ex- communist  parties  were  supposed  to  rapidly  disappear,  and  scholars  foresaw a  crisis  of  the  left  in  general  once  they  did.  Yet  these  parties  have  managed to  survive  and  challenge  scholarly  predictions  with  their  remarkable  elec¬ toral  consistency.  Throughout  the  region  successor  parties,  historical  parties, new  party  formulas,  and  even  orthodox  communist  parties  have  managed to  survive  initially  grim  situations.  In  most  cases  the  successor  parties  mo¬ nopolized  the  entire  left  spectrum,  and  “no  significant  social  democratic alternatives  arose  where  the  successor  parties  could  preempt  their  moder¬ ate  leftist  rhetoric.  In  contrast,  where  the  communist  parties  failed  to  re¬ generate,  other  parties  could  take  up  the  moderate  left  side  of  the  political spectrum”  (Grzymala-Busse  2002,  283).  More  recently,  increasingly  balanced political  competition  and  increasingly  stable  party  systems  may  have  dimin¬ ished  the  prominence  of  successor  parties  on  the  left  as  the  region’s  only  well- organized  and  more  or  less  coherent  political  alternatives.  For  such  parties, discredited  by  their  past,  the  new  regime  required  complicated  changes  (De Waele  1996).  Following  a  classic  assumption  that  “Parties  don’t  just  change,” the  last  part  of  our  chapter  will  focus  on  who  and  what  gave  left  parties  the motivation  and  resources  to  comply  with  the  norms  of  the  new  political  order (Harmel  and  Janda  1994). The  answer  to  what  were  the  primary  inputs  of  change  is  relatively  simple. The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  313 First  came  the  domino  effect  that  brought  down  communist  regimes  and  in¬ duced  the  rapid  implosion  of  the  USSR,  which  suddenly  narrowed  space  for returning  to  the  past.  Overnight  Moscow  ceased  to  provide  relevant  politi¬ cal  support,  making  loyalty  to  the  new  order  the  only  pragmatic  alternative. Next,  despite  the  ostracism  faced  by  formerly  communist  parties,  the  tran¬ sition  to  democracy  almost  by  definition  meant  that  no  political  party,  other than  openly  extreme  groups,  could  be  excluded  from  political  competition. These  circumstances  effectively  sealed  the  successor  parties’  commitment  to the  new  order. The  transformation  of  the  ex-communist  parties  has  been  quite  funda¬ mental,  involving  acceptance  of  multiparty  competition  and  support  for the  market  economy.  Even  so,  it  was  eased  considerably  by  the  institutional framework.  The  transition  process  presented  three  main  challenges:  democ¬ ratization,  the  creation  of  functioning  markets,  and  the  rebuilding  of  state institutions  (Offe  1996).  State  change  has  been  the  paramount  challenge  for ex-communist  parties,  since  the  end  of  the  cold  war  dismantled  communist regimes  and  the  states  that  embodied  them.  Under  the  ancien  regime  commu¬ nist  parties  had  an  effective  monopoly  on  legally  acceptable  political  activity, and  the  state  itself  was  deeply  rooted  in  the  parties.  Throughout  the  entire  re¬ gion  “the  weakness  of  the  communist  state  left  its  successor  open  to  predation” during  the  early  transition  (Grzymala-Busse  2003, 1127).  Post-communist  in¬ stitutional  arrangements  that  characterized  states  run  by  parties  with  flexible identities  and  few  principles  allowed  these  groups  to  make  these  states  com¬ pliant  with  the  party  in  power.  All  around  the  region  post-communist  parties were  able  to  penetrate  new  states  and  use  public  offices  to  their  own  ad¬ vantage  (Van  Biezen  and  Kopecky  2007).  Reformed  communist  parties  bene¬ fited  from  a  state  model  that  was  open  to  the  influence  of  parties  in  power (Ganev  2001;  Grzymala-Busse  and  Jones  Loung  2002;  Grzymala-Busse  2003). In  other  words,  the  political  experience,  know-how,  professional  capital,  and broad  territorial  organization  of  ex-communists  led  new  leaderships  to  seize the  opportunities  provided  by  fluid  institutional  frameworks. The  rapid  strategic  metamorphosis  of  ex-communist  parties  translated  into well-disciplined,  centralized,  and  efficient  party  organizations,  and  the  pro¬ cess  was  further  eased  by  their  economic  viability.  They  inherited  financial capital  from  their  predecessors  at  the  start  of  the  transition.  The  privatization process  and  their  economic  expertise  then  put  the  parties  in  a  favorable  posi¬ tion  for  doing  business  and  balancing  business  and  politics.  A  Romanian  ex¬ cadre  who  had  become  a  big-time  entrepreneur  explained  the  smooth  tran¬ sition:  “Questioned  about  his  miraculous  transformation,”  his  interlocutor explains,  “he  declared  he  sees  no  contradiction  between  his  past  and  current 314  De  Waele  and  Soare career:  ‘On  the  contrary,  I  was  a  good  communist  and  I’ll  be  an  even  better capitalist!”’  (Stoica  2004,  271).  Of  course  other  structural  factors  such  as  elec¬ toral  systems  have  been  significant  as  well.  In  most  of  the  case  studies,  for example,  proportional  representation  facilitated  the  comeback  of  left  parties. But  being  the  “successor”  to  the  previous  rulers  was  critical. At  the  electoral  level  it  is  hard  to  construct  an  ideal  picture  of  the  base  of left  parties  and  to  discern  the  typical  voter  at  the  regional  level.  The  Roma¬ nian  Social  Democrats  (PSD)  and  their  Bulgarian  counterparts  (BSP)  were better  implanted  in  rural  zones,  where  their  voters  were  older  and  had  mini¬ mal  education.  More  recently  the  changing  nature  of  party  systems  has  chal¬ lenged  this  profile  and  the  two  parties  have  lost  these  electoral  fiefs,  but  they have  also  made  inroads  into  urban  areas.  In  this  respect  the  victory  of  the Social  Democratic  candidate  for  mayor  of  Bucharest  in  the  most  recent  local elections  is  significant.  Hungarian  socialist  voters,  in  contrast,  remain  urban- based.  The  ways  the  recent  economic  crisis  has  hit  Polish  social  democrats make  identifying  their  typical  voters  more  difficult.  Urban  voters  are  still  the most  important  base  in  Czech  and  Slovak  social  democratic  electorates.  Yet  in virtually  all  cases  one  finds  parties  appealing  to  voters  over  the  heads  of  their own  party  members,  a  reflection  perhaps  of  ideological  weakness  but  also  an explanation  of  membership  decline. Moving  beyond  this  basic  balance  sheet,  it  is  difficult  to  identify  the  pre¬ cise  trigger  for  change.  The  scholarly  literature  regularly  emphasizes  the  in¬ ertia  of  big  organizations  as  “a  wall  of  resistance”  to  change,  and  one  would expect  even  more  resistance  from  highly  centralized  communist  parties (Harmel  and  Janda  1994,  261).  But  in  moments  of  great  uncertainty  the  ac¬ tions  of  leadership  are  strongly  influenced  by  circumstances.  The  vanishing credibility  of  communist  parties  at  a  time  of  pervasive  economic  crisis  and the  powerful  intuition  that  transition  was  unstoppable  accentuated  pressures for  change.  In  most  cases  the  communist  parties  also  experienced  a  rapid  and drastic  erosion  of  their  membership  (table  2),  which  made  breaking  with  the past  less  a  choice  than  a  necessity.  The  parties’  organizational  centralization nonetheless  allowed  elites  to  control  the  dimensions  and  pace  of  adaptation. Finally,  the  legacies  of  the  past  and  the  rigidity  of  communist  regimes  further enhanced  the  appeal  of  change.  In  Hungary,  Poland,  Bulgaria,  and  Slovakia the  new  communist  leadership  after  1989  consisted  of  younger  party  mem¬ bers  keen  for  rapid  transformation.  In  the  Czech  Republic,  where  old  appa¬ ratchiks  dominated,  reformers  had  less  visibility  and  space  for  maneuver. The  Romanian  case  is  unusual  because  the  new  leadership  of  “softliners”  and promoters  of  moderate  reformism  were  inspired  more  by  perestroika  than  by democratization. The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  315 Twenty  years  is  too  short  a  time  to  reach  definitive  conclusions,  so  we  must be  tentative.  We  have  told  the  story  of  an  extremely  resistant  species.  A  his¬ torical  and  structural  approach  that  favors  legacy-based  explanations  for  the evolution  of  the  Central  and  Eastern  European  post- communist  left  is  par¬ ticularly  relevant  to  account  for  the  commonalities  and  divergences  of  the various  political  actors.  Thus  the  reluctance  of  Czech  communists  (KSCM)  to change  and  the  longstanding  political  tradition  of  the  Czech  Social  Demo¬ crats  (CSSD)  offer  a  convincing  argument  for  how  historical  legacies  and  na¬ tional  opportunities  can  be  combined,  and  in  this  case  explain  how  the  Czech path  diverged  from  paths  taken  elsewhere  in  the  region.  As  for  analyzing  the shift  from  Marxism  to  capitalism  by  the  descendants  of  the  former  ruling Communist  parties,  history  reminds  us  that  for  the  most  part  these  parties had  been  imposed  from  abroad,  and  despite  almost  half  a  century  in  power, they  had  failed  at  building  the  socialism  they  preached.  Homo  sovieticus  had been  almost  exclusively  an  issue  of  propaganda,  while  Vaclav  Benda’s  theory of  the  “parallel  polis”  was  closer  to  reality.  In  the  end  the  successful  trans¬ formation  of  the  ex-communist  parties  thus  attests  to  a  paradox.  Communist parties  had  been  the  only  relevant  political  actors  in  the  region  for  almost  half a  century.  But  except  in  the  Czech  Republic  they  all  failed  at  direct  continua¬ tion  into  the  post-communist  era.  Symbolically,  Marxism  and  its  corollaries have  been  totally  and  effectively  superseded  by  variants  of  liberal  and  pro¬ market  theories.  Yet  the  successor  parties  themselves  often  succeeded. Historically  driven  explanations  of  the  success  of  the  left  and  center-left parties,  and  in  particular  of  the  ex-communists,  focus  mainly  on  their  orga¬ nizational  advantages  (De  Waele  2002).  Transformation  of  the  communist parties  was  an  organizational  strategy  without  clear  programmatic  baggage. In  the  fluid  political  competition  of  the  early  1990s,  organizational  continuity allowed  these  parties  to  preserve  their  influence  and  at  least  partially  their skilled,  experienced  political  elites.  Their  organizational  resources  contrasted sharply  with  those  of  the  fledgling  proto-parties  that  came  to  power  immedi¬ ately  after  the  end  of  the  old  regime.  While  holding  on  to  these  resources,  the successor  parties  also  adopted  a  twofold  strategy  to  achieve  new  legitimacy and  respectability.  They  first  gave  full  support  to  economic  reforms,  and  in government  these  “social  democrats,”  old  and  new,  worked  at  “building  capi¬ talism.”  They  then  went  on  to  embrace  the  EU  and  NATO. Their  concern  for  integration  in  the  new  capitalist  system  meant  abrupt disengagement  from  traditional  ideologies  and  at  times  traditional  social bases.  Successor  parties  and  historical  social  democrats  also  neglected  the development  of  a  left  or  center-left  political  culture  and  outlook.  Despite  per¬ vasive  organization,  the  absence  of  such  a  political  culture  has  eventually 316  De  Waele  and  Soare hampered  these  parties.  Support  for  a  market  economy  and  regular  stays  in government  have  not  been  cost-free.  All  over  the  region  populist  parties  have come  to  exploit  this  and  in  several  cases  have  been  able  to  find  fertile  breed¬ ing  ground.  In  addition,  traditional  alliances  between  these  parties  and  the trade  unions,  themselves  operating  at  a  disadvantage  in  the  new  era,  have been  weakened  (Mudde  2004).  In  general  the  absence  of  intermediary  orga¬ nizations  and  committed  social  actors  must  be  considered  when  reflecting  on the  limits  of  the  center-left  throughout  the  region.  Domination  of  the  political scene  by  parties,  the  weakness  of  civil  society,  and  the  alienation  from  poli¬ tics  regularly  emphasized  by  surveys  have  blocked  the  emergence  of  a  partici¬ patory  culture.  This  participation  deficit  has  progressively  generated  a  real representation  crisis,  with  a  major  impact  on  the  center-left  in  particular. The  strong  support  for  European  and  NATO  integration  has  also  created problems  for  center-left  parties  of  whatever  origin.  The  paradox  is  clear:  “So¬ cial  democrats  have  been  the  strongest  advocates  of  accession  in  many  coun¬ tries  . . .  Why  did  social  democrats  support  EU  membership  in  spite  of  the  costs and  partial  drawbacks  for  their  own  clientele?”  (Agh  2004,  5).  The  reasons for  this  exaggerated  Europeanism  were  the  need  for  international  credibility, pragmatism  tied  to  a  lack  of  alternatives,  and  perceived  national  diplomatic interests.  Twenty  years  on,  however,  center-left  parties  are  now  progressively squeezed  between  EU  requirements,  national  needs  to  comply  with  transition goals,  and  popular  disenchantment  due  to  the  social  costs  of  the  new  system. From  the  beginning  the  attempts  of  parties  of  the  left  to  develop  a  coherent programmatic  identity  through  the  prism  of  national  and  local  needs  and social  requirements  have  been  neglected  in  favor  of  the  choice  for  Europe. Despite  a  certain  amount  of  electoral  stability,  the  progressive  shrinkage  of the  blue-collar  working  class  and  the  appeal  to  the  left’s  traditional  working- class  base  of  new  right-wing  populist  parties  have  thus  become  very  large challenges.  In  such  new  political  circumstances,  the  center-left  is  on  the  de¬ fensive  all  around  the  region. Twenty  years  after  the  fall  of  “peoples’  democracies,”  the  post-communist political  landscape  has  changed  fundamentally.  The  resurrection  of  old  lefts in  central  Europe  was  helped  by  their  political  experience  and  organizational networks,  and  by  the  weakness  and  fragmentation  of  their  opponents.  But in  time,  their  weaknesses  in  ideology,  organization,  and  relationships  with party  members  and  voters,  along  with  accusations  of  corruption,  have  be¬ come  much  more  visible  with  the  consolidation  of  the  right  and  the  emer¬ gence  of  new  forms  of  populism.  Thus  the  successes  of  the  1990s  seem  mainly to  have  obscured  the  Achilles’  heel  of  these  left  parties,  their  ideological weakness.  The  ever  greater  convergence  of  social  policies  across  different The  Central  and  Eastern  European  Left  317 national  party  systems  has  also  limited  their  margins  of  maneuver  and  pro¬ gressively  eaten  away  at  their  traditional  electoral  bases.  Throughout  the  en¬ tire  region  the  center-left  thus  remains  trapped  in  a  process  of  reconstruction which  is  made  more  difficult  by  outside  pressures  and  a  troubled  past. Notes 1.  By  successor  parties  we  refer  to  those  parties  “that  were  formerly  the  governing party  in  the  pre-1989  communist  regime  and  which  inherited  the  preponderance  of  the former  ruling  parties’  resources  and  personnel”  (Ishiyama  1998,  62). 2.  Between  1991  and  1997  the  Eurobarometer  surveys  measured  high  levels  of  dis¬ satisfaction  with  the  untoward  consequences  of  democratization,  in  particular  its  so¬ cial  costs  (Dauderstadt  and  Gerrits  2000,  table  6). 3.  Outside  this  divided  family  the  KSCM  looks  to  be  the  only  large  Communist  party in  the  region  continuing  into  post-communism,  defining  itself  as  “the  only  genuine Czech  left  party,”  whose  goal  remains  “the  transformation  from  capitalism  to  social¬ ism”  (Zprava,  5th  Congress  1999,  quoted  in  Handl  2003,  4).  The  KSCM  may  be  related to  the  other  parties,  but  it  has  become  a  separate  case,  following  its  own  left  social democratic  paths  while  denouncing  the  “laxity”  and  loss  of  Marxist-Leninist  political principles  by  others. 4.  Even  though  the  notion  of  the  political  family  is  a  category  of  analysis  often  criti¬ cized  as  vague  and  based  on  common  sense,  it  remains  a  useful  tool  in  analyzing  politi¬ cal  parties,  for  it  offers  at  the  same  time  a  “domain  of  identification”  for  party  elites, members,  and  voters  and  a  reference  point  in  the  “domain  of  competition”  at  the  level of  party  systems  (Mair  and  Mudde  1998;  Sartori  and  Sani  1983). 5.  On  ideological  groups  and  the  link  with  structural  cleavages  see  Lipset  and Rokkan  1967. 6.  “Democratic  left  alliance  election  manifesto  2005,”  www.sld.org.pl/index.php ?view= l&artjd  =  7is8&pid  =  i88tret_id  =  I75&rsid  =  0. 7.  The  MSzP  was  to  rapidly  assume  a  central  role  in  the  rogue  privatization  of the  public  sector,  which  will  allow  the  accumulation  of  capital  in  the  hands  of  party leaders. 8.  The  MIEP  (Hungarian  Justice  and  Life)  fell  short  of  the  electoral  threshold  in 2002,  the  Independent  Smallholders’  Party  (FKGP)  collapsed  after  corruption  scandals, the  MDF  (Democratic  Forum)  merged  with  the  FIDESZ,  and  the  SzDSz  progressively shrank  to  5%  of  the  vote. 9.  http://www.KSCM.cz/article.asp?thema=3247&item =28074. 10.  According  to  an  internal  analysis,  “the  decline  in  KSCM  membership  oscillates  at 6-7  percent  a  year,  while  the  membership  grows  by  0.6  to  0.68  percent  a  year.”  “Czech Communist  Party  Membership  Steadily  Shrinking,”  9  May  2008,  www.praguemonitor .com/en/33i/czech_politics/22449. 11.  It  is  worth  noting  that  all  Czech  parties  experienced  a  steep  decline  in  member- 318  De  Waele  and  Soare ship  starting  in  the  early  1990s,  with  the  CSSD,  whose  numbers  rose  from  16,200  to 18,300,  the  only  exception. 12.  Significantly,  the  unemployment  rate  was  much  lower  in  the  Czech  Republic than  elsewhere  in  the  region.  In  1995  unemployment  stood  at  2.9%  in  the  Czech  Re¬ public,  in  contrast  to  10.3%  in  Hungary  and  14.7%  in  Poland.  Similarly,  the  poverty  rate was  less  than  1%  in  the  Czech  Republic,  2%  in  Hungary,  and  31%  in  Poland  (Graham 1998,  202). 13.  Handl  (2003,  5)  observes:  “During  1990-1998,  3289  new  members  entered  the party.  67,3%  party  members  are  pensioners,  64%  have  only  the  elementary  education” (based  on  Zprava  5th  Congress,  1999,  52-54). 14.  http://slovakia.eunet.sk/slovakia/elections.html. 15.  “Access  to  patronage  typically  provides  party  leaders  with  the  means  to  build and  maintain  party  organizations  through  the  distribution  of  selective  incentives  to party  supporters  in  exchange  for  organizational  loyalty”  (Van  Biezen  and  Kopecky 2007,  241). 16.  Elections  pitting  the  two  dominant  parties,  until  recently  in  coalition,  against each  other  were  scheduled  for  late  2009. 17.  www.ndsv.bg/content/531.html. European  Center-Lefts  and  the  Mazes of  European  Integration George  Ross The  European  Union  (EU)  has  been  called  an  “unidentified  flying  political object”  because  of  its  constantly  changing  objectives,  scope,  size,  and  insti¬ tutions.1  The  European  left,  not  an  object  at  all,  is  many  political  formations varying  nationally  with  each  historical  moment.  Today’s  center-lefts  are powerfully  influenced  by  the  EU,  and  vice  versa,  and  our  goal  is  to  discuss how  these  things  happen.  We  review  the  historic  interaction  of  the  EU  and the  left— until  the  Maastricht  Treaty  (1992),  after  the  end  of  the  cold  war,  and with  the  coming  of  globalization  — and  then  look  at  the  EU’s  present  implica¬ tions  for  lefts.  The  basic  question  that  concerns  us  can  be  asked  simply:  Has European  integration  been  friend  or  foe  to  European  lefts? The  EU  and  Lefts  to  the  Euro The  intertwined  histories  of  the  EU  and  European  lefts  before  the  Maastricht Treaty  demonstrate  the  complexities  of  their  interactions.  European  integra¬ tion  was  not  an  idea  that  lefts  warmly  welcomed.  But  after  a  deep  crisis  in the  1970s  sorely  tested  both  the  EU  and  national  political  economies,  it  was the  French  left  which  favored  renewing  European  integration  in  ways  which would  promote  a  new  market  liberalism  and  challenge  social  market  achieve¬ ments.  The  EU’s  programs  to  complete  the  single  market  and  economic  and monetary  union  (EMU)  undercut  the  autonomy  of  earlier  national  models.  An argument  can  be  made  that  these  changes  at  the  European  level  were  central in  transforming  European  lefts  into  the  center-lefts  we  discuss  today. Lefts  and  the  EU’s  Early  Successes  and  Trials The  EU  was  started  by  six  countries  — France,  the  German  Federal  Republic, Italy,  and  the  Benelux  three  — in  the  Rome  Treaties  (1957)-  Its  first  name,  the 320  Ross European  Economic  Community  (EEC),  and  its  colloquial  name,  “the  Com¬ mon  Market,”  underlined  its  focus  on  economic  matters.  The  Rome  EEC  Treaty set  out  great  ambitions,  including  “ever  closer  union”  among  EEC  members, but  it  was  mainly  devoted  to  creating  a  customs-free  zone  surrounded  by  a common  external  tariff  within  which  barriers  to  trade  in  manufactured  and agricultural  goods  were  to  be  removed. Institutionally  the  EEC  copied  its  immediate  ancestor,  the  European  Coal and  Steel  Community  (ECSC,  1952).  It  was  basically  intergovernmental  — a council  of  (national)  ministers  decided  key  policy  matters.  But  it  also  had  a supranational  European  Commission  given  exclusive  power  to  propose  legis¬ lation.  In  addition  there  was  a  European  Court  of  Justice  (ECJ)  to  adjudicate and  keep  the  EEC  within  its  “treaty  bases.”  Finally  there  was  a  “European  As¬ sembly”  (precursor  of  today’s  European  Parliament),  whose  members  were appointed  from  national  legislatures.  The  institutional  model  was  chosen  be¬ cause  the  EEC’s  founders  felt  that  supranational  mechanisms  like  the  com¬ mission  and  the  court,  purpose-built  to  promote  intergovernmental  co¬ operation,  were  needed  to  forestall  the  ineffective  deals  that  would  follow if  governments  were  left  to  their  own  devices.  They  felt  further  that  if  this institutionally  unique  EEC  could  promote  interstate  cooperation  in  its  initial economic-market  purview,  the  linkages  between  economics  and  other  policy areas  could  foster  “spillover”  and  progressively  broaden  the  scope  of  integra¬ tion.  Finally,  they  knew  that  European  integration  would  work  best  in  a  fog of  political  stealth:  if  people  knew  too  much,  the  processes  might  bog  down. The  EEC  began  in  Europe’s  postwar  boom,  when  each  member  had  its  own national  economic  strategies,  welfare  states,  and  industrial  relations  systems. These  national  models  placed  limits  on  how  far  early  Europeanization  could go.  Integration  increased  intra-EEC  trade  in  manufactured  goods,  helping  to stimulate  national  growth.  A  Common  Agricultural  Policy  (CAP)  prodded agricultural  investment,  cushioned  difficult  transitions  from  farming  to  fac¬ tory  work,  and  protected  farmers.  The  external  tariff  was  simultaneously  a buffer  against,  and  a  subsystem  within,  the  Bretton  Woods  trading  system  co¬ ordinated  by  the  United  States. Postwar  lefts  composed  of  Socialist,  Communist,  and  other  parties  rep¬ resented  groups— workers  in  the  first  instance— that  were  relatively  new  to democratic  participation.  Parties  and  party  systems  differed  from  place  to place,  much  like  the  national  models  with  which  they  worked.  There  were “mass”  parties  tied  to  organized  labor  like  the  German  SPD  that  needed middle-class  support  to  win  elections.  Communists,  powerful  in  France  and Italy,  were  also  mass  parties,  but  tied  to  the  Soviet  side  of  the  cold  war.  French and  Italian  Socialists  combined  clientelism  with  a  nineteenth-century  brand European  Center-Lefts  321 of  municipal  socialism.  In  general  it  was  rare  for  the  EEC  left  to  have  exclu¬ sive  representation  over  all  left-leaning  constituencies,  even  if  the  German SPD  came  close.  More  often  lefts  were  divided,  whether  between  Commu¬ nists  and  Socialists,  as  in  Italy  and  France,  or  by  linguistic  or  religious  differ¬ ences,  as  in  Belgium  and  the  Netherlands,  and  these  divisions  created  persis¬ tent  strategic  quarrels  and  electoral  problems.  That  most  lefts  also  competed within  multiparty  systems  complicated  strategic  problems  even  more  (Pater¬ son  and  Thomas  1977). Divided  or  not,  EEC  lefts  were  central  in  their  national  political  economies, with  stakes  in  expanding  welfare  states,  labor  rights,  and  state  involvement in  markets.  But  even  here  differences  were  striking.  The  German  SPD  lived in  a  “social  market  economy”  which  thrived  on  exports,  wage  restraint,  and tough  monetary  policies.  In  direct  contrast,  center-right  statism  in  France after  1958  assumed  exaggerated  proportions  and  marginalized  a  deeply  di¬ vided  left  (Schonfield  1969).  Belgium  and  the  Netherlands  lived  within  di¬ visive  pillar  arrangements  (Liphardt  1977;  Visser  and  Hemerijk  1997).  Italy was  less  developed  and  played  catch-up  in  semi-statist  ways  which  hid  be¬ hind  a  clientelist  center-right  Christian  Democratic  regime,  leaving  behind the  country’s  south,  where  economic  conditions  could  resemble  those  of  the third  world,  and  marginalizing  its  largely  Communist  left  (Heilman  2008, 249-81).2  In  general,  if  the  first  postwar  decades  are  rightly  associated  with the  construction  of  what  some  call  “Keynesian  welfare  states,”  different  lefts did  not  always  have  easy  times. The  EEC  itself  was  not  a  left  project,  mainly  because  lefts  were  focused  on developing  their  national  systems.  Spaak,  the  Belgian  minister  who  led  the talks  leading  to  the  Rome  Treaties,  was  a  titular  Socialist,  but  really  more  a Belgian  national  politician  deeply  molded  by  wartime  experiences.  Some  left leaders  of  the  French  Fourth  Republic  (including  Guy  Mollet,  head  of  the  Sec¬ tion  Frangaise  de  l’lnternationale  Ouvriere,  or  SFIO,  and  Franqois  Mitterrand) were  “Europeans,”  but  entire  swaths  of  the  French  left  opposed  integration (Featherstone  1988).  German  Social  Democrats  opposed  integration  initially but  changed  their  minds  after  the  mid-1950s  when  its  economic  advantages became  clearer.  The  Italian  left,  socialist  and  communist,  was  more  positive, as  were  Italian  politicians  more  generally.  But  the  EEC  was  really  the  product of  an  elite  generation  of  politicians,  often  Christian  Democrats,  haunted  by the  Second  World  War. Lefts  had  reasons  to  be  apprehensive  about  the  EEC.  Trade  liberalization could  change  comparative  advantages  and  threaten  national  jobs.3  The  idea of  “ever-closer  union  among  the  peoples  of  Europe”  had  federalist  connota¬ tions  which  bothered  leftists  who  saw  national  arenas  as  their  best  bets.  The 322  Ross Communist  line  was  that  the  EEC  was  a  plot  sponsored  by  the  United  States to  resurrect  German  power.  The  treaty’s  other  explicit  objectives,  beyond  the CAP,  included  common  policies  for  transport,  coordinating  EEC  economic policy,  and  an  EEC  antitrust  regime,  all  readable  by  lefts  as  threatening.  In addition,  the  treaty  was  a  “framework  agreement”  that  announced  general goals  and  left  practical  substance  for  later  in  ways  that  implied  future  sur¬ prises. The  EEC’s  institutions  prompted  additional  worries  on  the  left.  The  Euro¬ pean  Commission  was  clearly  meant  to  expand  the  EEC’s  mandate  over  time. This  would  be  hard  if  the  Council  of  (national)  Ministers  had  the  last  word, giving  governments  a  veto.  But  the  treaty  proposed  that  eventually  the  coun¬ cil  would  decide  by  “qualified  majority  vote”  (QMV),  in  which  votes  by  mem¬ ber  states  would  be  weighted  by  relative  size,  allowing  member  states  to  be outvoted.  The  ECJ  could  also  be  a  threat  because  through  its  jurisprudence  it could  make  European  law  that  superseded  national  statutes.  Yet  the  EEC  insti¬ tutions  were  empowered  only  in  areas  that  the  treaty  specified,  and  this  pro¬ vided  some  comfort,  in  large  part  because  social  and  tax  policies  remained national. The  early  EEC  thrived  on  buoyant  economic  conditions  in  a  win-win  game between  it  and  national  models.  But  things  did  not  always  run  smoothly. President  Charles  de  Gaulle,  a  center-right  nationalist,  spearheaded  member states’  resistance  to  the  commission’s  attempt  to  acquire  more  power  and  to enlarging  the  community  by  extending  membership  to  the  United  Kingdom.4 Introducing  QMV  decision  making  was  also  postponed,  making  unanimity  the norm  well  into  the  1980s.  De  Gaulle  spoke  for  France’s  specific  French  archi¬ tectural  stipulations  about  the  EEC,  but  these  concerns  often  reflected  deeper realities.  The  Common  Market  had  begun  after  each  of  its  members  had  de¬ veloped  its  own  economic  strategies  and  each  had  moved  through  the  1960s in  its  own  ways. The  1970s  were  a  turning  point  (Eichengreen  2007,  chapters  7,  8).  In  1971 the  United  States  renounced  its  Bretton  Woods  engagement  to  the  convert¬ ibility  of  dollars  and  gold.  Currencies  floated,  speculators  shifted  into  high gear,  and  financial  globalization  began.  The  oil  shocks  of  1973  and  1979 sharply  accelerated  inflation,  particularly  in  a  Europe  which  had  no  oil.  EC governments  reacted  in  dispersed  national  order.  The  British  Labour  govern¬ ment  and  the  Gaullist  French  tried  austerity  followed  by  Keynesian  refla¬ tion,  and  the  result  was  stagflation.  Countries  with  effective  wage  restraint were  less  perturbed,  although  not  immune  — Germany,  for  example,  which used  tough  monetary  policies  to  maintain  price  stability.  In  general,  though, lefts  had  difficult  encounters  with  key  constituencies  and  risky  paths  in  the international  economy.5  During  these  years  central  bankers  and  Anglophone European  Center-Lefts  323 economists  pronounced  the  death  of  Keynesianism.  EC  leaders,  who  at  a  sum¬ mit  in  1969  had  proposed  a  list  of  changes  including  economic  and  mone¬ tary  union,  deeper  foreign  policy  cooperation,  and  new  social  policies,  had to  abandon  almost  all  of  them.  Floating  exchange  rates  menaced  EC  trade and  the  CAP.  In  addition,  changed  economic  circumstances  had  led  member states  toward  using  non-tariff  barriers  to  protect  themselves. The  European  Monetary  System  (EMS),  shepherded  in  1978  by  France and  Germany,  was  one  of  the  few  innovations  of  this  crisis  period.6  All  EC members  belonged  to  EMS,  but  its  inner  circle,  the  Exchange  Rate  Mecha¬ nism  (ERM),  included  only  those  accepting  stronger  monetary  constraints.7 EMS  was  founded  on  a  political  equivocation.  Stronger-currency  EMS  mem¬ bers  used  monetary  policy  to  maintain  price  stability,  following  the  German Bundesbank.  Weaker-currency  ones  like  France  were  more  tolerant  of  in¬ flation  and  devaluation.8  French  elites  hoped  that  EMS  would  lead  the  Ger¬ mans  to  constrain  the  profligate  sides  of  French  policies  while  the  French won  greater  flexibility  from  the  Germans.  These  differences  were  to  provide a  central  thread  in  EC  history  through  the  1990s. EMS  was  no  remedy  for  all  EC  problems.  The  British  had  done  a  bad  deal when  they  joined  in  1973,  contributing  more  than  they  got  back,  and  Prime Minister  Thatcher  made  this  issue  a  cause,  insisting  on  a  “rebate”  while  threat¬ ening  to  block  anything  else.9  And  after  the  collapse  of  southern  European dictatorships  in  the  later  1970s,  the  new  democracies  wanted  to  join  the  EC. But  after  Greece,  governed  by  the  Panellinio  Sosialistiko  Kinima,  or  PASOK, was  admitted  in  1981  it  demanded  serious  development  aid  and  threatened to  prevent  Spain  and  Portugal  from  joining  until  it  got  it.  The  EC  was  stuck. The  dramatic  evolution  of  the  French  left  got  European  integration  un¬ stuck.  Out  of  power  since  1958,  the  French  Socialists  and  their  Communist allies  won  a  majority  in  1981  after  the  presidential  election  of  Frangois  Mitter¬ rand.  They  brought  with  them  a  long  list  of  pledges  to  reinvigorate  France’s dirigiste  national  model,  including  new  nationalizations,  planning,  industrial relations  reforms,  decentralization,  redistributive  shifts  of  the  welfare  state, and  strong  Keynesian  stimulation  (Favier  and  Martin-Roland  1990).  The  “Mit¬ terrand  experiment”  quickly  ran  into  difficulties  (Hall  1987).  Pressures  on  the franc  led  to  devaluations  and  retrenchment,  and  by  the  winter  of  1983  the French  faced  a  choice  between  leaving  EMS,  at  high  risk  of  isolation  and  fail¬ ure,  and  staying  in  and  making  major  policy  changes. Mitterrand’s  decision  was  providential  for  European  integration.  For France  the  new  period  started  with  deep  austerity,  budgetary  constraints, liberalization  including  a  rationalizing  of  the  bloated  public  sector,  privati¬ zation,  industrial  restructuring,  and  slow  growth.  It  also  brought  deflation toward  parity  with  the  German  DM  and  high  interest  rates  that  deepened  the 324  Ross recession.  France,  of  all  EC  countries,  and  a  French  left  president,  of  all  politi¬ cal  animals,  thus  recognized  the  new  international  constraints,  beginning  a forced  march  for  French  Socialists  from  radical  reformism  toward  “center- leftism.” Change  was  as  decisive  in  foreign  policy.  Mitterrand,  a  “European”  since the  1950s,  recommitted  France  to  Europe  during  the  French  EC  presidency in  1984.  Under  his  leadership  leaders  settled  the  “British  check”  issue  and agreed  on  how  to  admit  Spain  and  Portugal,  ending  the  decision-making paralysis  of  the  EC.  Quite  as  important,  Jacques  Delors,  former  French  min¬ ister  of  finances,  became  president  of  the  European  Commission.  In  January 1985  Delors  announced  a  program  to  complete  the  single  market.  A  commis¬ sion  white  paper  soon  followed,  proposing  massive  EC  legislation  to  remove all  barriers  to  a  single  European  economy  and  institute  the  free  circulation of  goods,  capital,  services,  and  people.  The  white  paper  prompted  the  Single European  Act  (SEA)  — the  first  major  EC  treaty  change  since  Rome  in  1957- expanding  EC  prerogatives,  changing  decision  rules,  and  granting  the  Euro¬ pean  Parliament  new  powers  (Ross  1995). The  next  big  EC  push  began  in  June  1988,  when  leaders  appointed  Delors to  chair  a  top-level  committee  that  would  produce  proposals  for  economic and  monetary  union  (Quatremer  and  Klau  1997,  151-56).  The  French  and other  softer-currency  countries  wanted  to  get  more  control  over  monetary policy  from  the  Bundesbank  to  construct  a  new  basis  for  European  monetary policy  less  biased  toward  price  stability  and  more  growth-friendly.  The  Ger¬ mans,  with  bargaining  advantage  from  their  financial  power,  set  out  strong preconditions:  independent  national  central  banks,  an  independent  European central  bank  to  produce  price  stability,  stringent  requirements  for  budgetary and  economic  policy  convergence  for  EMU  membership,  and  liberalization  of capital  markets  (Dyson  and  Featherstone  1999).  The  drive  to  EMU  culminated in  the  Maastricht  Treaty  on  European  Union.  The  EMU  deal  included  the  Ger¬ man  priorities  to  price  stability,  national  budgetary  responsibility,  and  tough “convergence  criteria.”10  Applicants  had  to  lower  annual  budget  deficits  to 3%  of  GDP,  squeeze  longer-term  debt  to  60%  of  GDP,  sustain  low  interest and  inflation  rates,  and  stabilize  their  currencies.  EMU  would  begin  fully  on 1  January  1999,  and  only  those  who  had  met  these  criteria  would  be  allowed to  join.11 Stories  in  the  Story:  The  French  Left  Makes  Center-Leftism  Obligatory? European  integration  did  not  begin  as  a  left  affair,  but  it  had  been  relaunched in  the  1980s  by  Mitterrand,  Delors,  and  Chancellor  Helmut  Kohl  of  Germany, European  Center-Lefts  325 the  two  French  Socialist  politicians  in  the  lead.  Relaunch  was  built  on  the single-market  program  and  monetary  integration,  both  deeply  liberal  eco¬ nomic  initiatives.  The  relaunch  would  be  one  of  the  more  important  processes converting  Europe  to  international  market  opening  and  post-Keynesian  out¬ looks.  To  be  sure,  several  EC  member  states  had  by  then  already  opened  up markets  and  abjured  Keynesianism,  but  new  European-level  policies  en¬ sured  that  everyone  would  have  to  follow,  including  left  parties  and  govern¬ ments. Francois  Mitterrand  was  a  complicated  man.  Europe  was  a  traditional arena  for  French  operations,  the  nexus  of  Franco-German  relationships,  and a  key  location  for  France  to  work  indirectly  on  a  global  scale.  On  European issues  Mitterrand  followed  long-standing  Gaullist  goals,  promoting  integra¬ tion  to  make  Europe  more  independent  of  American  hegemony  but  eschewing supranationalism  where  possible.  France  also  had  foreign  economic  policy interests  in  decanting  German  market  and  monetary  power  into  broader European  vessels.  Still,  this  does  not  fully  explain  France’s  dramatic  shift  in the  1980s.  Mitterrand  cared  less  about  economic  policy  than  about  staying in  power,  and  his  high-visibility  European  initiatives  intertwined  with  more mundane  electoral  concerns.  Mitterrand  needed  exceptional  reasons  to  jus¬ tify  abandoning  the  radical  program  upon  which  he  had  been  elected.  Pre¬ senting  his  about-face  in  terms  of  the  sacrifices  needed  to  help  Europe  flour¬ ish  anew  could  put  a  different  spin  on  things  and  perhaps  cover  up  some  of the  left’s  deep  failures.  The  new  “option  for  Europe”  plus  day-to-day  political prestidigitation  helped  Mitterrand  win  two  terms,  until  1995,  making  him  the longest-serving  president  in  the  history  of  the  Fifth  Republic. Jacques  Delors  was  a  different  story.  Mitterrand’s  outlooks  fluctuated with  his  electoral  prospects,  but  Delors  had  always  been  “center-left.”12  As finance  minister  after  1981,  he  had  dragged  his  feet  on  renewing  dirigisme  and Keynesianism.  The  reformist  strategy  that  Delors  advanced  as  commission president  was  no  surprise,  therefore,  because  he  believed  in  liberalization, ending  inflationary  spending,  and  serious  structural  reform.  He  also  sensed the  coming  of  globalization  before  most  politicians  did.  But  Delors  was  at heart  a  left  Catholic  corporatist  who  believed  that  key  social  groups  should cooperate  for  the  common  good,  and  he  felt  strongly  that  new  liberalization and  monetary  stability  should  be  accompanied  by  social  policy  initiatives  at the  EC  level.  He  thus  invested  considerable  resources  to  promote  “social  dia¬ logue”  at  the  European  level  in  the  hope  of  stimulating  Euro-level  collective bargaining.13  His  Charter  of  Fundamental  Social  Rights  (1989)  sought  new legislation  in  areas  of  social  policy  where  the  EC  had  legal  prerogatives,  in a  not-so-hidden  hope  for  spillover  to  new  EC  social  policy  powers.14  Delors 326  Ross also  successfully  promoted  redistributive  EC-level  development  funding  for poorer  EC  regions— what  came  to  be  called  the  “structural  funds.” Delors’s  “social  Europe”  was  a  gamble,  however.  EC  Europe  worked  on  a consensus  to  which  all  Europeans,  left  or  right,  might  subscribe  that  avoided partisan  tones  and  spoke  to  common  European  interests.  But  in  the  real  world of  the  EC  the  usual  doctrinal  struggles  ground  away.  Big  business  and  the  po¬ litical  right  wanted  liberalization,  deregulation,  and  sounder  public  finances, and  they  were  happy  to  have  the  EU  make  them  happen.  They  had  little  sym¬ pathy  for  social  Europe  proposals,  regarding  them  as  steps  back  into  a  past that  they  wanted  to  leave  behind.  Delors  hoped  to  mobilize  other  groups,  in¬ cluding  unions,  to  Europeanize  and  reform  European  social  models  through social  Europe.  Business  and  neoliberal  constituencies  were  strong,  well  orga¬ nized,  and  able  to  shift  resources  easily  to  the  European  level.  Those  who might  favor  more  social  Europe,  in  contrast,  were  weaker,  less  well  organized, and  less  mobile.  Delors’s  social  Europe  enterprise  was  therefore  a  long  shot. During  the  Delors  years  liberalization  and  monetarism  went  along  with  “up¬ ward  harmonization”  in  workplace  health  and  safety,  equal  opportunities, and  environmental  policy,  in  part  because  the  relatively  wealthy  EC  countries that  counted  most  did  not  want  a  “race  to  the  bottom.”  But  momentum  toward social  Europe  had  stalled  by  the  mid-1990s,  far  short  of  Delors’s  hopes. What  was  most  significant  in  the  era  of  Delors  and  Mitterrand  went  un¬ spoken.  Shifting  national  sovereignty  to  the  EC  level  was  a  high-stakes  game that  inevitably  constrained  EC  members  to  change  domestic  policies.  “Going European”  was  a  prime  way  to  circumvent  national  reluctance  to  reform.  The single  market  program  ruled  out  non-tariff  barriers,  state  aids  to  industry, and  pumping  up  industrial  champions,  methods  that  members  of  the  French left,  among  others,  had  long  taken  for  granted.  EMU  ruled  out  excessive  in¬ flation,  high  budget  deficits,  debt,  periodic  devaluations,  and  interest  rates set  for  national  purposes,  all  honored  traditions  in  several  EC  member  states. Thus  whatever  else  they  intended,  the  accomplishments  of  Mitterrand  and Delors  at  the  European  level  bound  future  national  policies  and  practices  and obliged  European  lefts  to  adapt. The  EU  in  Middle  Age The  EU  celebrated  its  fiftieth  birthday  in  2007,  but  the  occasion  was  not  very happy.  The  single  market  had  not  had  the  promised  positive  economic  effects. EMU  had  become  a  corset  constraining  EU  members,  center-lefts  with  them, to  limit  economic  growth.  The  end  of  the  cold  war  had  obliged  EU  members to  undertake  the  complicated  new  tasks  of  enlarging  to  the  east,  necessitating European  Center-Lefts  327 a  redesign  of  EU  institutions  for  twenty-seven  members.  Amid  these  difficul¬ ties  globalization  had  exploded,  first  financially,  then  in  direct  challenges  to European  manufacturing  sectors.  But  the  particular  unfolding  of  EU  policies, their  impacts  on  EU  citizens,  and  the  ways  the  EU  then  responded  created new  puzzles.  These  responses  also  revealed  how  perplexing  a  terrain  the  EU and  its  institutions  could  be  as  a  political  arena  to  center-lefts. The  EU  Tries  Out  European-Level  Center-Leftism EMU,  designed  during  a  good  economic  period,  had  to  be  prepared  during  a severe  downturn  after  1992.15  Then,  with  a  deadline  of  1998  to  decide  EMU membership  on  the  horizon  the  Germans,  skeptical  about  eventual  members like  Italy  and  Spain,  insisted  on  a  new  Stability  and  Growth  Pact  (SGP)  that would  bind  Eurozone  members  to  any  convergence  criteria  decided  in  the future.  The  major  troublesome  issue  has  been  that  the  European  Central  Bank (ECB)  has  emphasized  price  stability  over  anything  else,  growth  included.16 When  countries  get  into  difficulty  the  ECB  holds  them  responsible  for  disci¬ plining  market  actors  and  changing  domestic  policies  (Martin  and  Ross  eds. 2004).  This  has  been  difficult  for  both  rights  and  lefts,  but  it  has  often  been the  best-organized  constituencies  of  the  center-left— like  unions  and  wel¬ fare  state  stakeholders  — that  have  been  on  the  frontline  of  the  pressures  for change. Criticism  of  the  ECB  and  the  retrenchment  that  it  enjoined  eventually  tar¬ geted  the  Stability  and  Growth  Pact.  This  was  inevitable,  since  fully  half  of EMU  members,  including  all  the  large  continental  countries  and  quite  a  few smaller  ones,  had  violated  the  taboo  against  running  annual  budget  deficits  of more  than  3%  of  GDP  at  one  time  or  another  after  2000.  SGP  reform  in  2005 gave  members  slightly  more  room  to  confront  ups  and  downs,  in  particular  in the  discounting  costs  of  future-oriented  policies  for  things  like  research  and restructuring.  In  difficult  circumstances  EMU  members  thus  could  exceed  the annual  3%  deficit,  but  they  were  also  enjoined  to  lower  deficits  when  things went  better.17 In  1993,  after  it  had  concluded  that  important  EU  economies  faced  serious longer-run  problems  in  the  run-up  to  EMU,  the  Delors  Commission  produced a  new  white  paper,  “Growth,  Competitiveness,  and  Employment,”  which urged  EU  Europe  to  mobilize  anew  to  confront  the  new  monetary  environ¬ ment  and  globalization.  Levels  of  European  growth  and  investment  had  been shrinking  over  decades,  it  noted,  and  the  EU’s  global  competitive  position  was worsening.  What  followed  was  a  manifesto  that  went  well  beyond  Delors’s early  single-market,  “social  Europe”  conceptualizations.  The  white  paper  as- 328  Ross serted  that  “creating  as  favorable  an  environment  as  possible  for  company competitiveness”  was  essential,  placing  stress  on  innovation  to  push  Europe toward  an  “information  society”  where  new  comparative  advantage  lay.  It also  called  for  more  labor  market  flexibility,  particularly  through  active  labor market  policies,  plus  substantial  welfare  state  reform.  The  document  was solidly  “center-left.”  It  began  from  recognition  of  new  constraints  from  glob¬ alization  and  from  the  EU’s  own  single-market  and  EMU  policies,  eschewed market  fundamentalism,  and  aimed  for  the  preservation  of  Europe’s  commit¬ ments  to  social  market  economies,  but  it  also  argued  that  Europeans  should cooperate  in  the  reforms  that  were  needed  to  achieve  that  preservation.  The white  paper  fell  flat  politically,  however.  EU  members,  facing  severe  domes¬ tic  problems,  were  tired  of  constant  Euro-level  tension  and  refused  its  request for  neo-Keynesian,  employment-boosting  loans. The  Lisbon  Agenda  (2000),  promoted  by  a  center-left  Portuguese  EU  presi¬ dency  and  backed  by  Tony  Blair,  focused  again  on  declining  European  global competitiveness  and  reformist  preservation  of  the  EU’s  social  market  econo¬ mies.  It  declared  that  EU  Europe  should  become  the  world’s  most  advanced “knowledge  economy”  and  restore  full  employment  by  2010.  It  proposed  a big  increase  in  Euro-level  research  and  development,  greater  coordination among  research  efforts  by  member  states,  training  for  new  skills,  new  infra¬ structure,  and  environmental  policies  for  sustainable  development.  It  also focused  on  active  labor  market  policies,  increasing  labor  force  participation, and  removing  disincentives  to  work  that  persisted  in  many  national  welfare states. Delors’s  white  paper  and  the  Lisbon  strategy  were  both  couched  in  the EU’s  usual  consensus  rhetoric,  and  their  goal  was  to  reframe  EU  perspectives on  general  European  economic  goals.  Their  results  have  been  mixed.18  Most Lisbon  policies  fell  within  national  prerogatives,  meaning  that  the  success of  European  policies  and  urging  were  dependent  on  voluntary  national  co¬ operation.  To  produce  such  cooperation  Lisbon  institutionalized  an  “Open Method  of  Coordination”  (OMC).  OMC  began  when  the  EU  set  out  general guidelines,  then  encouraged  member  states  to  hold  regular,  open  discussions about  achieving  them;  identified  national  “best  practices”  and  established indicators  of  progress;  and  finally,  publicized  successes  and  failures  by  nam¬ ing  and  shaming  from  Brussels.  OMC  used  soft  law  and  exhortation  because the  EU  lacked  harder  tools.19  The  hope  was  that  they  would  help  remodel overregulated  labor  markets  and  welfare  state  programs  while  preserving the  “European  social  model.”  The  center-right  carved  its  own  goals  out  of  the consensual  rhetoric  of  Lisbon,  which  it  sought  to  use  to  push  neoliberal  struc¬ tural  reforms.  By  2005,  with  the  strategy  far  short  of  its  goals,  Lisbon  was  re- European  Center-Lefts  329 centered  on  narrower  issues  of  structural  reform  and  liberalization,  and  re¬ sponsibilities  were  reassigned  to  national  state  governments  in  a  retreat  from OMC.  Thereafter  member  states  picked  and  chose  what  they  wanted  to  do. Delors’s  white  paper  and  the  Lisbon  strategy  were  good  examples  of center-left  thinking  about  economic  and  social  reform  applied  at  the  EU  level. They  began  proposing  ideas,  pleas,  and  programs  to  achieve  new  European competitiveness  in  globalizing  circumstances.  Since  the  EU  could  not  legally oblige  member  states  to  follow,  it  could  only  hope  to  persuade  them  to  co¬ operate  in  a  decentralized,  coordinated  way.  Would  member  states,  each  with special  economic  problems,  political  and  partisan  setups,  and  social  models, cooperate  enough  voluntarily  to  make  a  difference?  On  a  different  plane, would  OMC  be  seductive  enough  to  wean  labor  movements  and  welfare  state stakeholders,  significant  constituencies  of  the  center-left,  away  from  their deeply  entrenched,  often  corporatist  preferences?  Or,  in  contrast,  would  it simply  confuse  them  or,  worse  still,  antagonize  them? As  Lisbon  moved  toward  the  target  year  of  2010,  it  was  hard  not  to  con¬ clude  that  the  choices  proposed  by  both  Delors’s  white  paper  and  Lisbon contained  wishful  center-left  political  thinking.  The  methods  that  they  chose involved  high-minded  EU  preaching  to  member  states  to  produce  national reform,  “new  modes  of  governance,”  and  procedural  innovations  like  OMC that  covered  up  technocratic  leadership,  decentralization,  and  depoliticiza¬ tion.  These  approaches  merged  different  issues  and  policy  areas  in  untried ways  and  underplayed  European  and  national  disagreements.  Today  Lisbon has  clearly  not  accomplished  enough  to  live  up  to  the  hype  surrounding  it.20 It  is  not  at  all  clear,  for  example,  whether  it  has  helped  to  advance  Europe toward  greater  competitiveness,  its  ostensible  purpose  (Buchs  2007;  Buchs 2008).  Further,  in  other  quarters  market  fundamentalists  have  consistently derided  original  Lisbon  formulations  as  ineffective,  arguing  that  OMC  ap¬ proaches  were  too  convoluted  and  that  behind  its  consensual  words  Lisbon really  sought  to  preserve  the  European  social  models  that  were  the  real  bar¬ riers  to  new  competitiveness.  Center-left  efforts  at  the  European  level  to  tran¬ scend  the  structures  of  older  left  worlds  have  not  worked  yet,  or  perhaps  have not  worked  at  all. Troublesome  EU  Policies  =  Troubled  EU  Citizens This  lack  of  success  correlated  with  rising  public  opposition  to  the  EU  and its  policies.  During  its  first  decades  EU  leaders  had  been  able  to  count  on “permissive  consensus”  from  citizens.  This  had  left  leaders  free  to  use  the European  arena  as  long  as  they  agreed  to  do  nothing  that  caused  too  much 330  Ross national  political  grumbling.  But  in  the  decade  prior  to  its  fiftieth  birthday, the  EU  dramatically  lost  favor  with  parts  of  public  opinion.  Its  loss  of  popu¬ larity  began  as  the  Single  Market  broke  the  cocoons  of  national  development models,  EMU  normalized  an  emerging  international  price  stability  regime, and  Lisbon  tried  to  “flexibilize”  labor  markets  and  welfare  states.  The  Maas¬ tricht  Treaty  also  increased  EU  power  in  areas  like  policing,  immigration,  and foreign  and  defense  policy,  and  not  everyone  approved  of  this.21  On  another plane,  Western  European  electorates  were  not  fully  persuaded  that  enlarg¬ ing  the  EU  to  Central  and  Eastern  European  countries  was  wise,  partly  be¬ cause  leaders  did  not  really  explain  the  process  and  its  goals.  Enlargement and  Maastricht’s  unfinished  business  also  fed  constant  intergovernmental wrangling  about  adapting  EU  institutions  and  communicated  directly  to  citi¬ zens  the  deep  divisions  about  high  EU  politics.  All  this  was  presided  over  by a  generation  of  national  leaders  preoccupied  with  national  politics  and  rela¬ tively  indifferent  to  the  EU. The  most  immediate  explanation  for  the  decline  in  EU  popularity  was  the failure  of  the  Single  Market,  EMU,  and  Lisbon  Agenda  to  restore  growth,  limit unemployment,  and  respond  effectively  to  globalization.  Some  EU  countries fared  better  than  others,  but  the  problem  of  low  growth  and  high  unemploy¬ ment  persisted,  and  the  worst  performers  were  France,  Germany,  and  Italy, among  the  largest  EU  countries,  which  together  decide  the  EU’s  general  eco¬ nomic  fate.  Eurobarometer  polling  showed  that  the  EU  remained  valued  in the  abstract,  but  only  20%  associated  the  EU  with  democracy  and  prosperity, while  the  same  percentage  associated  it  with  bureaucracy  and  wasted  money. It  was  globalization  that  worried  EU  citizens  most:  42%  felt  that  the  EU  might protect  them  from  its  negative  effects,  while  40%  did  not  (Reynie  2008). The  most  spectacular  indicators  of  weakening  public  support  for  the  EU came  in  national  referenda.  In  1992  the  Danes  fired  the  first  warning  shot  by refusing  to  ratify  Maastricht  in  1992,  while  the  French  barely  voted  yes  the same  year.  The  Irish  refused  the  Nice  Treaty  in  2002.  The  French  and  Dutch refused  the  European  Constitutional  Treaty  in  2005.  Most  recently  the  Irish refused  the  Lisbon  Treaty  in  June  2008.  The  trends  revealed  in  these  votes were  worrisome  for  anyone  invested  in  European  integration.  They  were doubly  so  to  European  lefts,  for  it  was  constituencies  most  likely  to  support left  parties— workers,  the  poor,  and  social  movement  activists— who  dem¬ onstrated  the  least  enthusiasm.  The  problem  was  complicated  by  the  more favorable  disposition  toward  the  EU  of  the  new  middle-class  groups  that  the center-left  also  needed  to  attract,  making  coalition  building  a  perplexing  task (Fligstein  2008). For  center-lefts  to  have  influence  on  EU-level  policies  they  had  to  be  able European  Center-Lefts  331 to  play  at  the  EU  level,  and  for  this  they  needed  to  win  national  elections  and mobilize  national  support  behind  what  they  wanted  the  EU  to  do.  This  was a  real  challenge.  EU  market  liberalization  breached  the  borders  around  the relatively  self-contained  national  development  models  upon  which  most  lefts had  long  depended.22  Globalization  then  obliged  everyone  to  squeeze  down inflation  and  avoid  deficits  and  debt,  with  EMU  and  the  SGP  intensifying  the squeezing.  Newly  mobile  financial  markets  limited  tax  policymaking  and wage  growth  and  put  new  pressure  on  labor  markets  and  social  programs. Manufacturing  successes  of  lower-wage  areas  of  the  world  compressed  the wages  and  benefits  of  European  manufacturing  workers  and  added  to  em¬ ployment  insecurity. These  changes  coincided  with  the  end  of  socialist  dreams,  meaning  that center-lefts  had  to  find  new  grounds  to  win  the  electoral  support  they  needed to  assert  influence  at  the  EU  level.  The  saga  surrounding  the  white  paper  and Lisbon  marked  perhaps  the  Euro-level  center-left’s  best  effort  to  do  this,  and it  did  not  work,  or  at  least  has  not  yet  worked.  Persuading  traditional  left constituencies  and  stakeholders  to  hear  and  accept  new  reformist  strategies was  difficult  when  they  faced  growing  economic  insecurity  and  had  strong incentives  to  hold  on  to  positions  that  the  left  had  helped  them  win  in  the postwar  period.  To  make  things  even  harder,  new  radical  forces  were  emerg¬ ing,  particularly  from  the  new  middle  classes,  mobilized  around  very  differ¬ ent  dreams:  things  like  environmental  change,  stopping  globalization,  and anti-immigrant  populism.  The  European  world  of  center-lefts  had  become  an uncertain  place. Fragmented  Center-Lefts,  Biased  Policy  Agendas, and  Confusing  Institutions The  importance  of  the  EU  in  its  members’  domestic  politics  and  lives  has grown  enormously  in  the  last  two  decades,  to  different  degrees  in  different countries.  The  single  market  and  EMU  increased  employment  insecurity,  con¬ strained  public  finances,  and  compressed  growth,  making  it  more  difficult  for lefts  to  reward  traditional  constituencies.  Center-left  national  governments have  had  to  trim  spending,  remodel  welfare  states,  restrain  wages,  and  intro¬ duce  new  flexibility  into  labor  markets,  policies  that  have  often  run  counter to  the  expectations  of  center-left  supporters.  In  the  meantime  deindustrial¬ ization  had  reduced  the  number  of  blue-collar  workers,  undercutting  unions and  service  workers,  and  “new  middle  class”  groups  have  grown,  complicat¬ ing  coalitional  and  electoral  problems. In  the  abstract  it  makes  sense  for  center-lefts  to  work  more  effectively 332  Ross at  the  EU  level  for  the  changes  and  reforms  they  seek.  The  kinds  of  poli¬ cies  proposed  in  the  white  paper  in  1993  and  reposed  in  the  Lisbon  Agenda ought  to  be  seen  as  examples  of  this,  while  the  problems  that  the  center-lefts have  faced  underline  the  problems  of  doing  so.  The  EU  is  a  tricky  place  for center-lefts  to  work.  One  reason  is  that  the  deep  historic  trajectories  of  the EU  asymmetrically  favor  the  center-right.  The  backbone  of  what  the  EU  does, grounded  in  international  treaties,  has  been  market  liberalization  and  bud¬ getary  restraint  through  EMU,  things  which  the  center-right  has  most  often favored.  The  center-left  has  often  advocated  Euro-policies  for  “re-regulating” markets  and  redistributing  resources,  but  the  EU  has  always  been  much  better at  de-  than  re-regulating,  and  even  when  the  EU  has  re-regulated  it  has  done so  in  more  economically  liberal  ways  than  most  center-lefts  have  desired.  Be¬ yond  this,  the  treaties  have  granted  to  the  EU  only  limited  powers  to  effect redistribution,  because  most  social  and  tax  policy  matters  remain  national. This  is  no  accident:  member  states  and  national  parties  have  preferred  to keep  resources  at  home  rather  than  donate  them  to  others. The  EU’s  policy  asymmetry  is  complemented  by  the  workings  of  EU  insti¬ tutions.  Even  if  it  has  serious  mechanisms  to  promote  binding  cooperation among  members,  the  EU  remains  made  up  of  states  which  evolve  in  different ways  and  whose  national  politics  vary  greatly.  When  translated  into  different national  interests  at  the  EU  level,  this  is  one  reason  why  European  integra¬ tion  has  proceeded  by  fits  and  starts,  punctuated  by  crises.  Moreover,  at  any moment  the  EU  is  likely  to  be  inhabited  by  both  left  and  right  governments. Except  in  extraordinary  circumstances,  therefore,  not  much  can  happen  at the  EU  level  unless  a  consensus  can  be  reached  among  member  governments, right  and  left.  Because  decisions  built  on  complicated  intergovernmental negotiations  must  be  compromises  between  national  interests,  the  EU’s  pro¬ cesses  are  slow,  sometimes  too  much  so  to  reach  appropriate  decisions  in  time to  solve  important  problems  effectively. The  institutional  problems  of  reaching  consensus  have  grown  with  the  en¬ largement  of  the  EU  since  1995  from  twelve  to  twenty-seven  members.23  The political  mathematics  of  this  are  simple.  The  more  EU  members  there  are, the  greater  the  likelihood  of  a  divergence  of  preferences  about  issues  and decisions,  and  of  blocking  coalitions.  When  compared  to  national  political processes,  in  which  majorities  and  minorities  are  derived  from  electoral  re¬ sults,  it  will  be  harder  to  do  things  at  the  European  level.  All  else  being  equal, this  creates  a  bias  in  favor  of  slow  forward  movement  and  frequent  decision¬ making  problems.  This  makes  it  difficult  to  achieve  the  reforms  that  are  the center-left’s  stock  in  trade. Irrespective  of  the  limits  imposed  by  EU  institutions  on  the  left’s  influ- European  Center-Lefts  333 ence,  to  have  influence  European  lefts  need  to  agree  on  what  they  want  to do  together.  Here  is  where  the  largest  problems  for  center-lefts  arise.  Today’s center-lefts  are  as  diverse  as  their  countries,  for  several  reasons.  However realistic  center-left  elites  might  be  about  European  and  international  con¬ straints,  they  have  first  to  win  power  nationally.  The  primacy  of  this  task shapes  their  outlooks  by  path-dependent  national  histories,  policy  legacies, institutions,  organizations,  and  coalitional  patterns.24  And  European-level policies  will  affect  each  country  differently.  It  also  follows  that  when  work¬ ing  in  European  arenas  center-left  governments  will  pursue  national  inter¬ ests  that  go  beyond  and  probably  dilute  partisanship.  The  resulting  puzzle  is difficult  for  any  center-left  to  solve.  More  importantly,  different  national  out¬ looks  will  limit  the  capacities  of  center-left  parties  to  cooperate  on  Euro-level policy  goals,  if  only  because  the  degree  to  which  they  agree  to  cooperate  on these  goals  may  limit  their  capacities  to  succeed  nationally. By  now  center-lefts  have  all  accepted  new  constraints  on  what  they  can  do nationally,  but  this  has  not  appreciably  narrowed  differences  between  them, as  a  few  examples  should  demonstrate.25  All  the  members  added  when  the EU  was  enlarged  in  1995— the  Scandinavian  neutrals  except  Norway,  plus Austria— were  wealthy  and  had  extensive  experience  with  budgetary  and wage  restraint,  employment  flexibility,  and  participation  in  open  interna¬ tional  markets,  making  their  adaptation  to  post-EMU  EU  constraints  relatively easy.  British  New  Labour  had  been  prepared  by  Thatcherite  deconstruction of  the  old  Labour  world,  which  left  public  finances  in  order  and  growth  pros¬ pects  good.  New  Labour,  with  openings  for  domestic  social  policy  initiatives of  an  “activating”  kind,  could  adapt  easily  (Cronin  2004).  Continental  lefts were  the  main  problem  cases,  often  because  of  corporatist  rejection  of  labor market  and  social  policy  reforms  and  growing  electoral  problems.  The  posi¬ tion  of  the  French  Parti  Socialiste  was  complicated  by  chronic  left  pluralism. The  German  SPD,  leading  a  Red-Green  coalition  from  1998  to  2005,  faced post-unification  difficulties  and  had  to  enact  unpopular  labor  market  reforms which  helped  create  die  Linke,  a  new  rival  to  its  left.  Italy  had  divided  left coalitions  that  were  chronically  unable  to  face  its  intractable  problems.  Of the  left  parties  in  big  continental  EU  members  only  the  Spanish  PSOE,  helped by  Europeanization  and  EMU,  has  flourished.  Lefts  in  the  smaller  continen¬ tal  countries  struggled  and  to  varying  degrees  declined.  The  new  Central  and Eastern  European  lefts,  involved  in  democratic  transitions,  were  center-left from  the  beginning  and  constrained  by  the  requirements  of  joining  the  EU, but  loath  to  give  up  any  more  of  their  new  and  hard-won  sovereignty.  There were  center-lefts  and  center-lefts,  in  other  words,  each  profoundly  national and  each  affected  in  different  ways  by  what  the  EU  did. 334  Ross What  this  differentiation  implied  for  left  cooperation  at  the  European  level can  be  gleaned  from  one  of  the  rare  occasions  when  several  center-left  gov¬ ernments  held  power  at  the  same  time.  In  the  later  1990s  New  Labour,  the “plural  left”  around  the  PS  in  France,  a  center-left  coalition  in  Italy,  and  the Red-Green  coalition  in  Germany  governed  four  of  the  largest  EU  member states,  while  eleven  of  fifteen  EU  governments  leaned  leftward  more  gener¬ ally.  The  effect  was  to  impart  a  leftish  tinge  to  EU-level  politics,  leading  in  par¬ ticular  to  the  European  Employment  Strategy  (EES),  an  immediate  precursor of  the  Lisbon  Agenda.  The  EES  combined  ideas  from  socialists  in  the  European parliament,  the  Delors  white  paper  of  1993,  the  commission’s  directorate- general  for  employment  and  social  affairs  (then  led  by  a  very  clever  Swedish Social  Democrat),  and  New  Labour  “Third  Way”  prescriptions  about  employ- ability  (Aust  2004).  Its  goals  included  more  active  and  flexible  labor  markets, social  programs  sustaining  commitments  to  existing  social  models,  and  in¬ creasing  labor  force  participation.  But  because  labor  market  and  social  policy realms  remained  national,  the  EES  used  OMC  methods.  The  results,  seen  in EES  and  the  Lisbon  Agenda,  have  been  uneven  and  ambiguous.  EU  member states  could  choose  to  cooperate  more  or  less  depending  on  their  national situations.  Changes  are  ongoing,  but  are  most  rigorously  pursued  in  those countries  that  were  already  committed  to  such  things  before  the  EES  and  Lis¬ bon  were  devised.  In  other  places,  particularly  on  the  continent,  opposition to  protect  the  status  quo  has  been  strong  (Pochet  and  Zeitlin  eds.  2005;  de  la Porte  2008). The  episode  surrounding  the  EES  and  Lisbon  illustrates  just  how  weak agreement  and  cooperation  between  different  EU  member  state  lefts  can  be. New  Labour  under  Tony  Blair,  more  pro-EU  than  any  British  government  in history,  remained  Euro-skeptical  in  key  areas  — participation  in  EMU  and  EU social  policies  among  them.26  The  French  “Plural  Left”  government  under Lionel  Jospin,  cool  toward  the  EU  in  general,  was  neo-Keynesian,  dead  set against  Blairite  commitments,  and  preoccupied  with  domestic  work-sharing reforms  of  which  most  other  center-lefts  disapproved.  The  German  SPD  chan¬ cellor  Schroder,  preoccupied  with  domestic  concerns,  was  cynical  about  the EU  and  the  willingness  of  German  unions  to  undertake  changes  that  might jeopardize  their  domestic  positions.  The  Italian  left  had  usually  been  pro- European— it  played  a  key  role  in  allowing  Italy  to  join  EMU— but  the  govern¬ ment  of  the  time  was  an  unruly  multiparty  coalition  which  on  matters  of  EES and  Lisbon  domestic  reforms  was  at  the  mercy  of  refractory  neocommunists. The  Danish,  Swedish,  and  Austrian  center-lefts,  deeply  social  democratic  and in  favor  of  reforms  of  the  sort  embodied  in  EES,  were  Euro-skeptical,  in  keep¬ ing  with  traditional  perspectives  of  “don’t  touch  our  intricate  and  success- European  Center-Lefts  335 ful  domestic  arrangements.”27  Further,  in  virtually  every  case  national  trade union  movements,  whose  cooperation  in  labor  market  reforms  were  essen¬ tial,  stood  behind  their  national  governments’  varying  EU  positions,  despite the  hard  work  of  the  transnational  European  Trade  Union  Confederation.  The larger  story  was  that  even  when  center-lefts  had  a  political  edge  at  the  EU level  and  might  have  weighed  heavily  on  EU  decisions,  they  had  difficulty agreeing  on  what  the  EU  might  do  and  on  carrying  out  the  EU’s  proposals. EU  institutions  also  make  it  difficult  to  achieve  cooperation  between  Euro¬ reformists  and  the  left.28  Center-lefts  are  now  well  organized  in  a  transna¬ tional  Party  of  European  Socialists,  for  example,  but  the  European  Parliament as  an  institution  restricts  what  they  can  do.29  Unlike  national  parliaments  it cannot  initiate  legislation,  because  the  European  Commission  has  exclusive right  to  this  power.  But  to  exercise  this  power  effectively  the  commission must  solicit  cooperation  among  member  states.  Thus  it  cannot  act  like  a  gov¬ ernment  or  party  leader,  and  can  propose  only  after  carefully  gauging  what national  governments  are  willing  to  accept.30  Proposals  for  legislation  are thus  the  product  of  consensus  across  national  differences  and  party  lines.  The European  Parliament  has  usually  shared  this  consensus-oriented  outlook  and often  proceeded  on  agreement  between  center-left  and  center-right.  Without power  of  initiative,  the  EP’s  work  mainly  lies  in  scrutinizing  those  commis¬ sion  proposals  that  it  gets,  which  it  does  in  committees  rather  than  in  par¬ tisan  debate  on  the  EP  floor.  In  addition,  the  European  Parliament  is  only  a co-legislator  in  the  EU  system.  To  reach  any  decisions  it  must  negotiate  com¬ promise  with  an  intergovernmental  Council  of  Ministers. EU  institutions  in  general,  like  the  commission  and  Parliament,  are purpose-built  to  promote  and  facilitate  transnational  cooperation,  and  there¬ fore  speak  in  consensual,  pan-European  languages.  The  institutions  have  thus more  often  than  not  turned  potentially  partisan  issues  into  technocratic  ones. These  forms  of  expression  have  helped  make  the  EU  distant  from  citizens.  The intergovernmental  dimensions  of  EU-level  governance,  the  European  Coun¬ cil,  which  also  talks  in  consensus  language,  and  the  Council  of  Ministers, which  continues  to  meet  in  diplomatic  secret,  do  little  to  translate  EU  mat¬ ters  into  national  vocabularies.  The  European  Parliament  is  the  most  likely translator  of  Euro-level  politics  into  national  political  dialects,  but  it  has  not yet  replicated  national  left-right  cleavages  in  readable  ways  and  its  concerns have  rarely  penetrated  national  agendas  (Franklin  2006).  For  these  and  other reasons  elections  to  the  EP  have  had  low  participation  and  national  issues have  predominated  in  election  campaigning.  Thus  if  EU  policies  have  pro¬ found  effects,  the  EU  itself  has  so  far  not  been  able  to  Europeanize  the  perti¬ nent  political  lives  of  center-lefts. 336  Ross Conclusions:  Center-Lefts  in  Chilly  European  Climates? The  EU  is  today  in  a  difficult  situation.  Exhausting  and  complicated  debate about  the  institutional  change  needed  for  enlargement  to  twenty-seven  mem¬ bers,  interspersed  with  French  and  Dutch  no  votes  on  the  “constitutional treaty”  in  2005  and  the  Irish  no  to  its  successor,  the  Lisbon  Treaty,  in  2008, underline  chronic  problems  that  ordinary  citizens  have  in  making  sense  of the  EU.  It  is  common  to  talk  of  an  EU  “democratic  deficit,”  even  if  it  can be  argued  that  EU  institutions  meet  reasonable  constitutional  standards  for democracy.31  Whatever  one  calls  the  EU’s  political  dilemmas,  however,  the European  Union  has  serious  problems  of  legitimacy  and  credibility. EU  institutions  suffer  from  serious  “readability”  problems  as  well.  Citizens are  accustomed  to  the  structures,  cultures,  and  politics  of  the  countries  which have  first  claim  on  their  loyalties  and  identities.  Adding  another  layer  of  very different  institutions  at  the  EU  level  and  expecting  citizens  to  understand and  identify  with  them  may  be  overoptimistic.  The  European  Commission  is thus  easy  to  demonize  as  a  distant  and  irresponsible  “Brussels  bureaucracy” whose  roles  are  mysterious  except  to  insiders  aware  that  it  is  designed  to  pre¬ vent  strong  member  states  from  running  the  EU  show  and  ensure  that  govern¬ ments  honor  their  commitments.  Some  citizens  know  that  their  leaders  get together  as  the  EU  Council  of  Ministers  and  that  this  makes  a  difference,  but they  get  precious  little  information  about  how  the  council  works.  To  this  mix¬ ture  one  must  also  consider  what  the  EU  actually  does.  It  is  not  a  state,  and  is unlikely  to  become  one.  Yet  it  does  some  things  that  states  do,  shares  in  the doing  of  other  things  with  these  states  that  they  used  to  do  by  themselves, and  can  have  strong  indirect  impacts  in  areas  where  citizens  have  every  rea¬ son  to  expect  national  leaders  to  be  able  to  act  on  their  own.  The  Parliament, as  just  noted,  does  not  resemble  anyone’s  “real”  parliament.  On  top  of  all  this there  is  no  EU  “we  the  people,”  but  rather  twenty-seven  different  peoples with  different  histories,  cultures,  and  languages. All  this  places  the  EU  at  a  distance  from  most  of  its  citizens,  whether  on  the left  or  the  right,  and  when  the  EU  touches  matters  that  are  perceived  as  fun¬ damental  to  the  daily  lives  of  citizens  it  is  bound  to  stir  up  controversy.  Given that  daily  lives  are  organized  differently  from  one  EU  country  to  another,  con¬ troversies  will  take  on  different  forms.  And  since  these  days,  thanks  in  part  to center-leftish  programs  like  the  Lisbon  Agenda,  it  can  look  as  if  the  EU  is  bent on  shaping  up  its  member  states  for  liberal  globalization,  the  EU  is  likely  to be  controversial  to  wary  and  uncertain  “peoples  of  the  left.”  The  EU’s  base  of support,  such  as  it  is,  is  found  among  the  better  educated  and  better  off.  The lower  one  goes  down  the  social  ladder,  the  more  the  EU  arouses  opposition. European  Center-Lefts  337 The  center-left’s  traditional  constituencies  are  those  likely  to  be  skeptical.  A more  complex  problem  is  that  center-lefts  must  also  find  ways  to  appeal  to higher  pro-European  strata.32 In  fact  “real”  European  politics  happens  largely  in  national  arenas,  built on  what  national  governments  want  to  share  v/ith  other  EU  members  and what  they  prefer  to  keep  out  of  EU  hands.  There  exists  little  European  po¬ litical  culture  except  among  elites.  There  are  no  European  news  media— despite  the  claims  to  pan-European  status  of  Anglophone  sources  like  the Economist  and  the  Financial  Times—  just  nationally  based  media  that  inter¬ pret  EU  events  through  national  lenses.  National  parliamentary  discussions rarely  place  European  issues  squarely  before  the  public,  while  elections  to  the European  Parliament  remain  tightly  linked  to  national  political  debates.  With few  exceptions— Denmark,  for  example— national  parties  have  barely  begun to  embrace  European  matters.  The  gap  between  the  thickness  of  national democratic  deliberative  practice  and  its  thinness  at  the  European  level  is  evi¬ dent.  This  is  important  to  center-lefts,  whose  political  bases  may  be  conflicted about  the  EU  but  whose  leaders  must  also  have  strategies  to  work  at  EU  levels if  they  win  power. All  this  has  tended  to  make  European  center-lefts  more  takers  than  makers of  European-level  policies.  The  EU  decides  and  center-lefts  integrate  the  con¬ sequences  into  their  diverse  national  arenas,  like  it  or  not.  In  the  EU’s  earlier years,  when  European  integration  was  handmaiden  to  national  development models  and  EU  members  had  a  national  veto,  this  was  less  of  a  burden.  It  has become  a  much  larger  one  with  the  EU  opening  economic  and  other  borders, running  a  monetary  union,  and  engaging  in  “mission  creep”  into  broader areas  like  policing,  immigration  control,  civil  law,  education  and  research policy,  environmental  and  energy  policy,  and  foreign  and  defense  policy. Also,  today’s  EU  of  twenty-seven  members  includes  practically  all  the  peoples on  the  European  continent,  adding  to  complex  diversity. In  policy  terms  things  have  not  worked  quite  as  planned.  The  EU  has  lib¬ eralized  extensively  and  EMU  works  in  technical  terms.  But  encroaching globalization  has  meant  that  economic  growth  and  prosperity  have  returned only  for  those  who  were  already  well  prepared,  for  national  reasons,  to  grow. Those  center-lefts  that  inherited  flexible,  muscular  economic  and  social policy  systems  and  learned  to  function  without  Keynesianism  and  with  non¬ accommodating  monetary  policies  have  done  best.  Other  center-lefts,  par¬ ticularly  on  the  European  continent,  face  constituents  who  resist  the  national imposition  of  center-left  policy  formulas  and  insistently  worry  whether today’s  EU  is  a  cushion  to  ease  them  into  a  globalized  world  or,  in  contrast, an  agent  of  neoliberal  globalization.  This  is  where  things  now  stand. 338  Ross That  European  center-lefts  have  been  takers  rather  than  makers  of  Euro¬ level  politics  does  not  mean  that  they  should  be  seen  as  persistent  victims  of EU  policies.  EU  Europe  has  historically  been  an  open  arena  for  debating  re¬ formist  changes  and  sometimes  has  even  led  the  implementation  of  changes.33 While  there  has  been  much  of  bureaucrats  talking  to  other  bureaucrats  and a  few  Members  of  the  European  Parliament,  with  small  groups  of  academics and  lobbyists  listening,  some  of  the  discussion  must  be  taken  seriously,  as  his¬ torical  record  shows.  When  new  members  have  joined  the  EU  they  have  been expected  to  accept  what  is  called  the  acquis  communautaire,  the  EU’s  accu¬ mulated  institutional  rules  and  processes,  and  this  acceptance  has  enhanced their  commitment  to  human  rights,  good  governance,  and  social,  environ¬ mental,  and  other  policies.  Moreover,  the  European  power  of  northern  Euro¬ pean  “social  market”  societies  has  meant  that  European-level  policies  have usually  involved  “upward  harmonization”  rather  than  races  to  the  bottom. Environmental  policies  are  an  important  case  in  point,  but  there  are  others, such  as  equal  opportunities  between  men  and  women  in  the  workplace,  and workplace  health  and  safety.  And  even  when  the  EU  has  few  explicit  treaty powers  it  can  also  try  to  promote  reformist  change  through  decentralized “soft  law”  techniques  like  those  used  in  OMC  and  the  Lisbon  strategy. What  does  this  all  come  to?  That  EU  Europe  is  an  obstacle  course  for  center- leftists  does  not  mean  that  the  EU  is  a  paradise  for  the  neoliberal  forces:  they too  have  found  EU-level  politics  frustrating.  One  reason  is  that  today’s  EU works  badly.  It  must  function  ideologically  according  to  the  presumed  con¬ sensus,  or  at  least  the  presumed  common  interest,  of  Europeans  — 500  million individual  citizens,  different  localities,  regions,  civil  societies,  and  nation¬ states,  and,  yes,  EU  officials  and  leaders.  Any  such  EU  consensus  is  bound  to be  a  vague  common  denominator  of  the  huge  variety  of  interests  living  under and  around  the  EU’s  big  tent.  The  lack  of  clarity  that  results  is  not  comforting for  everyone. The  handicaps  of  working  with  such  a  vague  European  consensus  are  not the  same  as  those  of  winning  the  policy  struggles  whose  content  is  often obscured  by  the  EU’s  veils  of  consensus  and  difficult-to-fathom  institutional life.  It  is  hard  to  underestimate  the  significance  of  recent  EU  battles  between neoliberals  and  the  advocates  of  something  that  might  be  called  social  mar¬ ket  economies.  Lefts  and  their  center-left  successors  have  been  present  and active  in  these  battles,  which  are  far  from  over.  As  we  write,  EU  efforts  to liberalize  service  markets  and  recent  ECJ  decisions  about  freedom  of  busi¬ ness  movement  across  borders  threaten  social  and  labor  protection  programs underlying  national  social  contracts.  Center-lefts  cannot  stand  aside  on  such matters  any  more  than  on  other  battles  about  Europe’s  place  in  global  com- European  Center-Lefts  339 petition  and  the  desirable  shape  of  globalization  itself.  It  is  nonetheless  clear that  the  center-lefts  have  not  been  nearly  as  effective  as  they  might  have  been in  these  and  other  EU  skirmishes.  The  EU  demands  that  center-lefts  answer vitally  important  questions,  but  it  is  not  terribly  helpful  in  providing  them with  answers. Notes 1.  The  official  title  changes  over  time.  Until  1965  it  was  the  European  Economic Community  (EEC).  After  a  merger  treaty  in  1965  bundling  the  ECSC,  Euratom,  and  the EEC  it  became  the  European  Communities,  or  EC.  After  the  Maastricht  Treaty  was  rati¬ fied  it  became  the  European  Union,  or  EU. 2.  The  variety  grew  when  one  looked  at  the  EEC’s  near  neighborhoods.  Scandi¬ navian  lefts  built  densely  organized  egalitarian  social  democratic  systems  where  so¬ cial  actors  internalized  national  cooperation  for  international  economic  success.  The British,  determined  but  ineffective  saboteurs  at  the  start  of  the  EEC,  had  a  strong  work- erist  Labour  Party  and  a  Labour-created  public  sector  and  welfare  state  stalled  by  bad economic  policies,  a  flawed  industrial  relations  system,  and  a  collapsing  empire. 3.  The  Rome  EEC  Treaty  also  proposed  abolishing  “obstacles  to  freedom  of  move¬ ment  for  persons,  services  and  capital,”  a  reform  which,  were  it  actually  done,  might pose  an  even  bigger  threat  to  national  jobs  than  open  trade  in  manufacturing. 4.  When  the  commission  proposed  a  very  liberal  Common  Agricultural  Policy (CAP)  that  threatened  French  agricultural  subsidy  systems,  it  was  shot  down,  replaced by  a  costly  scheme  of  administered  price  supports  that  protected  EEC  farmers  interna¬ tionally. 5.  Perhaps  the  best  example  came  when  British  Labour’s  failed  “Social  Contracts” led  to  the  election  of  Margaret  Thatcher  in  1979. 6.  They  also  took  the  lead  in  promoting  direct  elections  to  the  European  Parliament and  creating  the  European  Council,  which  held  institutionalized  summits  of  member state  leaders. 7.  ERM  members  committed  to  keeping  their  currencies  within  a  “narrow  band”  of exchange  rates  as  compared  to  a  basket  of  currencies  tied  to  the  dollar,  as  well  as  to market  intervention  to  buoy  threatened  currencies  and  negotiations  to  revalue  when needed.  Revaluation  occurred  twenty-six  times  between  1979  and  1999. 8.  This  endowed  EMS  with  a  rhythm.  When  weaker  currencies  ran  up  against  the “narrow  band”  barrier,  central  banks  had  to  intervene.  Stabilization  was  often  tempo¬ rary,  however,  and  the  troubled  country  might  then  have  to  negotiate  a  revaluation, often  entailing  change  in  its  economic  policies. 9.  Wall  2008,  chapters  1-3,  provides  a  British  insider’s  account. 10.  See  Dyson  and  Featherstone  1999  for  EMU  negotiations. 11.  The  French  wanted  an  “economic  government”  to  set  EMU  macroeconomic policy,  but  the  Germans  refused,  insisting  instead  on  a  completely  independent  Euro¬ pean  Central  Bank  statutorily  committed  to  price  stability. 340  Ross 12.  Delors  2004  is  an  indispensable  source. 13.  He  managed  to  persuade  the  EU  to  invest  heavily  in  this,  getting  a  clause  dedi¬ cated  to  its  pursuit  included  in  the  SEA  and  then  pumping  up  the  finances  of  the theretofore  weak  European  Trade  Union  Confederation  to  allow  it  to  play  more  sig¬ nificantly  at  the  EU  level.  Martin  and  Ross  eds.  1999,  chapter  8. 14.  The  Social  Charter  played  a  role  in  the  domestic  politics  of  a  number  of  EC  coun¬ tries.  In  the  United  Kingdom,  for  example,  it  convinced  the  Trade  Union  Congress,  bat¬ tered  by  Thatcherism,  of  the  importance  of  Europe. 15.  Inflation  in  Germany  fed  by  the  unification  of  West  and  East  put  pressure  on EMS  currencies  and  prompted  a  severe  response  from  the  Bundesbank.  Realigning currencies  might  have  ended  the  problems,  but  few  wanted  to  try  realignment  in  the middle  of  a  French  referendum  campaign  to  ratify  Maastricht.  The  first  result  was “Black  Wednesday,”  16  September  1992,  when  the  British  pound  left  ERM,  followed  by wild  currency  fluctuations  elsewhere.  The  EMS  crisis  contributed  to  lowered  growth and  rising  unemployment— to  over  10%  in  the  larger  continental  economies,  and  made EMU  convergence  a  major  burden. 16.  In  January  1999  the  Euro  was  valued  at  $1.18,  by  autumn  2000  at  $0.80,  and  by early  2008  at  $1.60. 17.  The  “policy  mix”  between  federalized  monetary  policies  and  decentralized macroeconomic  policies  has  often  been  suboptimal.  The  “Eurogroup”  of  EMU  mem¬ bers  has  tried  to  promote  coherence  through  “broad  economic  policy  guidelines,”  but member  states  have  not  been  obliged  to  harmonize  macroeconomic  policies. 18.  Liberalizing  services  was  a  centerpiece,  but  resistance  to  a  commission  proposal in  2004  watered  down  the  directive.  Financial  services  and  energy  market  liberaliza¬ tion  are  incomplete.  Brussels  has  moved  on  chemicals  regulation  (REACH)  and  climate change,  and  talked  about  lightening  its  regulatory  hand,  with  limited  results. 19.  It  had  been  pioneered  in  the  EU  Employment  Policy,  begun  after  the  Amsterdam Treaty  in  1997  and  then  extended  to  social  policy  areas  like  “social  inclusion”  (poverty policy)  and  pension  reforms. 20.  Lisbon  has  certainly  helped  the  professional  profiles  of  the  progressive  demo¬ crats  who  have  waxed  eloquently  in— often  scholarly— journals  about  the  virtues  of OMC  as  “directly  deliberative  polyarchy,”  a  substitute  for  representative  parliamen¬ tarism. 21.  The  EU’s  rocky  foreign  policy  start  did  not  help.  The  EU  was  impotent  in  its  Yugo¬ slavian  backyard,  leaving  American  help  as  the  only  recourse. 22.  Stein  Rokkan’s  work  on  shifting  borders  and  nation  building  in  Europe  has  been resurrected  recently  in  discussions  of  European  integration  (Bartolini  2005;  Kriesi et  al.  2008). 23.  New  CEEC  members  have  just  regained  sovereignty  and  are  unlikely  to  want  to give  up  much  of  it  to  the  EU.  In  addition,  their  development  models  are  often  different from  those  of  Western  Europe  (Zielonka  2006). 24.  Schmidt  2006  hints  at  this  story,  alas  only  part,  in  trying  to  analyze  the  effects of  the  EU  on  “simple”  versus  “compound”  polities. European  Center-Lefts  341 25.  This  chapter  does  not  attempt  to  discuss  how  EU  constraints  on  national  center- lefts  actually  alter  the  structures  and  functioning  of  these  national  parties,  a  topic that  remains  badly  underresearched  and  probably  underconceptualized.  For  a  critical introduction  see  Gombert  2008. 26.  EES  and  Lisbon  demonstrated  an  aggressive  New  Labour  line  that  liberalizing reforms  of  welfare  states  and  industrial  relations  systems  was  the  only  road  to  future successes.  For  a  taste  of  aggressive  Third  Way  proselytizing  on  labor  market  and  social policy  see  Giddens  2007. 27.  See  the  essays  by  Pekarinnen,  Aylott,  Haaher,  and  Veiden  in  Notermans  ed.  2001. Chapter  12  in  Gaffney  ed.  1996  reviews  the  Scandinavian  cases. 28.  Center-rights  vary  in  similar  ways,  but  lesser  commitments  to  re-regulating  and redistributing  at  the  Euro  level  and  the  EU’s  liberal  bias  lessen  their  coordination  dif¬ ficulties. 29.  Some  experts,  like  Simon  Hix,  see  this,  plus  growing  right-left  divisions  in  the EP,  as  nourishing  stronger  “Euro”  dimensions  in  national  center-lefts.  See  Hix  2007. There  are  good  reasons  to  think  that  this  effect  will  be  limited  and  slow,  however.  On the  European  Socialist  Party  see  Ladrech  2003  and  Moschonas  2007. 30.  This  is  true  even  if  in  recent  years  commissions  have  been  appointed  in  the  wake of  European  Parliament  elections  to  reflect  the  partisan  balance  in  the  Parliament. 31.  See  Moravscik  2002. 32.  Moschonas  2008b  provides  a  different  argument,  complementary  to  what  fol¬ lows. 33.  At  the  time  of  writing,  for  example,  EU  officials  had  begun  an  extensive  debate on  the  EU’s  “social  agenda”  by  circulating  an  important  document  on  “Europe’s  Social Reality.”  See  European  Commission  2008  for  details. Conclusion Progressive  Politics  in  Tough  Times James  Cronin,  George  Ross,  and  James  Shock The  stories  told  here  are  all  about  the  fate  of  the  center-left  in  tough  times. What  made  the  times  so  tough  for  social  democrats  and  liberals  were  the three  critical  events  noted  at  the  beginning  of  this  volume:  the  end  of  capital¬ ism’s  “golden  age”  and  the  loss  of  faith  in  the  Keynesian  policies  that  guided it;  the  end  of  communism  and  its  disenchanting  effects;  and  the  globalization of  the  economy.  All  this  made  for  a  much  less  hospitable  environment  for  the center-left.  So  too  did  the  acceleration  of  the  trend  toward  postindustrial  em¬ ployment  and  the  shifts  in  social  structure  and  demography  that  accompa¬ nied  the  transition.  These  forces  were  of  course  compounded  by  the  legacies that  liberal  and  social  democratic  parties  brought  into  the  new  era.  In  some cases  the  center-left  was  clearly  uncomfortable  with  the  managed  capitalism of  the  postwar  period  and  had  trouble  reconciling  its  transformative  goals with  a  more  prosaic,  if  also  more  prosperous  and  democratic  and  equitable, reality.  In  other  cases  parties  of  the  moderate  left  had  become  rather  too  com¬ fortable  in  the  mixed  economy,  too  thoroughly  enmeshed  in  its  corporatist institutions  and  in  the  compromises  they  represented,  and  so  unable  to  think beyond  the  time  when  those  arrangements  would  cease  to  work.  In  all  cases adapting  to  an  era  of  slower  growth  and  tighter  budgets,  greater  technologi¬ cal  change,  and  a  more  demanding  and  competitive  world  economy  in  which markets  were  seen  as  more  useful  than  the  state  was  a  serious  challenge.  The main  work  of  this  book  has  been  to  chart  and  assess  this  adaptation.  Here, roughly,  is  what  we  have  found. Center-Lefts  Have  Been  Successful Center-lefts  were  historically  central  in  building,  explaining,  consolidat¬ ing,  and  lately  defending  the  modern  welfare  states  and  employment  rela- 344  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch tions  systems  which  have  protected  workers  and  citizens  in  Europe,  North America,  and  elsewhere  from  the  risks  and  uncertainties  of  capitalism.  These innovations  have  taught  us  that  peoples’  lives  need  not  be  completely  subject to  the  cycles  of  markets,  the  inequalities  that  markets  produce,  or  the  capri¬ ciousness  that  owners  of  capital  might  otherwise  demonstrate.  They  have thus  smoothed  and  humanized  what  would  have  been  much  rougher  lives  for hundreds  of  millions  of  people.  Our  first  conclusion,  therefore,  is  that  these innovations  are  still  solidly  in  place  notwithstanding  the  tough  times  and substantial  challenges,  social  changes,  and  outright  attacks.  To  be  sure,  other actors  have  contributed  to  this  result,  and  different  center-lefts  have  played their  roles  in  different  ways  to  make  this  happen.  But  absent  these  historic victories  and  the  efforts  of  center-lefts  to  maintain  them,  which  during  the tough  times  beginning  in  the  late  1970s  have  often  required  difficult  reforms, today’s  globalizing  world  would  not  have  models  to  emulate  for  those  who would  democratize  capitalism.  This  achievement  has  meant  that  neoliber¬ alism  has  not  won  the  decisive  victory  that  three  decades  of  political  domi¬ nance  might  have  led  one  to  expect. Center  Lefts  Vary  Greatly The  second  major  conclusion  to  emerge  from  this  book  is  that  there  is  no single,  universally  agreed  model  either  for  democratized  capitalism  or  for  the center-left  itself.  Some  center-lefts  have  obviously  been  more  successful  than others.  Moreover,  the  special  nature  of  each  center-left  has  created  a  wide range  of  organizations,  policy  practices,  and  goals.  Untangling  these  variants and  the  political  economies  within  which  they  have  arisen  and  worked  has been  one  of  our  most  important  tasks. The  greatest  center-left  successes,  which  provide  the  most  widely  admired models  for  many  center-lefts,  are  found  in  Scandinavia,  and  the  reasons  for this  are  elaborated  in  the  chapter  by  Jonas  Pontusson.  In  this  region  are  sev¬ eral  small,  very  well-organized  societies  where  organizations,  social  groups, citizens,  and  politicians  cooperate  at  a  high  level  to  maintain  international competitiveness  and  domestic  welfare.  Here  are  highly  coordinated  market economies  with  unusual  adaptive  capacities  and  policy  creativity  which  do very  well  on  most  performance  criteria:  growth,  employment,  innovation, per  capita  income,  productivity,  education,  social  security,  gender  equality, and  reconciling  work  and  family.  The  Swedish  system,  promoted  as  a  viable “third  way”  before  anyone  had  ever  heard  of  Tony  Blair,  is  the  envy  of  center- leftists  everywhere.  What  the  Danes  call  “flexicurity”  has  recently  been  held up  as  a  workable  and  humane  policy  response  to  a  globalized  and  highly  com- Conclusion  345 petitive  economy.  Norway  continues  to  impress,  albeit  while  benefiting  from oil  resources,  and  Finland’s  ability  to  shift  gears  after  the  cold  war  toward  a growth  model  led  by  high  technology  has  been  truly  extraordinary.  Success¬ ful  labor  market  reforms  in  the  Netherlands  may  also  have  made  the  Dutch into  honorary  Scandinavians. Scandinavian  center-lefts  are  unique.  They  all  emerged  from  very  small economies  and  largely  homogeneous  societies  which  could  only  grow  in  con¬ ditions  of  trade  openness  to  which  they  had  to  learn  to  adapt.  To  avoid  the social  disruptions  and  inequalities  that  could  have  followed  their  adapta¬ tion,  they  also  had  to  find  ways  to  help  their  citizens  manage  life  transitions. Often  they  did  so  through  institutions  that  simultaneously  obliged  employers to  innovate  and  helped  employees  to  move  from  declining  to  growing  sec¬ tors.  Many  social  democratic  formations  drew  strong  distinctions  between industrial  workers  and  other  citizens.  Most  Scandinavian  parties,  by  con¬ trast,  sought  to  promote  equality  among  citizens,  as  Sheri  Berman  underlines, through  policies  of  wage  compression,  redistribution  through  taxation,  and universal  access  to  a  wide  range  of  social  programs  and  services,  including retraining  to  facilitate  job  transitions.  This  has  turned  out  to  be  a  fundamen¬ tal  distinction. Scandinavian  center-left  approaches  have  had  one  additional  consequence. Their  combination  of  well-coordinated,  competitive  market  economies  able to  make  supply-side  adaptations  in  the  face  of  industrial  change  with  commit¬ ments  to  equal  socioeconomic  citizenship  have  been  difficult  for  opponents  to dislodge,  because  practically  everyone  has  become  a  stakeholder.  This  helps to  explain  a  recent  paradox:  the  systems  have  held  on  despite  the  electoral and  organizational  weakening  of  center-left  political  parties.  In  Sweden  so¬ cial  democrats  can  still  effectively  dominate  policymaking,  even  if  they  are  in opposition.  Norwegian  social  democrats  remain— barely— -in  control  of  broad coalitions,  but  the  model  persists.  Elsewhere  Scandinavian  center-lefts  today are  part  of  broad  coalitions  whose  precise  directions  they  often  cannot  con¬ trol,  or  in  some  places,  like  Denmark,  have  been  in  opposition  for  some  time, but  again  the  framework  remains  intact.  Scandinavian  political  economies thus  seem  durable,  even  if  center-left  political  hegemony  is  not.1 Center-lefts  on  the  European  continent,  particularly  in  France  and  Ger¬ many,  the  most  important  members  of  the  European  Union,  have  evolved  in a  different  fashion.  In  the  postwar  period  both  France  and  Germany  chose export-led  development  models,  but  in  very  different  ways.  In  both  coun¬ tries  social  democracy  came  with  a  focus  on  industrial  workers  rather  than on  equal  citizenship  for  all.  This  focus  fed  strong  concerns  about  redressing workers’  conditions  (which  in  Germany  meant  primarily  male  workers),  lead- 346  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch ing  to  compromise  with  Bismarckian  and  Christian-Democratic  social  insur¬ ance  approaches,  in  which  benefits  reflected  wage  inequalities,  and  strong measures  to  protect  industrial  workers  in  the  labor  market.  In  the  reconstruc¬ tion  years  of  high  postwar  growth  and  full  employment,  virtually  everyone was  a  “worker,”  however,  which  obscured  potential  problems. Germany  chose  corporatist  approaches  according  to  which  welfare  state programs  and  labor  market  protection  were  built  mainly  on  private  deals  be¬ tween  employers  and  unions.  One  result  was  that  Germany’s  perennially  suc¬ cessful  export  firms  built  job  security,  retraining,  in-house  flexibility,  and  a degree  of  redistribution  into  their  company  practices,  often  accompanied  by Mitbestimmung,  which  gave  workers  a  say  in  corporate  choices.  The  French model  had  similar  aims  but  used  different  techniques.  Starting  from  behind, France  under  de  Gaulle  chose  statist  techniques  to  build  national  champion exporters  alongside  its  Bismarckian,  corporatist  welfare  state  programs  and legislated  labor  market  protection  (both  strategies  were  informed  by  the goals  of  a  broad  Resistance  coalition  that  included  Christian  Democrats  but was  premised  upon  an  ideology  of  Republicanism).  Neither  the  German  nor the  French  model  has  weathered  recent  tough  times  well,  though  for  different reasons. Large  problems  appeared  first  in  France.  As  Goldhammer  and  Ross  show, French  statist  strategies  were  stymied  by  the  international  changes  that  began in  the  1970s.  Mass  unemployment  followed,  uncovering  large  categories  of citizens  who  were  not  “workers”  in  the  traditional  sense  and  so  suffered  from a  range  of  exclusions.  The  center-left,  in  power  during  much  of  this  period, devised  innovative  reforms  to  combat  surging  poverty  while  also  deliberately removing  large  numbers  from  the  workforce  and  promoting  work  sharing among  those  who  remained  in  it.  This  policy  contravened  the  conventional wisdom  of  the  moment,  which  instead  advocated  new  supply-side  activation and  more  flexible  labor  markets;  it  also  contributed  to  growing  divisions  be¬ tween  outsiders  and  insiders,  often  the  remnants  of  weak  French  unionism, who  used  their  influence  to  protect  their  advantages.  The  French  center-left suffered  greatly  as  a  result.  The  French  political  system,  in  which  the  presi¬ dency  is  the  key  to  governance,  places  a  premium  on  forming  and  managing multiparty  coalitions.  The  Socialist  Party— which  has  not  won  an  important national  election  since  1997  — has  had  great  difficulty  doing  so,  in  large  part because  of  widening  diversity  in  the  left’s  electorate,  which  has  aggravated intractable  internal  problems. The  German  story  is  different.  Germany  withstood  new  challenges  after the  1970s  because  of  its  successful  pursuit  of  monetary  stability  and  its  con¬ tinuing  adeptness  at  competing  in  export  markets.  But  unification  of  West Conclusion  347 and  East  Germany  proved  costly  and  contributed  to  a  slow  unraveling  of  col¬ lective  bargaining,  greater  unemployment,  and  rising  social  policy  expendi¬ tures.  If  Germany’s  export  sector  was  to  continue  to  conquer  international markets  as  long  as  they  remained  buoyant,  to  do  so  it  needed  strong  produc¬ tivity  gains,  leading  it  to  shed  more  and  more  labor.  One  result  has  been  that Germany’s  once-powerful  union  movement  has  fallen  into  serious  if  largely unacknowledged  decline,  as  unemployment  and  the  growing  costs  of  pen¬ sions,  healthcare,  and  unemployment  compensation  have  posed  new  prob¬ lems  for  German  governments.  The  Red-Green  coalition  (1998-2005)  led  by Gerhard  Schroder  finally  confronted  some  of  these  problems  in  ways  that have  since  proven  costly  among  social  democratic  voters,  while  at  the  same time  Germany  has  created  its  own  growing  insider-outsider  labor  market problem.  The  SPD  now  finds  itself  in  a  situation  where  sustaining  its  tradi¬ tional  working-class  base,  and  by  implication  the  German  export  sector,  runs counter  to  reforms  that  might  attenuate  the  problems  of  outsiders.  The  conse¬ quence  has  been  a  steep  decline  in  SPD  electoral  performance— to  23%  in  the parliamentary  elections  of  2009,  its  lowest  score  since  1945.  It  now  has  severe problems  in  claiming  political  leadership  and  preventing  the  rise  of  electoral competitors,  and  faces  new  and  difficult  coalition-building  tasks. “Southern”  European  center-lefts,  whose  electoral  fortunes  are  discussed by  Gerassimos  Moschonas,  have  had  different  histories  from  both  the  Scan¬ dinavians  and  the  continentals.  Portugal,  Spain,  and  Greece,  less  developed than  northern  European  countries,  all  suffered  under  unpleasant  and  protec¬ tionist  dictatorships  during  the  postwar  period.  When  the  dictators  all  fell  in the  1970s,  the  long  complicity  of  right-wing  parties  with  them  gave  center- lefts  significant  political  advantages.  The  center-lefts  then  chose  strategies  of catch-up  modernization  and  Europeanization,  and  when  in  power,  which  they have  very  often  been,  they  opened  and  remodeled  their  economies,  joined  the EU  and  received  helpful  development  aid  from  it,  improved  national  institu¬ tions,  and  revamped  social  and  labor  market  regimes.  What  is  most  signifi¬ cant  in  these  stories  is  the  difference  in  political  timing  from  the  European North.  From  the  1980s  northerners  struggled  to  adapt  over-rigid  and  costly postwar  structures,  while  southern  center-lefts  embarked  on  a  modernizing trajectory  that  presented  opportunities  to  build  electoral  strength,  win  elec¬ tions,  and  govern.2  Yet  there  are  signs  that  this  southern  trajectory  may  be running  down,  mainly  because  the  benefits  accruing  from  being  on  the  right side  of  history  are  dissipating,  while  economic  growth  has  become  harder  to engineer  and  financial  stability  increasingly  difficult  to  maintain. A  particular  goal  of  this  book  has  been  to  give  appropriate  attention  to center-lefts  in  the  “liberal  market  economies”  in  the  United  Kingdom  and  the 348  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch United  States.  The  two  cases  are  historically  rather  different.  In  the  United Kingdom  postwar  development  toward  what  might  have  resembled  a  con¬ tinental  model  was  quite  advanced  by  the  1970s,  but  it  abruptly  stopped in  1979  after  the  electoral  victory  of  a  Conservative  Party  that  under  Mar¬ garet  Thatcher  had  rediscovered  the  virtues  of  markets.  The  consequences for  Labour,  as  elaborated  by  James  Cronin,  have  been  dramatic.  Thatcher¬ ism  worked  such  fundamental  economic  and  social  changes  that  Labour  was forced  to  adapt,  since  it  could  persist  in  or  return  to  pre-1979  politics  only at  the  risk  of  electoral  irrelevancy.  The  Labour  Party  eventually  made  basic changes  in  outlook  and  strategy.  These  were  embodied  in  Blairite  “third  way” politics  whose  starting  point  was  a  broad  acceptance  of  the  more  market- oriented  policy  frameworks  that  Thatcher  had  left  behind.  The  thrust  of Labour’s  new  strategy  was  thus  to  promote  economic  management  for  bal¬ anced  growth  within  these  frameworks  and  then,  once  economic  success  was obtained,  to  use  the  fruits  of  growth  to  initiate  reforms  that  would  reinforce safety  nets,  attenuate  the  extreme  inequalities  left  by  the  Thatcher  era,  and rebuild  public  services  on  new  grounds.  New  Labour’s  record  of  success  at most  of  these  endeavors  was  considerable.  One  important  index  was  a  sub¬ stantial  reduction  after  1997  in  the  dramatic  income  inequality  that  Thatcher¬ ism  had  wrought.3  But  after  Labour  had  been  in  office  for  more  than  a  decade, support  began  to  ebb.  Labour  began  to  look  tired  and  exhausted,  it  was  stuck with  an  uncharismatic  leader  in  Gordon  Brown  whose  grip  on  the  highest office  was  nevertheless  tenacious,  and  its  record  looked  decidedly  less  im¬ pressive  as  the  economy  was  hit  by  the  financial  crisis  of  2008.  As  the  nation and  Conservatives  looked  forward  to  a  Tory  victory  in  2010  — and  got  some¬ thing  different  but  close  enough  — the  key  question  became  how  much  a  new government  would  move  away  from  the  policies  of  New  Labour.  Labour  had effectively  re-centered  the  political  settlement  left  in  place  by  Thatcher,  mov¬ ing  it  toward  the  left  by  making  it  more  humane  and  restoring  public  services and  according  to  government  a  greater  role  in  society.  Would  the  Tories  under David  Cameron  move  back  to  the  right,  hewing  to  their  Thatcherite  heritage, or  would  they  obey  the  logic  of  electoral  competition  and  fight  on  the  more centrist  ground  occupied  by  Labour  (Cronin  2009;  McKibbin  2009)?  The  un¬ usual  outcome  of  the  election  of  May  2010  seemed  to  give  at  least  an  indirect answer:  the  Tories,  in  coalition  with  the  Liberal  Democrats,  would  be  re¬ quired  to  adopt  a  rhetoric  and  style  of  politics  that  would  distinguish  their policies  from  the  still  toxic  past  evoked  by  the  name  of  Margaret  Thatcher.  To this  extent  the  settlement  brokered  by  New  Labour  would  not  be  quickly  or easily  undone  while  Labour’s  fortunes,  ironically,  might  not  easily  be  revived against  rivals  with  which  it  did  not  seem  to  differ  greatly.  The  issue  remains Conclusion  349 very  much  in  doubt,  however,  for  the  austerity  policies  proposed  by  the  coali¬ tion  are  harsh  and  contain  more  than  a  whiff  of  Thatcherism. The  American  case,  discussed  from  different  angles  by  Ruy  Teixeira, Christopher  Howard,  and  James  Shoch,  also  begins  with  a  “liberal”  market context  that  is  quite  different  from  that  of  Europe  and  a  history  different from  that  of  Britain.  The  United  States,  which  during  the  New  Deal  in  the 1930s  made  a  strong  start  toward  what  might  have  been  a  welfare  state  and an  industrial  relations  system  along  European  lines,  stalled  far  short  of  com¬ pletion  in  the  immediate  postwar  period.  Among  other  New  Deal  beginnings were  a  Bismarckian  pension  system,  the  groundwork  for  strong  labor  market regulation  in  the  Wagner  Act,  and  initiation  of  a  discussion  of  national  health insurance.  But  despite  active  Keynesian  economic  management  and  the  per¬ petuation  of  the  New  Deal  political  coalition,  reformist  momentum  slowed, sometimes  in  historically  ironic  ways.  The  development  of  trade  unions  led to  collective  bargaining  for  privately  provided  health  insurance  and  supple¬ mentary  pensions  in  ways  that  benefited  insiders  at  the  expense  of  outsiders, and  blunted  the  political  thrust  behind  campaigns  for  more  universal  pro¬ grams.  The  successful  civil  rights  movement  and  disastrous  Vietnam  War  of the  1960s  and  economic  problems  in  the  1970s  tore  apart  the  New  Deal  coali¬ tion  and  opened  the  door  to  a  powerful  neoliberal  offensive  marked  by  a  stri¬ dent  anti-statism,  a  strong  reassertion  of  individualism,  and  a  determination to  weaken  the  social  programs  and  labor  protections  created  by  the  New  Deal and  Great  Society  programs  of  the  1960s.  In  critical  respects  this  thrust  lasted longer  than  Thatcherism,  encompassing  twelve  years  after  1980,  interrupted by  the  two-term  presidency  of  Bill  Clinton,  during  much  of  which  Republi¬ cans  controlled  both  houses  of  Congress,  and  then,  until  2009,  the  two-term presidency  of  George  W.  Bush.  During  that  extended  period  the  entire  Ameri¬ can  political  spectrum  was  moved  dramatically  to  the  right,  bringing  with it  a  large  increase  in  inequality  and  an  exaggerated  insider-outsider  society in  which  the  lowest-paid  and  least  secure  were  kept  going,  more  or  less,  by harsh  workfare  policies  ( Wilentz  2008).  The  victory  of  Barack  Obama  in  2008 appeared  to  have  revived  center-left  reformism,  but  Obama  was  compelled to  start  from  a  very  low  baseline.  The  economic  stimulus  bill,  healthcare  re¬ form,  and  new  financial  regulations  were  all  important  achievements.  But in  the  face  of  intransigent  Republican  opposition,  an  ambivalent  public,  and significant  institutional  obstacles,  progress  has  been  difficult  and,  after  the Republicans’  big  gains  in  the  2010  congressional  midterm  elections,  will  be¬ come  even  harder.  Further  advance,  if  it  occurs,  will  demand  extraordinary strategic  skills  on  the  part  of  the  center-left,  and  the  results  are  likely  to  be different  from  those  in  Europe. 350  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch The  post-cold  war  center-lefts  in  Central  and  Eastern  Europe,  discussed  by De  Waele  and  Soare,  provide  yet  another  trajectory.  After  1989  there  was  no possibility  of  reforming  the  socioeconomic  order  established  by  Soviet  domi¬ nation,  and  strong  incentives  existed  instead  for  moving  decisively  toward market-based  democracies.  In  the  years  immediately  following  the  end  of communism,  this  was  the  path  taken  throughout  the  region.  Initially  the  lead was  taken  by  anticommunist  reformers,  but  in  many  places  they  were  quickly supplanted  by  parties  that  were  technically  “center-left”  but  had  been  hastily built  around  the  vertebrae  of  older  communist  parties  whose  leaders  had  con¬ verted  to  markets  and  democratic  institutions.  The  secret  of  this  odd  success story  was  the  ability  of  ex-communist  leaders  and  parties  to  shift  political and  organizational  resources  from  the  old  regime  to  new  purposes,  while competitors  had  no  comparable  resources  at  hand.  These  “successor  party” center-lefts  faced  contradictions.  Once  in  power  they  had  to  pursue  liberal¬ izing  reforms  that  displeased  their  supporters  and  undercut  their  prospects. Predictions  about  the  future  in  this  region  are  hazardous,  of  course,  because the  period  since  the  early  1990s  is  so  brief  and  the  outcomes  of  transition  re¬ main  uncertain. Center-Lefts  Are  a  Family  That  Often  Disagrees, Even  about  Its  Models  for  Society The  record  surveyed  here  leads  to  several  further  conclusions.  One  is  that even  if  center-lefts  may  have  had  broadly  similar  outlooks  and  have  faced similar  challenges  in  the  tough  times  we  examine,  their  responses  have  been divergent,  and  they  have  often  disagreed  profoundly  on  day-to-day  matters. In  brief,  center-lefts,  given  the  variety  of  their  situations,  have  had  differ¬ ent  strategies  and  goals.  This  is  mainly  because  their  actions  have  been  con¬ strained  by  different  political  economies  which  have  opened  quite  different “paths”  upon  which  they  became  “dependent.”  These  paths,  together  with significant  institutional  variations,  have  also  created  widely  varying  electoral equations.  To  illustrate,  let  us  take  the  issue  that  has  perhaps  loomed  largest for  center-lefts  in  recent  years:  the  need  to  introduce  supply-side  flexibility into  postwar  social  and  employment  policy  systems. The  Scandinavians  have  been  able  to  “flexibilize”  with  relative  ease,  even though  they  have  had  to  make  serious  changes,  because  of  their  long  ex¬ perience  with  international  openness  and  existing  practices  of  supply-side flexibility.  The  “continentals,”  in  contrast,  have  had  a  rockier  time  because changing  activation  and  flexibility  policies  has  meant  changing  benefit  sys¬ tems  and  protective  regulations,  eliciting  strong  resistance  from  entrenched Conclusion  351 interests.  The  result  has  been  reluctant,  spasmodic,  and  weak  supply-side  re¬ forms  whose  economic  effects  have  been  modest  but  which  have  nevertheless contributed  to  a  loss  of  political  support.  “Southerners”  have  faced  similarly entrenched  corporatist  interests,  but  they  have  often  been  able  to  limit  the damages  through  their  broader  modernizing  strategies.  Center-lefts  in  “lib¬ eral”  environments— the  United  Kingdom  and  the  United  States  in  our  vol¬ ume-had  to  work  with  the  consequences  of  conservative  policies  to  open markets,  make  labor  markets  more  flexible,  and  weaken  unions,  regulation, and  social  protection.  These  changes  left  a  legacy  of  flexibility  with  a  harsh, almost  Darwinian  edge.  Center-lefts  could  then  propose  new  policies  to  limit the  harshness.  In  the  new  market  democracies  of  Central  and  Eastern  Europe, center-lefts  faced  yet  again  different  choices.  With  little  choice  but  to  slash and  burn  earlier  protective  arrangements  which  had  guaranteed  social  ser¬ vices  and  jobs  (not  always  good  ones)  for  practically  everyone,  center-lefts created  “activated”  and  often  much  harsher  labor  markets  and  social  policies. Economic  growth  cushioned  these  processes  somewhat,  although  better- skilled  and  better-organized  center-rights  have  already  emerged  to  challenge these  center-lefts. There  are  many  more  examples  of  the  differences  between  center-lefts. Despite  a  general  commitment  to  greater  social  security  and  justice,  center- lefts  have  had  widely  varying  approaches  to  the  new  social  policy  challenges surrounding  what  Jane  Jenson  labels  “new  social  investment,”  particularly  in the  areas  of  “care”  and  poverty  policy.  And  while  most  center-lefts  have  be¬ come  vulnerable  to  rightist  anti-immigrant  populism,  they  have  responded  in very  different  ways— often  successfully— as  Perez  shows.  In  the  light  of  such persistent  differences  in  approach,  there  is  little  mystery  in  the  difficulty  that European  center-lefts  have  had  in  finding  common  ground  on  EU-level  poli¬ cies,  as  George  Ross  suggests. Center-Lefts  Face  Common  Challenges Despite  these  differences,  a  common  set  of  problems  confronts  center-lefts almost  everywhere.  The  most  important  is  electoral  erosion,  which  is  hap¬ pening  in  different  places  at  different  rates,  with  the  one  significant  but  only partial  and  not  necessarily  lasting  exception  of  the  United  States.  In  his  wide- ranging  essay  Gerassimos  Moschonas  notes  that  this  erosion  has  been  slow and  that  it  affects  major  center-right  parties  as  well,  although  to  a  lesser degree.  Deep  sociological  causes  undoubtedly  explain  a  great  deal.  Tradi¬ tional  lefts  were  usually  built  on  a  projection  that  industrial  workers  — with common  situations,  identities,  needs,  interests,  and  goals  — would  come  to 352  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch dominate  politically.  But  service-sector  work  and  salaried  “new  middle  class” work  has  grown  much  more  rapidly  than  traditional  working-class  occupa¬ tions.  In  addition,  those  who  do  these  “new  middle  class”  jobs  have  often  de¬ veloped  outlooks  quite  different  from  those  of  workers,  sometimes  joining single-issue  parties,  social  movements,  and  lobbies  which  disagree  with  parts of  what  center-lefts  advocate. Another  reason  for  the  slow  electoral  erosion  is  that  the  basic  program¬ matic  and  utopian  projects  that  lefts  developed  over  more  than  a  century  are now  largely  exhausted.  The  goal  of  “democratizing  capitalism”  has  largely been  achieved.  Programs  to  take  democratization  further  or  in  new  directions do  not  mobilize  in  the  ways  they  once  did.  Today’s  center-lefts  are  often  con¬ fronted  with  the  apparent  need  to  “modernize”  and  reform  what  they  have largely  put  in  place,  a  much  less  glamorous,  less  inspiring,  and  also  more  di¬ visive  project  than  before.  “Transcending  capitalism,”  the  early  left’s  utopian goal,  could  in  the  past  connect  day-to-day  reformism  to  a  grander  vision  for a  new  and  dramatically  different  society.  This  utopia  is  no  longer  politically plausible.  Markets  are  here  for  the  duration,  and  everyone  knows  it. In  the  earlier  “imaginary,”  the  goal  of  transcending  capitalism  and  the  re¬ formism  that  came  with  it  promised  successive  redistributions  that  would reach  an  end  state  in  which  privileged  capitalists  would  no  longer  exist. Center-left  reformism,  no  longer  backed  by  the  socialist  dream,  today  lives in  a  reality  which  seems  to  demand  policies  that  would  reconfigure  and  fine- tune  social  protections  and  supports,  and  redistribute  income  and  opportu¬ nity  from  some  parts  of  “the  people”  to  others.  The  goal  could  be  restated  in terms  of  “equality.”  Older  lefts  could  at  least  pretend  to  be  engaged  in  a  quest to  create  nearly  absolute  equality  among  citizens  by  positing  and  proposing to  fight  a  zero-sum  redistributive  game  with  capitalists.  Today’s  center-lefts, while  they  may  still  focus  on  reducing  excessive  wealth,  in  particular  because of  the  substantial  recent  increase  in  high-end  incomes,  are  aware  that  the concentration  of  wealth  is  only  a  small  part  of  the  “equality  puzzle”  they  face. In  many  places  large  insider-outsider  gaps  have  opened  in  which  relatively secure  salaried  employees  and  unionized  workers  coexist  with  badly  paid, insecure  workers  who  face  much  harsher  labor  market  and  living  conditions. The  need  to  respond  to  these  gaps  is  now  a  central  issue,  and  since  doing  so often  requires  shifting  resources  from  one  part  of  the  center-left’s  potential base  toward  another,  solutions  are  not  easy.  Still,  the  alternative  is  to  allow  a caste-like,  dualistic  social  order  to  emerge.  Pledging  to  increase  “equality  of opportunity,”  as  practically  everyone  has  been  doing  for  some  time,  may  be electorally  successful  on  occasion,  but  center-lefts  stand  to  lose  if  the  pledges turn  out  to  be  hollow,  as  they  very  often  have  been  in  the  past. Conclusion  353 Center-Lefts  Have  Had  Trouble  Combining  Management  and  Reform It  is  also  clear  from  our  analysis  that  center-lefts  with  serious  claims  on  gov¬ ernmental  power  have  long  had  to  strike  delicate  balances  between  managing markets  and  reforming  them.  Finding  the  right  combination  has  been  diffi¬ cult,  as  was  amply  demonstrated  throughout  the  Keynesian  postwar  era.  It may  be  that  in  some  places  electoral  decline  has  been  tied  to  an  overempha¬ sis  on  the  part  of  center-lefts  on  management  and  a  move  away  from  seri¬ ous  reformism,  a  reflex  that  would  be  understandable  in  response  to  brutal neoliberal  offensives  and  the  inroads  of  globalization.  Given  new  social  pat¬ terns  and  coalitional  difficulties,  the  challenges  of  creative  reformism  have undoubtedly  got  much  larger,  while  the  tasks  of  management  and  govern¬ ing  have  not  become  any  easier.  It  may  also  be  that  the  temptation  to  run by  proving  superior  management  skills  alone  has  grown  among  center-left parties.  Have  at  least  some  center-lefts  shifted  their  visions  too  much  from creative  reforming  to  managing  the  complexities  of  ever  more  powerful  mar¬ kets?  This  is  at  least  what  the  former  French  foreign  minister  and  socialist elder  statesman  Hubert  Vedrine  thinks.  He  found  “incomprehensible”  the miserable  results  of  center-lefts  in  elections  to  the  European  parliament  in 2009:  “Perhaps  it  is  because  so  much  of  social  democracy  over  the  last  thirty years  wanted  so  much  to  free  itself  of  the  absurdities  of  communism  and hard  left  ideas  that  they  have  shifted  too  far  in  the  other  direction.  As  a  result ideologically  they’ve  wrong-footed  themselves.  They  bought  into  the  mar¬ ket  economy,  which  they  believed  to  be  well-regulated  along  the  lines  of ‘the Rhine  capitalist  model’  and  instead  they  woke  up  in  some  kind  of  jungle” (Vedrine  2009). The  more  “managerial”  that  center-lefts  become  at  the  expense  of  propos¬ ing  distinctive  reformist  programs,  the  more  likely  it  is  that  center-left  and center-right  appeals  will  become  difficult  for  citizens  to  distinguish.  Histori¬ cally  lefts  led  reformist  crusades,  but  as  reform  has  succeeded,  the  crusading spirit  has  ebbed.  Though  differences  of  emphasis  remain,  in  recent  times  the center-lefts  in  many  countries  appear  to  stand  for  programs  and  policies  quite similar  to  those  of  their  rivals  on  the  center-right.  In  this  new  context  at  least some  voters  will  look  for  parties  that  do  have  real  crusades  on  offer,  while others  will  try  to  judge  dispassionately  between  the  comparable  platforms  of the  major  contenders  on  the  basis  of  which  is  more  likely  to  be  a  better  man¬ ager.  Still  others  will  vote  to  throw  out  incumbents  because  of  perceived  per¬ formance  failures  or  simple  boredom. The  narrowing  of  programs  and  identities  between  center-lefts  and  center- rights  has  occurred  not  only  because  of  growing  managerialism  on  the  left. 354  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch Social  changes  toward  what  many  call  post-industrialism  have  transformed center-left  parties  into  broad  cross-class  or  “catch-all”  parties  oriented toward  the  much-discussed  median  (or  swing)  voter.  Together  with  the  ad¬ vent  of  modern  polling  and  other  campaign  techniques,  this  transformation has  helped  to  erode  or  blur  left-right  partisan  distinctions  and  reduce  the importance  of  issues  altogether,  in  favor  of  an  emphasis  on  candidates’  per¬ sonal  characteristics  and  other  non-policy  factors.  This  point  should  not  be overstated,  since  incentives  remain  for  parties  to  remain  attentive  to  their informed  and  engaged  core  constituencies,  even  in  majoritarian  electoral systems  like  those  of  the  United  States  and  the  United  Kingdom  where  the pursuit  of  the  median  voter  is  more  likely  than  in  systems  based  on  propor¬ tional  representation  (PR).  In  PR  systems  the  formation  of  center-left  elec¬ toral  strategy  is  more  complex.  To  win  and  govern  effectively,  successful parties  must  appeal  to  the  political  center,  but  they  must  also  build  strong and  stable  coalitions  with  other  parties  — usually  Greens,  liberals,  or  groups further  to  the  left.  This  task,  easier  when  the  key  center-left  party  is  domi¬ nant  on  the  left  side  of  the  political  spectrum,  becomes  more  complicated when  the  center-left  is  less  dominant  and  smaller  parties  see  it  as  a  promising source  of  more  support  for  themselves.  In  such  situations,  which  appear  to  be becoming  more  typical,  the  bidding  process  for  votes  on  the  left  may  make  it much  more  difficult  for  center-lefts  to  appeal  to  critical  median  voters.  Too exclusive  a  focus  on  centrist  median  voters,  of  course,  can  lead  traditional center-left  supporters  to  defect  to  smaller  parties  to  the  left. Many  European  center-lefts  are  thus  likely  to  face  more  difficult  strategic circumstances  in  the  electoral  “tough  times”  to  come  than  they  have  done  in the  period  we  have  reviewed.  There  are  good  recent  examples  of  this.  In  the presidential  elections  of  2002  the  French  socialists  failed  to  qualify  for  the runoff  round  when  the  far-right  National  Front  got  slightly  more  votes.  Ana¬ lysts  attributed  this  failure  to  the  campaign  strategy  of  the  Socialist  candidate Lionel  Jospin,  who  focused  on  median  voters  with  the  runoff  in  mind  (which polls  indicated  he  might  well  have  won  had  he  got  through  the  primary) rather  than  attending  to  coalitional  issues  on  the  left.  In  Germany’s  general elections  in  2009  the  Social  Democrats,  threatened  with  a  loss  of  votes  to  die Linke  on  its  left,  chose  not  to  move  left.  Instead  they  decided  to  market  gov¬ ernmental  competence  against  a  Christian  Democratic  chancellor  who  could and  did  outbid  them  on  these  grounds.  Italy  presents  yet  a  different  variant: there  a  motley  collection  of  different  left-leaning  parties  — hard-line  leftists, left  liberals,  Greens,  and  a  relatively  strong  ex-Communist  party  which  has become  center-left— has  on  occasion  been  able  to  win  elections  but  not  to stick  together  on  important  policy  matters  thereafter.  As  might  be  expected, Conclusion  355 recurring  bouts  of  failure  in  government  have  had  disastrous  effects  on  the electoral  fortunes  of  the  center-left.  Dilemmas  of  this  sort  present  themselves across  Europe,  and  they  seem  to  be  getting  more  serious,  while  effective  an¬ swers  have  proved  illusive  and  at  best  temporary. Center  Lefts  in  the  Great  Recession Lefts  and  center-lefts  have  always  had  to  confront  new  situations,  chang¬ ing  realities,  and  emerging  problems.  The  onset  of  the  global  financial  crisis in  2007-8  and  the  protracted  downturn  that  ensued  meant  that  center-left parties  and  movements  which  had  barely  and  not  always  effectively  adapted to  the  post-Keynesian  and  post-communist  era  found  themselves  at  yet  an¬ other  historic  crossroads.  Are  the  stances  arrived  at  after  thirty  years  of  debate and  experimentation  likely  to  persist,  or  will  the  new  Great  Recession  lead  to another  effort  at  rethinking  and  yet  another  shift  in  orientation  and  practice? The  Great  Recession  is  the  largest  disruption  of  capitalism  to  occur  since the  Great  Depression  of  the  1930s.  The  expanded  economic  role  of  govern¬ ments  in  the  immediate  response  to  the  crisis  was  initially  interpreted  as a  rebirth  of  Keynesianism  which  could  redound  to  the  political  benefit  of the  center-left.4  The  reappearance  of  government  and  the  return  of  Keynes proved  superficial  and  short-lived,  however,  and  three  years  into  the  crisis, center-left  parties  have  profited  little  from  the  onset  of  hard  times.  Worse still,  small  but  significant  groups  of  voters  in  Europe,  including  some  who earlier  may  have  been  on  the  left,  have  opted  to  support  xenophobic  anti¬ immigrant  parties  in  ways  that  have  shifted  electoral  balances  further  to  the right.  Such  has  been  the  case  in  Sweden,  Denmark,  the  Netherlands,  Bel¬ gium,  Austria,  France,  Italy,  and  several  Central  European  countries.  And even  where  there  were  historical  and  institutional  barriers  to  this,  as  in  Ger¬ many  and  the  United  Kingdom,  there  have  been  indirect  effects  of  a  similar kind.5  In  the  United  States,  where  Obama’s  victory  raised  the  hopes  of  center- leftists  everywhere,  the  rightward  shift  has  had  a  slightly  different  shape,  but has  been  quite  as  great. The  Great  Recession  began  in  the  United  States,  where  loose  monetary policies  and  unregulated  financial  practices  stimulated  an  extraordinary housing  bubble,  which  then  burst  disastrously.  The  resulting  shock  waves shook  the  global  financial  world.  Stock  markets  dropped,  losses  decimated private  savings,  credit  dried  up,  and  governments  and  central  banks  were forced  to  bail  out  financial  institutions  because  the  functioning  of  the  “real economy”  depended  on  their  ability  to  provide  credit.  Different  emergency efforts  across  the  transatlantic  area  gradually  brought  about  a  semblance  of 356  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch stability,  and  by  mid-2009  the  initial  financial  panic  had  subsided  and  it  ap¬ peared  that  the  downward  spiral  toward  depression  had  been  limited  by  vari¬ ous  stimulus  measures. Yet  the  Great  Recession  was  not  so  easily  overcome,  as  events  in  the  Euro¬ zone  then  confirmed  (Dadush  et  al.  2010).  Initial  crisis  coordination  within the  EU  followed  the  transnational  scenario  of  bailouts,  stimulus  plans,  and reregulation  of  the  financial  sector.  There  was  one  puzzling  early  European indicator— a  North-South  divergence  in  interest  rate  spreads  on  Eurozone government  bonds  — that  was  duly  noted  and  then  filed  away.  The  bond spread  issue  exploded  in  the  spring  of  2010,  however,  threatening  to  push  the global  financial  order  again  into  chaos  and  cut  short  a  still  anemic  economic recovery.  The  initial  cause  was  Greek  national  insolvency,  which  spurred  in¬ tense  market  speculation,  but  similar  debt  problems  affected  Ireland,  Spain, Portugal,  and  even  Italy.  To  save  the  Greeks  and  then  the  Irish,  devising  new anti-crisis  measures  became  obligatory  for  richer  EU  members,  but  they  dis¬ agreed  about  what  to  do  and  took  months  to  find  compromises,  during  which the  financial  markets  chipped  away  at  the  EU’s  financial  credibility.  Even¬ tually  a  large  bailout  fund  was  put  in  place  by  the  EU  and  the  International Monetary  Fund  (IMF),  but  not  before  much  damage  was  done  to  Europe’s economy  and  to  the  EU  as  an  institution. The  acute  phase  of  the  crisis,  when  global  economic  catastrophe  threat¬ ened,  would  have  been  much  worse  had  governments  not  acted  as  they  did. But  even  with  these  actions,  the  economic  downturn  that  followed  was  pro¬ tracted  and  painful.  By  late  2009  the  drive  for  further  government  interven¬ tion  had  stalled.  Government  intervention  helped  ease  the  crisis,  but  it  was also  apparent  that  the  resilience  of  neoclassical  economics  and  opposition from  business,  parties  of  the  right,  and  fearful  voters  to  major  systemic  re¬ forms  were  great.  The  result  for  center-lefts  was  a  new  and  even  more  com¬ plicated  situation. Center-Left  Prospects Our  authors  have  gone  to  great  lengths  in  examining  the  kinds  of  reforms to  existing  social  programs  and  the  kinds  of  new  programs  that  center-lefts could  promote  to  ensure  the  maintenance  and  continued  viability  of  human¬ ized  democratic  societies  in  today’s  challenging  globalizing  environment.  As they  have  noted,  it  was  heartening  that  the  easiest  successes  in  these  areas, ensuring  the  provision  of  basic  security  and  opportunity  needs  for  entire populations,  had  been  won  in  most  places,  although  not  all,  as  the  experience of  the  United  States  shows.  There  existed  a  viable  social  model  that  center- Conclusion  357 lefts  had  done  much  to  put  in  place.  Reforming  successful  programs  and  de¬ vising  new  programs  to  meet  new  problems  are  demanding  tasks,  but  not  at all  impossible,  the  authors  believe.  Who  but  center-left  thinkers,  movements, and  parties  will  devise  paths  to  more  genuine  equal  opportunity?  Who  but the  center-left  will  put  in  place  the  new  flexibility  that  market  societies  need by  giving  people  the  educational  and  employment  resources  that  will  allow them  to  maximize  their  personal  capacities  and  confront  the  frequent  life  and occupational  transitions  that  are  already  becoming  the  norm?  Who  but  those nurtured  in  the  social  democratic  tradition  are  best  placed  to  promote  genu¬ ine  social  inclusion?  Who  but  those  long  committed  to  an  egalitarian  society can  struggle  effectively  against  deepening  inequalities  in  income  and  wealth? The  center-left  has  not  gained  much  in  the  new  century,  however,  whether in  the  “normal  times”  before  2007-8  or  since  the  Great  Recession.  Before the  crisis  center-right  parties  in  countries  like  Germany,  France,  Denmark, and  Sweden  had  already  won  power,  although  often  in  coalition,  by  promis¬ ing  to  administer  and  reform  the  welfare  state,  to  make  it  work  efficiently  in the  face  of  new  constraints  induced  by  globalization,  rather  than  roll  it  back. Sometimes  they  also  capitalized  on  growing  anti-immigrant  sentiments.  More recently  center-lefts  across  Europe  suffered  major  losses  in  the  European  par¬ liamentary  elections  of  June  2009,  and  in  September  of  the  same  year  the German  Social  Democrats  had  their  worst  national  election  vote  since  the end  of  the  Second  World  War.  Next  Labour  lost  the  British  general  election  of May  2010  and  the  Swedish  Social  Democrats  failed  to  regain  power  in  Sep¬ tember  of  the  same  year.  The  Greek,  Norwegian,  and  Portuguese  social  demo¬ crats  did  manage,  barely,  to  win  at  the  polls,  and  the  Spanish  left  managed to  cling  to  power.  But  who  would  now  want  to  be  in  government  in  Greece, Portugal,  or  Spain  in  the  aftermath  of  the  Eurozone  crisis?  With  Obama’s victory  in  2008  the  United  States  appeared  to  be  an  important  exception  to the  lack  of  center-left  political  success  in  the  Great  Recession.  It  now  seems, however,  that  Obama’s  election  was  more  a  reaction  to  the  noxious  policies of  George  W.  Bush  and  the  shock  of  economic  crisis  itself  than  any  announce¬ ment  of  a  growing  movement  for  change.6 To  put  it  simply,  the  characteristic  twentieth-century  pattern  of  enduring and  largely  class-based  political  mobilization  has  given  way  to  a  more  fluid and  unstable  environment.  This  context,  whose  maturation  was  a  key  fea¬ ture  of  the  era  covered  by  this  book,  means  that  no  party  can  be  expected to  achieve  the  sort  of  sustained  political  dominance  premised  on  a  “hege¬ monic  project”  or  “bloc”  that  once  seemed  possible.  Success  in  the  new  world of  politics  is  more  temporary  and  precarious.  The  resurgence  of  center-left parties  in  Europe  during  the  late  1990s  did  not  last,  and  not  simply  because  of 358  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch the  mistakes  of  its  leaders.  Obama’s  victory  in  the  United  States  has  been  even more  fleeting,  and  there  is  no  certainty  that  the  few  reforms  it  won  will  result in  durable  gains  for  the  party.  There  is  thus  little  certainty  either  in  Europe  or the  United  States  that  the  political  payoff  for  reengineering  relations  between state  and  society  and  creating  a  more  just  and  humane  social  model  will  be either  large  or  permanent. The  predominance  of  center-right  parties  that  we  see  today  faces  an  analo¬ gous  mix  of  uncertainties.  Just  as  center-left  parties  long  relied  on  a  big, solid  phalanx  of  working-class  votes  which  is  no  longer  so  big  nor  so  solid, parties  of  the  right  long  relied  on  the  backing  of  a  solid  alliance  of  the  upper, middle,  and  lower  middle  classes  that  is  no  longer  so  coherent  and  effective. That  coalition  — brought  together  by  fear  of  the  left  and  resistance  to  high taxes  and  union  power,  and  consolidated  by  the  cold  war— has  also  begun  to fragment.  Anticommunism  no  longer  holds  the  amalgam  together,  while  the growth  of  the  professions,  the  state,  and  services  throws  up  a  highly  educated new  middle  class  more  open  to  some  of  the  appeals  of  the  center-left,  espe¬ cially  on  social  issues.  Party  allegiance  on  the  center-right  has  therefore  also weakened,  bringing  a  politics  based  on  ad  hoc  alignments,  “wedge”  issues, and  personalities. The  medium-term  evolution  of  politics  and  policy  on  both  sides  of  the Atlantic  could  thus  converge  around  a  pattern  in  which  the  center-left  re¬ mains  an  important  and  essential  player  in  a  political  universe  without  domi¬ nant  parties.  The  implications  of  living  in  this  universe,  which  have  become clearer  in  recent  years,  are  that  center-left  victories,  when  they  come,  are modest,  while  defeats,  when  kept  within  bounds  and  understood  for  what they  are,  need  not  be  crippling.  This  is  not  an  argument  for  complacency,  for we  must  not  forget  that  center-lefts  will  still  have  important  contributions  to make  in  ensuring  that  global  capitalism  does  not  develop  unopposed  and  that its  progress  does  not  undermine  the  security  and  quality  of  life  that  parties and  movements  of  the  center-left  have  done  so  much  to  bring  about.  It  is nevertheless  a  counsel  for  patience  and  for  looking  to  the  long  term. Still,  the  prospects  of  parties  of  the  left  will  be  enhanced  precisely  to the  extent  that  they  can  provide  effective  responses  to  the  challenges  of  the present  era.  Before  the  financial  crisis  the  major  challenge  was  to  generate sustained  growth  in  a  highly  competitive  global  economy  while  preserving and  making  more  effective  the  essential  supports  that  will  make  it  possible for  ordinary  people  to  live  and  compete  in  that  world  successfully  and  with security  and  dignity.  Post-Great  Recession  conditions  add  new  challenges.  To be  sure,  the  economic  crisis  has  underlined  how  much  today’s  globalization cries  out  for  intelligent  new  governance  and  new  regulatory  initiatives  both Conclusion  359 nationally  and  internationally,  which  center-lefts,  because  they  are  more likely  to  believe  that  such  things  are  needed,  could  provide.  But  post-Great Recession  circumstances  are  likely  to  make  success  considerably  more  diffi¬ cult  to  attain.  This  is  because  staving  off  the  worst  in  the  global  financial  crisis has  turned  into  a  long-term  and  very  costly  enterprise. As  in  any  recession,  tax  revenues  declined  because  of  reduced  growth  and consumption,  while  outlays  for  social  programs  rose  considerably.  Beyond this,  when  governments  entered  the  scene  as  lenders  of  last  resort  to  shore up  credit,  employment,  and  consumption,  national  budget  deficit  and  debt levels  shot  up.  Rare  indeed  in  Europe  and  North  America  are  countries  whose annual  budget  shortfalls  after  2007  have  been  less  than  10%  annually  and whose  national  debts  have  not  ballooned.  We  should  not  forget,  however, that  the  Great  Recession  was  the  first  financial  disaster  of  the  era  of  global¬ ization,  and  this  has  made  an  ironic  difference.  The  financial  markets  that caused  the  crisis  were  quickly  called  upon  to  finance  the  new  national  debts that  the  crisis  produced.  Investors  had  to  be  repaid,  of  course,  and  this  meant that  the  markets  had  to  evaluate  the  quality  of  the  debt  instruments  that were  issued,  leading  to  the  differential  interest  rate  spreads  that  among  other things  underlay  the  Eurozone  imbroglio.  This,  perhaps  more  than  anything, limited  how  much  stimulus  different  countries  could  enact,  and  quickly  cre¬ ated  large  new  concerns  about  budgetary  stability. One  consequence  was  that  an  armada  of  international  authorities  (the G-20,  OECD,  IMF,  EU,  and  ECB,  among  others)  urged  a  massive  turn  to  aus¬ terity.  Such  a  turn,  already  begun  in  Europe  and  pressed  by  ascendant  Repub¬ licans  and  conservative  Democrats  in  the  United  States  despite  persistent  low growth  and  high  unemployment  in  both  regions,  greatly  complicates  the  stra¬ tegic  situation  for  all  political  forces.  The  level  of  austerity  imposed  on  the economically  and  fiscally  weaker  European  states  could  be  lessened  were  the stronger  states,  especially  Germany,  to  engage  in  more  fiscal  expansion,  thus boosting  exports,  growth,  and  tax  revenues  in  the  more  vulnerable  nations. But  the  continuing  hegemony  of  orthodox  economic  thinking  prevents  this. Consequently,  devising  medium-term  austerity  politics  on  the  scale  that will  be  needed  challenges  everyone.  It  may  be  less  of  a  problem  for  center- rights,  however,  to  the  degree  that  they  are  less  committed  to  social  programs involving  redistribution.  Cuts  in  existing  welfare  programs,  educational  sys¬ tems,  healthcare,  and  pensions,  like  those  that  the  recently  elected  British coalition  of  Conservatives  and  Liberal  Democrats  is  already  implementing, may  be  easier  to  make  in  the  heat  of  crisis  and  “in  the  interests  of  all”  than they  would  ordinarily  be.  Indeed,  post-crisis  conditions  may  provide  a  more propitious  moment  for  center-rights  to  work  basic  change  in  social  programs, 360  Cronin,  Ross,  and  Shoch perhaps  to  undercut  their  universality,  for  example,  than  they  have  seen  in some  time  (Vis  2010).  That  right-wing  populist  explosions  on  both  sides  of  the Atlantic  are  moving  political  discourses  and  repertories  rightward  may  also facilitate  neoliberal  declensions  of  austerity. The  situation  presents  formidable  new  challenges  to  center-lefts.  The  few center-lefts  actually  in  power,  in  Greece,  Spain,  and  Portugal,  for  example, now  have  little  choice  but  to  propose  and  administer  harsh  austerity  and  to do  so  without  dismantling  past  achievements.  This  demands  strategic  intelli¬ gence  that  few  of  these  parties  possess.  Where  center-lefts  are  now  in  oppo¬ sition  they  first  have  to  reflect  on  how  to  take  advantage  of  the  decline  in center-right  popularity  that  is  likely  to  follow  attacks  on  longstanding  social programs.  This  could  lead  them  into  a  political  minefield,  however.  They  will inevitably  be  drawn  toward  struggles  to  defend  such  programs,  but  excessive reliance  on  defensiveness  will  allow  opponents  to  label  them  as  irrespon¬ sible  naysayers  in  national  crusades  to  survive.  To  avoid  this  they  will  have to  summon  unusual  creativity  in  proposing  redesigns  of  programs  that  will also  save  money,  an  almost  impossible  task.  At  the  same  time,  they  will  also have  to  position  themselves  as  better  and  more  innovative  managers  of  aus¬ terity  than  center-rights.  The  risk  is  that  center-lefts  will  come  to  look  pro¬ grammatically  very  much  like  the  center-rights  whose  draconian  measures they  oppose.  These  are  not  altogether  new  strategic  dilemmas,  but  they  have become  much  more  difficult  to  resolve  in  Great  Recession  conditions.  The center-left’s  future  will  very  much  depend  on  whether  it  is  able  to  resolve them. Notes 1.  Volatile  new  forces  of  the  right,  mobilized  against  immigrants,  could  sap  even more  center-left  electoral  support.  Managing  coalitions  may  therefore  turn  out  to  be more  complicated  than  fending  off  neoliberalism. 2.  We  should  recall  here  the  Italian  case,  briefly  discussed  in  the  Introduction. Italy’s  center-left  probably  falls  into  its  own  category,  somewhere  between  the  other “southern”  cases  and  what  we  have  referred  to  as  the  continentals,  even  though  com¬ parative  European  politics  textbooks  often  discuss  Italy  with  northern  countries.  Italy had  no  dictators  after  the  Second  World  War,  but  it  was  politically  dominated  most of  the  time  by  the  Christian  Democrats,  whose  power  was  based  on  Catholicism,  cold war  fears  of  both  the  internal  and  the  external  left  (Italy  had  one  of  the  most  power¬ ful  and  skillful  communist  parties  in  the  world),  old-fashioned  clientelistic  patronage politics,  and  considerable  corruption.  The  country  thus  modernized  in  an  unusual  way, its  northern  half  to  levels  of  development  and  wealth  comparable  to  those  in  northern Europe,  its  southern  regions  as  poor  as  the  poorest  parts  of  Latin  Europe,  its  institu- Conclusion  361 tions  and  welfare  state  a  mixture  of  clientelism  and  modernity.  Once  the  center-left was  able  to  make  claims  on  governing  after  both  Christian  Democracy  and  the  cold war  collapsed  in  the  1990s,  it  suffered  from  serious  multipartisan  pluralism.  It  was able  to  win  and  sometimes,  as  in  the  mid-1990s,  able  to  work  significant  change,  but eventually  its  coalitions  would  collapse  in  acrimony,  recently  giving  way  to  the  odd, sometimes  clownish,  charismatic  politics  of  Silvio  Berlusconi. 3.  See  the  OECD’s  recent  report  Growing  Unequal?  (20o8e). 4.  On  the  revival  of  Keynes  see  Skidelsky  2009. 5.  It  is  almost  as  if  contemporary  successors  of  the  crisis-shaped  electoral  move¬ ments  of  the  early  1930s,  which  were  often  protectionist,  are  now  xenophobic.  Stu¬ dents  of  electoral  politics  may  soon  be  able  to  explain  this  better  than  we  can  now, but  the  answer  may  lie  in  political  economy:  it  may  be  that  broad-scale  protection¬ ists  movements  have  been  more  or  less  ruled  out  by  economic  globalization,  which has  greatly  increased  the  strength  of  elites  and  domestic  interests  with  stakes  in  open international  markets.  Instead,  the  sentiments  that  once  rallied  behind  protectionism and  restrictions  on  the  movement  of  goods  are  now  turned  against  the  international migration  of  persons. 6.  Obama’s  presidency  managed  to  pass  a  major  reform  of  American  healthcare and  the  financial  sector  over  fierce  Republican  opposition  in  Congress,  but  at  the  cost of  many  of  the  other  changes  that  it  had  initially  promised,  after  which  it  was  stymied politically.  Worse  still,  a  confluence  of  different  anti-statist,  populist,  and  conservative oppositions  accusing  Obama  of  a  multiplicity  of  alleged  sins,  including  a  desire  to  in¬ stall  “European-style  socialism,”  helped  Republicans  win  a  massive  victory  in  the  2010 midterm  elections.  The  question  for  the  American  center-left  then  became  whether  it would  be  able  to  find  enough  support  in  2012  to  reelect  Obama  rather  more  than  how to  pursue  any  new  progressive  agenda. Bibliography Abrajano,  Marisa,  Michael  Alvarez,  and  Jonathan  Nagler.  2005.  “The  Hispanic  Vote in  the  2004  Presidential  Election:  Insecurity  and  Moral  Concerns.”  Journal  of Politics  70,  no.  2  (April),  368-82. Adema,  Willem,  and  Maxime  Ladaique.  2005.  Net  Social  Expenditure.  Paris:  OECD. Agh,  Attila.  1995.  “The  Case  of  the  Hungarian  Socialist  Party.”  Party  Politics  1,  no.  4 (October),  491-514. - .  2004.  “The  Europeanization  of  Social  Democracy  in  East  Central  Europe.” Europaische  Politik  4  (August),  1-9. Ahlberg,  Jenny,  Christine  Roman,  and  Simon  Duncan.  2008.  “Actualizing  the  ‘Demo¬ cratic  Family’?  Swedish  Policy  Rhetoric  versus  Family  Practices.”  Social  Politics: International  Studies  in  Gender,  State  and  Society  15,  no.  1  (spring),  79-100. Aiginger,  Karl.  2008.  “New  Challenges  for  the  European  Model  and  How  to  Cope with  It.”  Growth  versus  Security:  Old  and  New  EU  Members’  Quest  for  a  New  Eco¬ nomic  and  Social  Model,  ed.  Wojciech  Bienkowski,  Josef  C.  Brada,  and  Mariusz-Jan Radio.  Basingstoke:  Palgrave  Macmillan. Akard,  Patrick.  1998.  “Where  Are  All  the  Democrats?  The  Limits  of  Economic  Policy Reform.”  Social  Policy  and  the  Conservative  Agenda,  ed.  Clarence  Y.  H.  Lo  and Michael  Schwartz,  187-209.  Malden,  Mass.:  Blackwell. Alesina,  Alberto  F.,  Edward  L.  Glaeser,  and  Bruce  Sacerdote.  2001.  “Why  Doesn’t  the US  Have  a  European-Style  Welfare  System?”  NBER  Working  Paper  W8524. Allan,  James  P.,  and  Lyle  Scruggs.  2004.  “Political  Partisanship  and  Welfare  State Reform  in  Advanced  Industrial  Societies  ."American  Journal  of  Political  Science  48, no.  3  (July),  496-512. Allen,  Christopher.  2009.  ‘“Empty  Nets’:  Social  Democracy  and  the  ‘Catch-All  Party Thesis’  in  Germany  and  Sweden.”  Party  Politics  15,  no.  5  (September),  635-53. Amenta,  Edwin.  1998.  Bold  Relief:  Institutional  Politics  and  the  Origins  of  Modem American  Social  Policy.  Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press. Amin,  Ash,  ed.  1995.  Post-Fordism:  A  Reader.  Malden,  Mass.:  Wiley-Blackwell. Andersen,  Jorgen  Goul.  2007.  “The  Danish  Welfare  State  as  ‘Politics  for  Markets’: Combining  Equality  and  Competitiveness  in  a  Global  Economy.”  New  Political Economy  12,  no.  1  (March),  71-78. Anderson,  Perry.  2007.  “Jottings  on  the  Conjuncture.”  New  Left  Review  48  (Novem- ber-December). Anderson,  Perry,  and  Patrick  Camiller.  1994.  Mapping  the  West  European  Left.  Lon¬ don:  Verso. 364  Bibliography Armstrong,  Philip,  Andrew  Glyn,  and  John  Harrison.  1991.  Capitalism  since  1945.  New York:  Basil  Blackwell. Arter,  David.  2003.  “Scandinavia:  What’s  Left  Is  the  Social  Democratic  Welfare  Con¬ sensus.”  Parliamentary  Affairs  56,  no.  1  (January),  75-98. Ashbee,  Edward,  and  Alex  Wadden.  2010.  “The  Obama  Administration  and  United States  Trade  Policy.”  Political  Quarterly  81,  no.  2  (April-June),  253-62. Aust,  Andreas.  2004.  “From  ‘Eurokeynesianism’  to  the  ‘Third  Way’:  The  Party  of European  Socialists  (PES)  and  European  Employment  Policies.”  Social  Democratic Party  Policies  in  Contemporary  Europe,  ed.  Giuliano  Bonoli  and  Martin  Powell. London:  Routledge. Aust,  Andreas,  and  Frank  Bonker.  2004.  “New  Social  Risks  in  a  Conservative  Welfare State.”  New  Risks,  New  Welfare:  The  Transformation  of  the  European  Welfare  State, ed.  Peter  Taylor-Gooby,  29-54.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Aylott,  Nicholas.  2001.  “The  Swedish  Social  Democratic  Party.”  Social  Democracy  and Monetary  Union,  ed.  Ton  Notermans.  New  York:  Berghahn. Aylott,  Nicholas,  and  Niklas  Bolin.  2007.  “Towards  a  Two-Party  System?  The  Swedish Parliamentary  Election  of  September  2006.”  West  European  Politics  30,  no.  3 (May),  621-33. Baer,  Kenneth  S.  2000.  Reinventing  Democrats:  The  Politics  of  Liberalism  from  Reagan to  Clinton.  Lawrence:  University  Press  of  Kansas. Bailey,  David.  2009a.  The  Political  Economy  of  European  Social  Democracy:  A  Critical Realist  Approach.  New  York:  Routledge. - .  2009b.  “A  Critical  Explanation  of  the  ‘New’  Social  Democratic  Turn  to  ‘Social Europe’:  (Not  Quite)  Reconciling  Some  Real  Contradictions.”  Paper  presented  at the  annual  conference  of  the  Political  Studies  Association,  Manchester,  England, 7-9  April. Baldwin,  Peter.  2009.  The  Narcissism  of  Minor  Differences:  How  American  and  Europe Are  Alike.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. Baldwin,  Robert  E.,  and  Christopher  S.  Magee.  2000.  Congressional  Trade  Votes:  From NAFTA  Approval  to  Fast-Track  Defeat.  Washington:  Institute  for  International  Eco¬ nomics. Bale,  Tim.  2010.  The  Conservative  Party:  From  Thatcher  to  Cameron.  Cambridge: Polity. Bardwell,  Kedron.  2000.  “The  Puzzling  Decline  in  House  Support  for  Free  Trade:  Was Fast  Track  a  Referendum  on  NAFTA?”  Legislative  Studies  Quarterly  25,  no.  4 (November),  591-610. Bartels,  Larry  M.  2004.  “Partisan  Politics  and  the  U.S.  Income  Distribution.”  http:// www.princeton.edu/~bartels/income.pdf. Bartolini,  Stefano.  2005.  Restructuring  Europe.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University Press. - .  2007.  The  Political  Mobilization  of  the  European  Left,  1860-1980:  The  Class Cleavage.  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press. Becker,  Frans,  and  Rene  Cuperus.  2007.  “The  Political  Centre  under  Pressure:  Elec¬ tions  in  the  Netherlands.”  Netherlands  Policy  Network,  www.policy-network.net. Becker,  Jean-Jacques.  1998.  Crises  et  altemances,  1974-1995.  Paris:  Le  Seuil. Bibliography  365 Becker,  Uwe.  2007.  “The  Scandinavian  Model:  Still  an  Example  for  Europe?”  Inter¬ nationale  Politik  und  Gesellschaft  online  /  International  Politics  and  Society  no.  4, 41-57- - .  2009.  Open  Varieties  of  Capitalism:  Continuity,  Change  and  Performances.  New York:  Palgrave  Macmillan. Benner,  Mats.  2003.  “The  Scandinavian  Challenge:  The  Future  of  Advanced  Welfare States  in  the  Knowledge  Economy.”  Acta  sociologica  46,  no.  2  (June),  132-49. Berger,  Stefan.  2004.  “Nothing  but  Doom  and  Gloom  in  the  House  of  Social  Democ¬ racy?  An  Upbeat  Assessment  of  European  Social  Democracy’s  Future.”  Labour History  Review  69,  no.  1. Bergh,  Anders,  and  Gissur  Erlingsson.  2009.  “Liberalization  without  Retrenchment.” Scandinavian  Political  Studies  32,  no.  1  (March),  71-93. Bergounioux,  Alain,  and  Gerard  Grunberg.  1996.  L’utopie  a  I’epreuve,  lesocialisme europeen  au  XXe  siecle.  Paris:  Fallois. Berkowitz,  Edward  D.  1991.  America’s  Welfare  State:  From  Roosevelt  to  Reagan.  Balti¬ more:  Johns  Hopkins  University  Press. Berman,  Sheri.  2006.  The  Primacy  of  Politics:  Social  Democracy  and  the  Making  of Europe’s  Twentieth  Century.  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press. - .  2009.  “Unheralded  Battle:  Capitalism,  the  Left,  Social  Democracy,  and Democratic  Socialism.”  Dissent  (winter). Bernard,  Paul,  and  Guillaume  Boucher.  2007.  “Institutional  Competitiveness,  Social Investment,  and  Welfare  Regimes.”  Regulation  and  Governance  1,  no.  3  (Septem¬ ber),  213-29. Bernstein,  Eduard.  1898.  “The  Struggle  for  Social  Democracy  and  the  Social  Revolu¬ tion.”  Neue  Zeit,  19  January. Bertram,  Eva  C.  2007.  “The  Institutional  Origins  of ‘Workfarist’  Social  Policy.”  Studies in  American  Political  Development  21,  no.  2  (October),  203-29. Betz,  Hans-Georg.  1993.  “The  New  Politics  of  Resentment:  Radical  Right-Wing  Popu¬ list  Parties  in  Western  Europe.”  Comparative  Politics  25,  no.  4,  413-28. Biglaiser,  Glen,  David  J.  Jackson,  and  Jeffrey  S.  Peake.  2004.  “Back  on  Track:  Support for  Presidential  Trade  Authority  in  the  House  of  Representatives.”  American  Poli¬ tics  Research  32,  no.  6  (November),  679-97. Binder,  Sarah  A.  2003.  Stalemate:  Causes  and  Consequences  of  Legislative  Gridlock. Washington:  Brookings  Institution. Birchall,  Ana.  2007.  “Education:  Cornerstone  of  the  Romanian  Social  Model,”  http:// www.policy-network.net/publications/articles.aspx7id =1080. Blair,  Tony.  1999.  “Doctrine  of  the  International  Community.”  London:  Prime  Minis¬ ter’s  Office,  24  April,  http://www.number10.gov.uk/Page1297. - .  2002.  “PM  Speech  on  Welfare  Reform,”  10  June. Blair,  Tony,  and  Gerhard  Schroder.  1999.  The  Third  Way  /  Die  neue  Mitte.  London: Labour  Party,  www.pmo.gov.uk/output/Page1716.asp. Blau,  Francine,  and  Lawrence  Kahn.  2005.  “Do  Cognitive  Test  Scores  Explain  Higher U.S.  Wage  Inequality?”  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics  87,  no.  1  (February), 184-93- 366  Bibliography Blonigen,  Bruce.  2008.  “New  Evidence  on  the  Formation  of  Trade  Policy  Prefer¬ ences.”  NBER  Working  Paper  14627,  December. Blumenthal,  Sidney.  1986.  The  Rise  of  the  Counterestablishment:  From  Conserva¬ tive  Ideology  to  Political  Power.  New  York:  Times  Books. Blyth,  Mark.  2002.  Great  Transformations:  Economic  Ideas  and  Institutional  Change  in the  Twentieth  Century.  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press. Boix,  Carles.  1998.  Political  Parties,  Growth  and  Equality:  Conservative  and  Social Democratic  Economic  Strategies  in  the  World  Economy.  New  York:  Cambridge  Uni¬ versity  Press. - .  2001.  “European  Monetary  Union  and  the  Spanish  Left.”  Social  Democracy and  Monetary  Union,  ed.  Ton  Notermans.  New  York:  Berghahn. - .  2006.  “Between  Redistribution  and  Trade:  The  Political  Economy  of  Protec¬ tionism  and  Domestic  Compensation.”  Globalization  and  Egalitarian  Redistribution, ed.  Pranab  Bardhan,  Samuel  Bowles,  and  Michael  Wallerstein,  192-216.  Princeton: Princeton  University  Press. Bond,  Jon  R.,  and  Richard  Fleisher,  eds.  2000.  Polarized  Politics:  Congress  and  the President  in  a  Partisan  Era.  Washington:  CQ  Press. Bonoli,  Giuliano.  2004.  “Social  Democratic  Party  Policies  in  Europe,  towards  a  Third Way?”  Social  Democratic  Party  Policies  in  Contemporary  Europe,  ed.  Giuliano Bonoli  and  Martin  Powell,  197-213.  London:  Routledge. - .  2005.  “The  Politics  of  the  New  Social  Policies:  Providing  Coverage  against New  Social  Risks  in  Mature  Welfare  States.”  Policy  and  Politics  33,  no.  3  (July), 431-49- - .  2006.  “New  Social  Risks  and  the  Politics  of  Post-Industrial  Social  Policies.” The  Politics  of  Post-Industrial  Welfare  Society,  ed.  Klaus  Armingeon  and  Giuliano Bonoli,  3-26.  New  York:  Routledge. Bonoli,  Giuliano,  and  Martin  Powell,  eds.  2004.  Social  Democratic  Party  Policies  in Contemporary  Europe.  London:  Routledge. Brady,  David,  Jason  Beckfield,  and  Wei  Zhao.  2007.  “The  Consequences  of  Economic Globalization  for  Affluent  Democracies.”  Annual  Review  of  Sociology  33,  313-34. Braunthal,  Gerard.  1994.  The  German  Social  Democrats  since  1969.  Boulder:  Westview. Braunthal,  Julius.  1967.  History  of  the  International,  1864-1914.  New  York:  Praeger. Brooks,  Clem,  and  Jeff  Manza.  2007.  Why  Welfare  States  Persist:  The  Importance  of Public  Opinion  in  Democracies.  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press. Buchs,  Milena.  2007.  New  Governance  in  European  Social  Policy:  The  Open  Method  of Co-ordination.  Basingstoke:  Palgrave. - .  2008.  “How  Legitimate  Is  the  Open  Method  of  Coordination?”  Journal  of Common  Market  Studies  46,  no.  4  (September),  765-86. Buras,  Piotr.  2005.  “Polish  Social  Democracy,  Policy  Transfer  and  Programmatic Change.”  Journal  of  Communist  Studies  and  Transition  Politics  21,  no.  1  (March), 84-104. Burgoon,  Brian.  2009.  “Globalization  and  Backlash:  Polanyi’s  Revenge?”  Review  of International  Political  Economy  16,  no.  2, 145-77. Burgoon,  Brian,  and  Michael  J.  Hiscox.  2000.  “Trade  Openness  and  Political  Com- Bibliography  367 pensation:  Labor  Demands  for  Adjustment  Assistance.”  Paper  presented  at  the annual  meeting  of  the  American  Political  Science  Association,  Washington. - .  2008.  “Who’s  Afraid  of  Trade  Adjustment  Assistance?  Individual  Attitudes  to Trade-Targeted  Adjustment  Assistance  in  the  United  States.”  Paper  presented  at the  annual  meeting  of  the  American  Political  Science  Association,  Boston. Burk,  Kathleen,  and  Alec  Cairncross.  1982.  “Goodbye,  Great  Britain”:  The  1976  IMF Crisis.  New  Haven:  Yale  University  Press. Busemeyer,  Marius.  2009.  “From  Myth  to  Reality:  Globalization  and  Public  Spending in  OECD  Countries  Revisited.”  European  Journal  of  Political  Research  48,  no.  4 (June),  455-82. Callaghan,  John.  2000.  “The  Rise  and  Fall  of  the  Alternative  Economic  Strategy: From  the  Internationalisation  of  Capital  to  ‘Globalisation.’”  Contemporary  British History  14,  no.  3  (autumn),  105-30. - .  2002.  “Social  Democracy  and  Globalisation:  The  Limits  of  Social  Democracy in  Historical  Perspective.”  British  Journal  of  Politics  and  International  Relations  4, no.  3  (October),  429-51. Callaghan,  John,  and  Sean  Tunney.  2001.  “The  End  of  Social  Democracy?”  Politics  21, no.  1  (February),  63-72. Calmfors,  Lars,  Anders  Forslund,  and  Maria  Hemstrom.  2002.  “Does  Active  Labour Market  Policy  Work?  Lessons  from  the  Swedish  Experiences.”  CESifo  Working Paper  675,  no.  4. Cameron,  David  R.,  and  Soo  Yeon  Kim.  2006.  “Trade,  Political  Institutions,  and  the Size  of  Government.”  Globalization  and  Self-Determination:  Is  the  Nation-State under  Siege?,  ed.  David  R.  Cameron,  Gustav  Ranis,  and  Annalisa  Zinn,  15-50. London:  Routledge. Cameron,  Maxwell  A.,  and  Brian  W.  Tomlin.  2000.  The  Making  of  NAFTA:  How  the Deal  Was  Done.  Ithaca:  Cornell  University  Press. Campbell,  Andrea  Louise.  2003.  How  Policies  Make  Citizens:  Senior  Political  Activism and  the  American  Welfare  State.  Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press. Campbell,  Andrea  Louise,  and  Kimberley  J.  Morgan.  2005.  “Financing  the  Welfare State:  Elite  Politics  and  the  Decline  of  the  Social  Insurance  Model  in  America.” Studies  in  American  Political  Development  19,  no.  2  (October),  173-95. Campbell,  Joan,  ed.  1992.  European  Labor  Unions.  New  York:  Greenwood. Campbell,  John  L.,  and  Ove  K.  Pedersen.  2007.  “Institutional  Competitiveness  in  the Global  Economy:  Denmark,  the  United  States,  and  the  Varieties  of  Capitalism.” Regulation  and  Governance  1,  no.  3  (September),  230-46. Cantril,  Albert  H.,  and  Susan  Davis  Cantril.  1999.  Reading  Mixed  Signals:  Ambivalence in  American  Public  Opinion  about  Government.  Washington:  Woodrow  Wilson Center  Press. Carr,  William.  1987.  “German  Social  Democracy  since  1945.”  Bernstein  to  Brandt:  A Short  History  of  German  Social  Democracy,  ed.  Roger  Fletcher.  London:  Edward Arnold. Castells,  Manuel.  2000.  The  Rise  of  the  Network  Society,  2nd  edn.  Malden,  Mass.: Blackwell. 368  Bibliography Castles,  Francis.  1978.  The  Social  Democratic  Image  of  Society.  London:  Routledge. - .  2004.  The  Future  of  the  Welfare  State:  Crisis  Myths  and  Crisis  Realities.  Oxford: Oxford  University  Press. - .  2005.  “Social  Expenditures  in  the  1990s:  Data  and  Determinants.”  Policy  and Politics  33,  no.  3  (July),  411-30. Castles,  Stephen.  1986.  “The  Guest-Worker  in  Western  Europe:  An  Obituary.”  Interna¬ tional  Migration  Review  20,  no.  4  (winter),  761-78  [special  issue:  Temporary Worker  Programs:  Mechanisms,  Conditions,  Consequences], Cautres,  Bruno,  and  Anthony  Heath.  1996.  “Declin  du  ‘vote  de  classe?’  une  analyse comparative  en  France  et  en  Grande-Bretagne.”  Revue  intemationale  de  politique comparee  3,  no.  3,  566-68. CERC  (Conseil  Emploi  Revenus  Cohesion  Sociale).  2002.  La  longue  route  vers  VEuro. Paris:  Documentation  Franqaise. Cerny,  Philip  G.  2000.  “Political  Globalization  and  the  Competition  State.”  Political Economy  and  the  Changing  Global  Order,  2nd  edn,  ed.  Richard  Stubbs  and  Geof¬ frey  R.  D.  Underhill,  300-309.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. Chaloff,  Jonathan.  2005.  “Italy.”  Immigration  as  a  Labor  Market  Strategy:  European and  North  American  Perspectives,  ed.  Jan  Niessen  and  Yongmi  Schiebel.  Brussels: Migration  Policy  Group. Clark,  Colin.  1940.  Conditions  of  Economic  Progress.  London:  Macmillan. Clasen,  Jochen,  and  Daniel  Clegg.  2006.  “New  Labour  Market  Risks  and  the  Revision of  Unemployment  Protection  Systems  in  Europe.”  The  Politics  of  Post-Industrial Welfare  Society,  ed.  Klaus  Armingeon  and  Giuliano  Bonoli,  192-210.  New  York: Routledge. Clayton,  Richard,  and  Jonas  Pontusson.  1998.  “Welfare-State  Retrenchment  Revis¬ ited:  Entitlement  Cuts,  Public  Sector  Restructuring,  and  Inegalitarian  Trends  in Advanced  Capitalist  Societies.”  World  Politics  51,  no.  1  (October),  67-98. Coalition  Agreement.  2005.  www.spd.de/sh0w/1683399/K0aliti0nsvertrag2005_engl .pdf. Coates,  David,  and  Joel  Krieger.  2004.  Blair’s  War.  Cambridge:  Polity. Cohen,  G.  A.  1999.  If  You’re  an  Egalitarian,  How  Come  You’re  So  Rich?  Cambridge: Harvard  University  Press. Colarizi,  Simona.  1996.  “Socialist  Constraints  following  the  War.”  Italian  Socialism, ed.  Spencer  Di  Scala.  Amherst:  University  of  Massachusetts  Press. Collins,  Robert  M.  2000.  More:  The  Politics  of  Economic  Growth  in  Postwar  America. New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. Colton,  Joel.  1966.  Leon  Blum.  New  York:  Alfred  A.  Knopf. Congressional  Budget  Office.  2007.  Utilization  of  Tax  Incentives  for  Retirement  Saving: Update  to  2003.  Washington:  Congressional  Budget  Office. Conley,  Richard  S.  1999.  “Derailing  Presidential  Fast-Track  Authority:  The  Impact  of Constituency  Pressures  and  Political  Ideology  on  Trade  Policy  in  Congress.”  Politi¬ cal  Research  Quarterly  52,  no.  4  (December),  785-99. Constant,  Amelie,  and  Klaus  F.  Zimmermann.  2005.  “Immigrant  Performance  and Selective  Immigration  Policy:  A  European  Perspective.”  National  Institute  Economic Review  194,  no.  1  (October),  94-105. Bibliography  369 Coriat,  Benjamin,  Pascal  Petit,  and  Genevieve  Schmeder,  eds.  2006.  The  Hardship  of Nations:  Exploring  the  Paths  of  Modem  Capitalism.  Northampton,  Mass.:  Edward Elgar. Cronin,  James.  2004.  New  Labour’s  Pasts:  The  Labour  Party  and  Its  Discontents.  Lon¬ don:  Pearson  Longman. - .  2006.  “New  Labour’s  Escape  from  Class  Politics.”  Journal  of  the  Historical Society  6,  no.  1  (March),  47-68. - .  2009.  “Converging  at  the  Center  in  Britain.”  Current  History  108,  no.  716 (March),  110-16. Crosland,  C.  A.  R.  1967.  The  Future  of  Socialism.  London:  Fletcher  and  Son. Crouch,  Colin.  2005.  Capitalist  Diversity  and  Change:  Recombinant  Governance  and Institutional  Entrepreneurs.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. CSJ  (Commission  on  Social  Justice).  1994.  Social  Justice:  Strategies  for  National  Re¬ newal:  Report  of  the  Commission  on  Social  Justice.  London:  Vintage. Cunningham,  Peter,  and  James  Kirby.  2004.  “Children’s  Health  Coverage:  A  Quarter- Century  of  Change.”  Health  Affairs  23,  no.  5  (September-October),  27-38. Cuperus,  Rene.  2007.  “Populism  against  Globalisation:  A  New  European  Revolt.” The  Challenge  of  Immigration  and  Social  Integration  in  Western  Societies.  Pamphlet of  Policy  Network  and  the  Friedrich  Ebert  Stiftung,  www.policy-network .net. Cuperus,  Rene,  Karl  Duffek,  and  Johannes  Kandel.  2001.  “European  Social  Democ¬ racy:  A  Story  of  Multiple  Third  Ways:  An  Introduction.”  Multiple  Third  Ways.  Am¬ sterdam:  Wardi  Beckman. Cuperus,  Rene,  and  Johannes  Kandel.  1998.  “The  Magical  Return  of  Social  Democ¬ racy.”  Social  Democracy:  Transformation  in  Progress,  ed.  R.  Cuperus  and  J.  Kandel. Amsterdam:  Wardi  Beckman  /  Friedrich  Ebert  Stiftung. Curtice,  John.  2007.  “Elections  and  Public  Opinion.”  Blair’s  Britain,  1997-2007,  ed. Anthony  Seldon,  35-53.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. Cuttitta,  Paolo.  2008.  “Yearly  Quotas  and  Country-Reserved  Shares  in  Italian  Immi¬ gration  Policy.”  Migration  Letters  5,  no.  1  (April),  41-51. Dadush,  Uri,  et  al.  2010.  Paradigm  Lost:  The  Euro  in  Crisis.  Washington:  Carnegie Endowment  for  International  Peace. Daguerre,  Anne.  2006.  “Childcare  Policies  in  Diverse  European  Welfare  States: Switzerland,  Sweden,  France  and  Britain.”  The  Politics  of  Post-industrial  Welfare Society,  ed.  Klaus  Armingeon  and  Giuliano  Bonoli,  211-26.  New  York:  Routledge. Dahrendorf,  Ralf.  1990.  Reflections  on  the  Revolution  in  Europe.  London:  Chatto. Daly,  Mary,  and  Martin  Seeleib-Kaiser.  2008.  “Emerging  Family  Policy  Models  in Germany  and  the  UK.”  Paper  presented  at  the  Conference  of  Europeanists,  Chi¬ cago,  March. Datculescu,  Petru.  1994.  “Cum  a  votat  Romania:  O  analiza  a  alegerilor  generale  si prezidentiale  de  la  27  Septembrie  1992.”  Revista  de  Cercetari  Sociale  1,  43-61. Dauderstadt,  Michael,  and  Andre  W.  M.  Gerrits.  2000.  “Democratisation  after  Com¬ munism:  Progress,  Problems,  Promotion.”  Internationale  Politik  und  Gesellschaft Online  /  International  Politics  and  Society,  no.  4,  361-76,  http:/ywww.fes.de/ipg/ ipg4_2ooo/daudiopti2.htm. 370  Bibliography Dauderstadt,  Michael,  Andre  W.  M.  Gerrits,  and  Gyorgy  G.  Markus.  1999.  How  Social Democrats,  after  the  Collapse  of  Communism,  Face  the  Task  of  Constructing  Capital¬ ism.  Bonn:  Friedrich  Ebert  Stiftung. Daune-Richard,  Anne-Marie,  and  Rianne  Mahon.  2001.  “Sweden:  Models  in  Crisis.” Who  Cares?  Women’s  Work,  Childcare,  and  Welfare  State  Redesign,  ed.  Jane  Jenson and  Mariette  Sineau,  146-76.  Toronto:  University  of  Toronto  Press. David,  Roman.  2003.  “Lustration  Laws  in  Action:  The  Motives  and  Evaluation  of Lustration  Policies  in  the  Czech  Republic  and  Poland.”  Law  and  Social  Inquiry  28, no.  2  (April),  387-439- Davidson,  Carl,  Steven  J.  Matusz,  and  Douglas  R.  Nelson.  2007.  “Can  Compensation Save  Free  Trade?”  Journal  of  International  Economics  71,  no.  1  (March),  167-86. Day,  Jennifer  Cheeseman,  and  Kurt  J.  Bauman.  2000.  “Have  We  Reached  the  Top? Educational  Attainment  Projections  of  the  U.S.  Population.”  U.S.  Bureau  of  the Census,  Population  Division,  Working  Paper  43. De  Grand,  Alexander.  1989.  The  Italian  Left  in  the  Twentieth  Century.  Indianapolis: Indiana  University  Press. de  la  Porte,  Caroline.  2008.  “The  European  Level  Development  and  National  Level  In¬ fluence  of  the  Open  Method  of  Coordination:  The  Cases  of  Employment  and  So¬ cial  Inclusion.”  PhD  diss.,  European  University  Institute,  Florence. Delors,  Jacques.  2004.  Memoires.  Paris:  Plon. Deloye,  Yves,  and  Michael  Bruter,  eds.  2007.  Encyclopedia  of  European  Elections. London:  Palgrave  Macmillan. Delwit,  Pascal.  2005.  “Electoral  Developments  in  European  Social  Democracy.”  Social Democracy  in  Europe,  ed.  Pascal  Delwit.  Brussels:  Editions  de  l’Universite  Libre  de Bruxelles. - .  2007.  “Les  partis  socialistes  d’Europe  du  sud:  Des  organisations  perfor- mantes?”  Pole  sud  27,  21-43. DeNavas-Walt,  Carmen,  Bernadette  D.  Proctor,  and  Jessica  Smith.  2007.  Income, Poverty,  and  Health  Insurance  Coverage  in  the  United  States:  2006.  Washington:  U.S. Government  Printing  Office. - .  2009.  Income,  Poverty,  and  Health  Insurance  Coverage  in  the  United  States: 2008.  Washington:  U.S.  Government  Printing  Office. Derthick,  Martha.  1979.  Policymaking  for  Social  Security.  Washington:  Brookings Institution. Destler,  I.  M.  2005.  American  Trade  Politics.  4th  edn.  Washington:  Institute  for  Inter¬ national  Economics. - .  2007.  “American  Trade  Politics  in  2007:  Building  Bipartisan  Compromise.” Washington:  Peterson  Institute  for  International  Economics.  Policy  Brief  PB07-5, May. De  Waele,  Jean-Michel.  1996.  “Les  partis  sociaux  democrates  a  l’est:  Sociale- democratie  ou  ‘nouvelle  gauche.’  ”  La  gauche  en  Europe  depuis  1945:  Invariants  et mutations  du  socialisme  europeen,  ed.  Marc  Lazar,  679-95.  Paris:  Presses  Universi- taires  de  France. - .  1998.  L’emergence  des  partis  politiques  en  Europe  centrale.  Brussels:  Universite de  Bruxelles. Bibliography  371 - .  2002.  Partis  politiques  et  democratic  en  Europe  centrale  et  orientale.  Brussels: Editions  de  l’Universite  de  Bruxelles.  Collection  Sociologie  Politique. Dinan,  Desmond.  2004.  Europe  Recast.  Boulder:  Lynne  Rienner. Di  Scala,  Spencer.  1996.  Italian  Socialism.  Amherst:  University  of  Massachusetts Press. - .  1998.  Italy  from  Revolution  to  Republic.  Boulder:  Westview. Dobrowolsky,  Alexandra,  and  Jane  Jenson.  2005.  “Social  Investment  Perspectives and  Practices:  A  Decade  in  British  Politics.”  Social  Policy  Review  17:  Analysis  and Debate  in  Social  Policy,  2005,  ed.  Martin  Powell,  Linda  Bauld,  and  Karen  Clarke, 203-30.  Bristol:  Policy  Press. Dolan,  Chris,  John  Frendreis,  and  Raymond  Tatalovich.  2008.  The  Presidency  and Economic  Policy.  Lanham,  Md.:  Rowman  and  Littlefield. Dplvik,  Jon-Erik.  2008.  “The  Negotiated  Nordic  Labour  Markets:  From  Bust  to Boom.”  Paper  presented  at  the  conference  “The  Nordic  Models,”  Minda  de  Gunz- burg  Center  for  European  Studies,  Harvard  University,  9-10  May. Duncan,  Fraser.  2006.  “A  Decade  of  Christian  Democratic  Decline:  The  Dilemmas  of the  CDU,  OVP  and  CDA  in  the  1990s.”  Government  and  Opposition  45,  no.  4  (Octo¬ ber),  469-90. Dunham,  Richard  S.  2006.  “Who’s  Afraid  of  Charlie  Rangel?”  Business  Week, 13  November,  37. Dyson,  Kenneth,  and  Keith  Featherstone.  1999.  The  Road  to  Maastricht.  Oxford: Oxford  University  Press. Eckes,  Alfred  E.,  Jr.  1995.  Opening  America’s  Market:  U.S.  Foreign  Trade  Policy  since 1776.  Chapel  Hill:  University  of  North  Carolina  Press. Eichengreen,  Barry.  2007.  The  European  Economy  since  1945:  Coordinated  Capitalism and  Beyond.  Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press. Einhorn,  Eric,  and  John  Logue.  2010.  “Can  Welfare  States  Be  Sustained  in  a  Global Economy?  Lessons  from  Scandinavia.”  Political  Science  Quarterly  125,  no.  1 (spring),  1-29. Eiro  Online.  2006.  “Spain:  Role  of  Immigrant  Women  in  the  Domestic  Services  Sec¬ tor.”  27  June. - .  2007.  “Employment  and  Working  Conditions  of  Migrant  Workers:  Italy.” 31  May. Eley,  Geoff.  2002.  Forging  Democracy:  The  History  of  the  Left  in  Europe,  1850-2000. New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. Engels,  Friedrich.  1962.  Anti-Diihring.  Moscow:  International  Publishers. Esping-Andersen,  Gpsta.  1985.  Politics  against  Markets:  The  Social  Democratic  Road  to Power.  Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press. - .  1990.  The  Three  Worlds  of  Welfare  Capitalism.  Cambridge:  Polity. Esping-Andersen,  Gpsta,  Duncan  Gallie,  Anton  Hemerijk,  and  John  Myers.  2002. Why  We  Need  a  New  Welfare  State.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. Estevez-Abe,  Margarita,  Torben  Iversen,  and  David  Soskice.  2001.  “Social  Protection and  the  Formation  of  Skills.”  Varieties  of  Capitalism,  ed.  Peter  Hall  and  David Soskice,  145-83.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Ette,  Andreas.  2003.  “Germany’s  Immigration  Policy,  2000-2002:  Understanding 372  Bibliography Policy  Change  with  a  Political  Process  Approach.”  Bremen:  Center  on  Migration, Citizenship  and  Development  (COMCAD).  Working  Paper  3/2003. European  Commission.  2008.  Communication  from  the  Commission,  the  Social  Agenda and  European  Commission:  A  Consultation  Paper  from  the  Bureau  of  European  Policy Advisers,  Europe’s  Social  Reality.  Brussels:  Comm.  33  Final. Fairclough,  Norman.  2000.  New  Labour,  New  Language.  London.  Routledge. Favier,  Pierre,  and  Michel  Martin-Roland.  1990.  La  decennie  Mitterrand  1:  les  ruptures. Paris:  Le  Seuil. Favretto,  Ilaria.  2006.  “Resisting  the  ‘Pervasiveness  of  Capitalist  Ideals’?  The  Italian Left  and  the  Challenge  of  Affluent  Society  since  1945.”  Transitions  in  Social  Democ¬ racy:  Cultural  and  Ideological  Problems  of  the  Golden  Age,  ed.  J.  Callaghan  and I.  Favretto.  Manchester:  Manchester  University  Press. Fay,  Stephen,  and  Hugo  Young.  1978.  The  Day  the  £  Nearly  Died.  London:  Sunday Times  Publications. Featherstone,  Kevin.  1988.  Socialist  Parties  and  European  Integration:  A  Comparative History.  New  York:  St.  Martin’s. Feinstein,  Charles.  1999.  “Structural  Change  in  the  Developed  Countries  during  the Twentieth  Century.”  Oxford  Review  of  Economic  Policy  15,  no.  4  (winter),  35-55. Fellowes,  Matthew  C.,  and  Patrick  J.  Wolf.  2004.  “Funding  Mechanisms  and Policy  Instruments:  How  Business  Campaign  Contributions  Influence  Congres¬ sional  Votes.”  Political  Research  Quarterly  57,  no.  2  (June),  315-24. Ferrera,  Maurizio,  Anton  Hemerijk,  and  Martin  Rhodes,  eds.  2006.  The  Future  of European  Welfare  States:  Recasting  Welfare  for  a  New  Century.  New  York:  Oxford University  Press. Fitzmaurice,  John.  1999.  “The  Luxembourg  Socialist  Workers’  Party.”  Social  Demo¬ cratic  Parties  in  the  European  Union,  ed.  R.  Ladrech  and  P.  Marliere.  Hampshire: Macmillan. Fletcher,  Roger,  ed.  1987.  Bernstein  to  Brandt:  A  Short  History  of  German  Social Democracy.  London:  Edward  Arnold. Fligstein,  Neil.  2008.  European  Clash.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Fondation  Robert  Schuman.  2008.  L’opinion  europeerme  en  2008.  Paris:  Lignes  et Reperes. Forgette,  Richard  G.  2004.  Congress,  Parties,  and  Puzzles.  New  York:  Peter  Lang. Fourastie,  Jean.  1979.  Trente  glorieuses.  Paris:  Fayard. Francia,  Peter.  2005.  “Protecting  America’s  Workers  in  Hostile  Territory:  Unions  and the  Republican  Congress.”  The  Interest  Group  Connection:  Electioneering,  Lobbying, and  Policymaking  in  Washington,  2nd  edn,  ed.  Paul  S.  Herrnson,  Ronald  G.  Shaiko, and  Clyde  Wilcox,  212-28.  Washington:  CQ  Press. Frank,  Robert  H.  2008.  “Why  Wait  to  Repeal  Tax  Cuts  for  the  Rich?”  New  York  Times, 7  December. Franklin,  Mark.  2006.  “European  Elections  and  the  European  Voter.”  European Union:  Power  and  Policy-Making,  3rd  edn,  ed.  Jeremy  Richardson.  London:  Rout- ledge. Freedman,  Lawrence.  2005.  “The  Age  of  Liberal  Wars.”  Review  of  International Studies  31,  93-107. Bibliography  373 Freeman,  Richard  B.  2003.  “What  Do  Unions  Do. ...  to  Voting?”  NBER  Working Paper  9992. Freeman,  Richard,  Birgitta  Swedenborg,  and  Robert  Topel,  eds.  2006.  NBER  rap- porten  II:  Att  reformera  valfardsstaten.  Stockholm:  SNS. Frey,  William  H.  2008.  “Race,  Immigration  and  America’s  Changing  Electorate.” Paper  presented  at  Brookings-American  Enterprise  Institute  conference  “The Future  of  Red,  Blue  and  Purple  America,”  Washington,  28  February. - .  2009.  “How  Did  Race  Affect  the  2008  Presidential  Election?”  University  of Michigan,  Population  Studies  Research  Center,  September. Friedman,  Benjamin.  2004.  The  Moral  Consequences  of  Economic  Growth.  New  York: Vintage. Friedman,  Thomas.  1999.  The  Lexus  and  the  Olive  Tree:  Understanding  Globalization. New  York:  Farrar,  Straus  and  Giroux. Gaffney,  John,  ed.  1996.  Political  Parties  and  The  European  Union.  London:  Routledge. Gallagher,  Tom.  2003.  “The  Balkans  since  1989:  The  Winding  Retreat  from  National Communism.”  Developments  in  Central  and  East  European  Politics,  ed.  Stephen White,  Judy  Batt,  and  Paul  G.  Lewis,  74-91.  New  York:  Palgrave  Macmillan. Galston,  William,  and  Elaine  Kamarck.  1989.  “The  Politics  of  Evasion.”  Washington: Progressive  Policy  Institute. Ganev,  Venelin  I.  2001.  “Postcommunism  as  a  Historical  Episode  of  a  State-Building: A  Reversed  Tillyan  Perspective.”  Paper  presented  at  the  12th  International  Con¬ ference  of  Europeanists,  Chicago.  Working  Paper  289,  http://kellogg.nd.edu/ publications/workingpapers/WPS/289.pdf. - .  2005.  “Where  Has  Marxism  Gone?  Gauging  the  Impact  of  Alternative  Ideas in  Transition  Bulgaria.”  East  European  Politics  and  Societies  19,  no.  3  (summer), 443-62. Garrett,  Geoffrey.  1998.  Partisan  Politics  in  the  Global  Economy.  Cambridge:  Cam¬ bridge  University  Press. Gerring,  John.  1998.  Party  Ideologies  in  America,  1828-1996.  New  York:  Cambridge University  Press. Giddens,  Anthony.  1998.  The  Third  Way:  The  Renewal  of  Social  Democracy.  Oxford: Friedrich  Ebert  Stiftung. - .  2000.  The  Third  Way  and  Its  Critics.  Cambridge:  Polity. - .  2007.  Europe  in  the  Global  Age.  Cambridge:  Polity. - ,  ed.  2001.  The  Global  Third  Way  Debate.  Cambridge:  Polity. Giddens,  Anthony,  Patrick  Diamond,  and  Roger  Liddle,  eds.  2006.  Global  Europe, Social  Europe.  Oxford:  Polity. Gilens,  Martin.  1999.  Why  Americans  Hate  Welfare:  Race,  Media,  and  the  Politics  of Antipoverty  Policy.  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press. Gill,  Stephen.  1995.  “Globalisation,  Market  Civilisation  and  Disciplinary  Neoliberal¬ ism.”  Millennium  24,  no.  3,  399-423. Glatzer,  Miguel,  and  Dietrich  Rueschemeyer,  eds.  2005.  Globalization  and  the  Future of  the  Welfare  State.  Pittsburgh:  University  of  Pittsburgh  Press. Glyn,  Andrew,  ed.  2001.  Social  Democracy  in  Neoliberal  Times:  The  Left  and  Economic Policy  since  1980.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. 374  Bibliography - .  2006.  Capitalism  Unleashed:  Finance,  Globalization,  and  Welfare.  Oxford: Oxford  University  Press. Gombert,  Sylvain.  2008.  “Basically  Unaffected?  Revising  the  Domestic  Party  Politics of  European  Integration  through  Political  Sociology.”  Unpublished  paper  for ECPR,  Rennes. Gorski,  Philip,  and  Andrei  Markovits.  1993.  The  German  Left:  Red,  Green,  and  Beyond. New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. Gottfried,  Heidi,  and  Jacqueline  O’Reilly.  2002.  “Reregulating  Breadwinner  Models in  Socially  Conservative  Systems:  Comparing  Germany  and  Japan.”  Social  Politics: International  Studies  in  Gender,  State  and  Society  9,  no.  1  (spring),  29-59. Gouldner,  Alvin.  1980.  The  Two  Marxisms.  New  York:  Seabury. Graetz,  Michael  J.,  and  Jerry  L.  Mashaw.  1999.  True  Security:  Rethinking  American Social  Insurance.  New  Haven:  Yale  University  Press. Graham,  Bruce.  1994.  Choice  and  Democratic  Order:  The  French  Socialist  Party,  1937- 1950.  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press. Graham,  Carol.  1998.  Private  Markets  for  Public  Goods:  Raising  the  Stakes  in  Economic Reform.  Washington:  Brookings  Institution. Graham,  Otis  L.,  Jr.  1992.  Losing  Time:  The  Industrial  Policy  Debate.  Cambridge:  Har¬ vard  University  Press. Grayson,  George  W.  1995.  The  North  American  Free  Trade  Agreement:  Regional  Com¬ munity  and  the  New  World  Order.  Lanham,  Md.:  University  Press  of  North  America. Greenberg  Quinlan  Rosner  Research.  2007.  “A  New  America:  Unmarrieds  Drive Political  and  Social  Change.” Green-Pedersen,  Christoffer,  Kees  van  Kersbergen,  and  Anton  Hemerijk.  2001.  “Neo- liberalism,  the  ‘Third  Way’  or  What?  Recent  Social  Democratic  Welfare  Policies  in Denmark  and  the  Netherlands.”  Journal  of  European  Public  Policy  8,  no.  2  (April), 307-25- Grunberg,  Gerard,  and  Gerassimos  Moschonas.  2005.  “Le  vote  socialiste:  Les  bene¬ fices  du  vote-sanction  dans  une  election  de  ‘second’  ordre.”  Le  vote  europeen, 2004-2005:  De  I’elargissement  au  referendum  frangais,  ed.  P.  Perrineau.  Paris: Presses  de  Sciences  Po. Grzymala-Busse,  Anna  Maria.  2002.  Redeeming  the  Communist  Past:  The  Regeneration  of Communist  Parties  in  East  Central  Europe.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. - .  2003.  “Political  Competition  and  the  Politicization  of  the  State  in  East  Cen¬ tral  Europe.”  Comparative  Political  Studies  36,  no.  10  (December),  1123-47. Grzymala-Busse,  Anna  Maria,  and  Pauline  Jones  Loung.  2002.  “Reconceptualizing the  State:  Lessons  from  Postcommunism.”  Politics  and  Society  30,  no.  4  (Decem¬ ber),  529-54. Hacker,  Jacob  S.  2002.  The  Divided  Welfare  State:  The  Battle  over  Public  and  Private Social  Benefits  in  the  United  States.  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press. - .  2004.  “Privatizing  Risk  without  Privatizing  the  Welfare  State:  The  Hidden Politics  of  Social  Policy  Retrenchment  in  the  United  States.”  American  Political Science  Review  98,  no.  2  (May),  243-60. - .  2005.  “Bringing  the  Welfare  State  Back  In:  The  Promises  (and  Perils)  of  the Bibliography  375 New  Social  Welfare  History.”  New  Directions  in  Policy  History,  ed.  Julian  Zelizer. University  Park:  Pennsylvania  State  University  Press. Hale,  Jon  F.  1995.  “The  Making  of  the  New  Democrats.”  Political  Science  Quarterly 110,  no.  2,  207-32. Hall,  Peter.  1987.  “The  Evolution  of  Economic  Policy  under  Mitterrand.”  The  Mitter¬ rand  Experiment,  ed.  George  Ross,  Stanley  Hoffmann,  and  Sylvia  Malzacher.  Cam¬ bridge:  Polity. - ,  ed.  1989.  The  Political  Power  of  Economic  Ideas:  Keynesianism  across  Nations. Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press. Hall,  Peter,  and  David  Soskice.  2001.  “An  Introduction  to  Varieties  of  Capitalism.” Varieties  of  Capitalism:  The  Institutional  Foundations  of  Comparative  Advantage, 1-70.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. - ,  eds.  2001.  Varieties  of  Capitalism:  The  Institutional  Foundations  of  Com¬ parative  Advantage.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Hallerod,  Bjorn.  2007.  Sweden:  Tackling  Child  Poverty  and  Promoting  the  Social  Inclu¬ sion  of  Children.  Brussels:  DG  Employment,  Social  Affairs  and  Equal  Opportunities, www.peer-review-social-inclusion.net. Halperin,  William.  1946.  “Leon  Blum  and  Contemporary  French  Socialism.”  Journal of  Modem  History  18,  no.  3  (September),  241-50. Hammar,  Tomas.  1999.  “Closing  the  Doors  of  the  Swedish  Welfare  State.”  Mechanisms of  Immigration  Control:  A  Comparative  Analysis  of  European  Regulation  Policies,  ed. Grete  Brochmann  and  Tomas  Hammar.  Oxford:  Berg. Handl,  Vladimir.  2003.  ‘“Hard  Left’  and  ‘Soft  Left’  Antagonism?  The  Transformation of  the  Communist  Party  of  Bohemia  and  Moravia  and  Its  Relations  to  the  Social Democrats.”  Paper  presented  at  the  4th  European  Conference  of  the  Rosa  Luxem¬ burg  Foundation,  Warsaw. - .  2005.  “Choosing  between  China  and  Europe?  Virtual  Inspiration  and  Policy Transfer  in  the  Programmatic  Development  of  the  Czech  Communist  Party.”  Jour¬ nal  of  Communist  Studies  and  Transition  Politics  21,  no.  1  (March),  123-41. Handl,  Vladimir,  and  Vladimir  Leska.  2005.  “Between  Emulation  and  Adjustment: External  Influences  on  Programmatic  Change  in  the  Slovak  SDL.”  Journal  of  Com¬ munist  Studies  and  Transition  Politics  21,  no.  1  (March),  105-22. Hansen,  Randall.  1999.  “The  Politics  of  Citizenship  in  1940s  Britain:  The  British Nationality  Act.”  20th  Century  British  History  10,  no.  1,  67-95. Hanson,  Brian  T.  1998.  “What  Happened  to  Fortress  Europe?  External  Trade  Policy  in the  European  Union.”  International  Organization  52,  no.  1  (January),  55-85. Hansson,  Per  Albin.  1982  (1928].  “Speech  in  the  Reichstag.”  Fran  fram  tillfolkhem- met:  Per  Albin  Hansson  som  tidningsman  och  talare,  ed.  Anna  Lisa  Berkling.  Stock¬ holm:  Metodica. Harmel,  Robert,  and  Kenneth  Janda.  1994.  “An  Integrated  Theory  of  Party  Goals  and Party  Change.”  Journal  of  Theoretical  Politics  6,  no.  3  (July),  259-87. Hasnat,  Baban,  and  Charles  Callahan  III.  2002.  “A  Political  Economic  Analysis  of Congressional  Voting  on  Permanent  Normal  Trade  Relations  of  China.”  Applied Economics  Letters  9,  no.  7  (June),  465-68. 376  Bibliography Haughton,  Tim.  2005.  Constraints  and  Opportunities  of  Leadership  in  Post- communist Europe.  Burlington,  Vt.:  Ashgate. Haupt,  Andrea  B.  2010.  “Parties’  Responses  to  Economic  Globalization.”  Party  Politics 16,  no.  1  (January),  5-27. Hausermann,  Silja.  2010.  The  Politics  of  Welfare  State  Reform  in  Continental  Europe. New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press. Hay,  Colin.  1997.  “Anticipating  Accommodations,  Accommodating  Anticipations:  The Appeasement  of  Capital  in  the  ‘Modernization’  of  the  British  Labour  Party,  1987- 1992.”  Politics  and  Society  25,  no.  2  (June),  234-56. Hays,  Jude  C.  2009.  Globalization,  Domestic  Institutions,  and  the  New  Politics  of  Em¬ bedded  Liberalism.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. Hays,  Jude  C.,  Sean  D.  Ehrlich,  and  Clinton  Peinhardt.  2005.  “Government  Spending and  Public  Support  for  Trade  in  the  OECD:  An  Empirical  Test  of  the  Embedded Liberalism  Thesis.”  International  Organization  59,  no.  2  (April),  473-94. Heisenberg,  Dorothee.  1999.  The  Mark  of  the  Bundesbank:  Germany’s  Role  in  Euro¬ pean  Monetary  Cooperation.  Boulder:  Lynne  Rienner. Heilman,  Stephen.  2008.  “Italy.”  European  Politics  in  Transition,  6th  edn,  ed.  Mark Kesselman  and  Joel  Krieger.  Boston:  Houghton  Mifflin. Henjak,  Andrija.  2003.  “New  Social  Divisions  and  Party  System  Developments.” Paper  presented  at  the  ECPR  Joint  Sessions  Workshop  “Cleavage  Development: Causes  and  Consequences,”  Edinburgh. Henrekson,  Magnus,  and  Ulf  Jakobsson.  2005.  “The  Swedish  Model  of  Corporate Ownership  and  Control  in  Transition.”  Who  Will  Own  Europe?,  ed.  Harry  Huizinga and  Lars  Jonung.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. Henry  J.  Kaiser  Family  Foundation.  2008.  “The  Medicare  Prescription  Drug  Benefit,” http:  //www.  kff.  org/medicare /upload /7044_o8  .pdf. - .  2010.  “Summary  of  New  Health  Reform  Law,”  http://www.kff.org/health reform/upload/8o6t.pdf. Hermet,  Guy,  and  Lili  Marcou.  1998.  Des  partis  comme  les  autres?  Les  anciens  commu- nistes  en  Europe  de  Vest.  Brussels:  Editions  Complexes. Herszenhorn,  David  M.  2010.  “Fine-Tuning  Led  to  Health  Bill’s  $940  Billion  Price Tag.”  New  York  Times,  18  March,  §  A,  16. Hibbs,  Douglas.  1993.  Solidarity  or  Egoism?  Aarhus:  Aarhus  University  Press. Hicks,  Alexander.  2000.  Social  Democracy  and  Welfare  Capitalism:  A  Century  of  In¬ come  Security  Politics.  Ithaca:  Cornell  University  Press. Hinnfors,  Jonas.  2006.  Reinterpreting  Social  Democracy.  Manchester:  Manchester University  Press. Hirschman,  Alfred  0. 1981.  Essays  in  Trespassing:  Economics  to  Politics  and  Beyond. Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. Hix,  Simon.  2007.  What’s  Wrong  with  the  European  Union  and  How  to  Fix  It.  Cam¬ bridge:  Polity. H.M.  Treasury.  1999.  Tackling  Poverty  and  Extending  Opportunity.  The  Modernisation of  Britain’s  Tax  and  Benefit  System,  vol.  4.  London:  H.M.  Treasury. - .  2001.  Tackling  Child  Poverty:  Giving  Every  Child  the  Best  Possible  Start  in  Life: A  Pre-Budget  Document.  London:  H.M.  Treasury. Bibliography  3  77 Hobsbawm,  Eric.  1978.  “The  Forward  March  of  Labour  Halted?”  Marxism  Today, September. - .  1981.  “The  Forward  March  of  Labour  Halted?”  The  Forward  March  of  Labour Halted,  ed.  Martin  Jacques  and  Francis  Mulhern,  1-18.  London:  Verso. Hollifield,  James  F.  1999.  “Ideas,  Institutions,  and  Civil  Society:  On  the  Limits  of Immigration  Control  in  France.”  Beitrage  [Institut  far  Migrationsforschung  und interkulturelle  Studien]  10  (January),  57-90. Home  Office.  1998.  “Fairer,  Faster  and  Firmer:  A  Modern  Approach  to  Immigration and  Asylum.”  Presented  to  Parliament  by  the  Secretary  of  State  for  the  Home Department  by  Command  of  Her  Majesty,  July  1998.  London:  Stationery  Office. - .  2002.  “Secure  Borders,  Safe  Haven:  Integration  with  Diversity  in  Modern Britain.”  Presented  to  Parliament  by  the  Secretary  of  State  for  the  Home  Depart¬ ment  by  Command  of  Her  Majesty,  February  2002.  London:  Stationery  Office. Horn,  Gerd-Rainer.  2007.  The  Spirit  of  ’68:  Rebellion  in  Western  Europe  and  North America,  1956-1976.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Hough,  Dan.  2005.  “Learning  from  the  West:  Policy  Transfer  and  Programmatic Change  in  Communist  Successor  Parties  of  Eastern  and  Central  Europe.”  Journal  of Communist  Studies  and  Transition  Politics  21,  no.  1  (March),  1-15. Howard,  Christopher.  1997.  The  Hidden  Welfare  State:  Tax  Expenditures  and  Social Policy  in  the  United  States.  Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press. - .  2007a.  The  Welfare  State  Nobody  Knows:  Debunking  Myths  about  U.S.  Social Policy.  Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press. - .  2007b.  “The  Haves  and  the  Have-Lots.”  Democracy:  A  Journal  of  Ideas  4 (spring),  48-58. Howell,  Chris.  2004.  “Is  There  a  Third  Way  for  Industrial  Relations?”  British  Journal of  Industrial  Relations  42,  no.  1  (March),  1-22. Howell,  Chris,  and  Rebecca  Kolins  Givan.  2009.  “Rethinking  Institutional  Change  in European  Industrial  Relations.”  British  Journal  of  Industrial  Relations,  forthcoming. Huber,  Evelyne,  and  John  D.  Stephens.  2001.  Development  and  Crisis  of  the  Welfare State:  Parties  and  Policies  in  Global  Markets.  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press. Hudson,  John,  and  Stefan  Kuhner.  2009.  “Towards  Productive  Welfare:  A  Compara¬ tive  Analysis  of  23  OECD  Countries.”  Journal  of  European  Social  Policy  19,  no.  1 (February),  34-46. Hughes,  Kent  H.  2005.  Building  the  Next  American  Century:  The  Past  and  Future  of American  Economic  Competitiveness.  Baltimore:  Johns  Hopkins  University  Press. Hughes,  Stuart.  1977.  Consciousness  and  Society:  The  Reorientation  of  European  Social Thought,  1890-1930.  New  York:  Vintage. Human  Rights  Watch.  1994.  “Germany.”  Human  Rights  Watch  World  Report,  1994. New  Haven:  Yale  University  Press. Huo,  Jingjing.  2009.  Third  Way  Reforms:  Social  Democracy  after  the  Golden  Age.  New York:  Cambridge  University  Press. Huster,  Ernst-Ulrich,  Benjamin  Benz,  and  Jurgen  Boeckh.  2007.  Germany:  Tackling Child  Poverty  and  Promoting  the  Social  Inclusion  of  Children.  Brussels:  DG  Employ¬ ment,  Social  Affairs  and  Equal  Opportunities,  www.peer-review-social-inclusion .net. 378  Bibliography Hutton,  Will.  1995.  The  State  We’re  In.  London:  Cape. - .  1997.  Stakeholding  and  Its  Critics.  London:  Institute  of  Economic  Affairs. Inglehart,  Ronald.  1971.  “The  Silent  Revolution.”  American  Political  Science  Review  65, no.  4  (December),  991-1017. - .  1977.  The  Silent  Revolution:  Changing  Values  and  Political  Styles  among  West¬ ern  Publics.  Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press. - .  1990.  Culture  Shifts  in  Advanced  Industrial  Society.  Princeton:  Princeton University  Press. Ishiyama,  John  T.  1998.  “Strange  Bedfellows:  Explaining  Political  Cooperation  be¬ tween  Communist  Successor  Parties  and  Nationalists  in  Eastern  Europe.”  Nations and  Nationalism  4,  no.  1  (January),  61-85. Iversen,  Torben.  2005.  Capitalism,  Democracy,  and  Welfare.  New  York:  Cambridge University  Press. - .  2009.  “Dualism  and  Political  Coalitions.”  Paper  presented  at  the  annual meeting  of  the  American  Political  Science  Association,  Toronto,  3-6  September. Iversen,  Torben,  and  Thomas  R.  Cusack.  2000.  “The  Causes  of  Welfare  State  Expan¬ sion:  Deindustrialization  or  Globalization?”  World  Politics  52,  no.  3  (April),  313-49. Iversen,  Torben,  and  John  Stephens.  2008.  “Partisan  Politics,  the  Welfare  State  and Three  Worlds  of  Human  Capital  Formation.”  Comparative  Political  Studies  41,  nos. 4-5  (April),  600-637. Iversen,  Torben,  and  Anne  Wren.  1998.  “Equality,  Employment,  and  Budgetary  Re¬ straint.”  World  Politics  50,  no.  4  (July),  507-46. Jacobs,  Lawrence  R.,  and  Theda  Skocpol,  eds.  2005.  Inequality  and  American  Democ¬ racy:  What  We  Know  and  What  We  Need  to  Learn.  New  York:  Russell  Sage  Founda¬ tion. Jacobs,  Michael.  2002.  “Reason  to  Believe.”  Prospect,  October. Jacques,  Martin,  and  Francis  Mulhern,  eds.  1981.  The  Forward  March  of  Labour Halted.  London:  Verso. Jandl,  Michael.  2008.  “Methodologies  for  the  Estimation  of  Stocks  of  Irregular  Mi¬ grants.”  Paper  presented  at  the  joint  unece/eurstat/unfpa/medstat  ii  Work Session  on  Migration  Statistics,  Geneva,  3-5  March. Jensen,  Carsten.  2011.  “Conditional  Contraction:  Globalisation  and  Capitalist  Sys¬ tems.”  European  Journal  of  Political  Research  50,  no.  2  (March),  168-89. Jenson,  Jane.  2004.  Canada’s  New  Social  Risks:  Directions  for  a  New  Social  Architec¬ ture.  Ottawa:  CPRN.  Report  F43,  www.cprn.org. Jenson,  Jane,  and  Stephane  Jacobzone.  2000.  Care  Allowances  for  the  Frail  Elderly and  Their  Impact  on  Women  Care-Givers.  Paris:  OECD.  OECD  Labour  Market  and Social  Policy  Occasional  Papers  41. Jenson,  Jane,  and  Denis  Saint-Martin.  2006.  “Building  Blocks  for  a  New  Social  Archi¬ tecture:  The  LEGO™  Paradigm  of  an  Active  Society.”  Policy  and  Politics  34,  no.  3 (July),  429-51- Jeong,  Guyung-Ho.  2009.  “Constituent  Influence  on  International  Trade  Policy  in  the United  States,  1987-2006.”  International  Studies  Quarterly  53,  no.  2  (June), 519-40. Jessop,  Bob.  2002.  The  Future  of  the  Capitalist  State.  Cambridge:  Polity. Bibliography  379 Judis,  John  B.,  and  Ruy  Teixeira.  2002.  The  Emerging  Democratic  Majority.  New  York: Scribner. Kalyvas,  Stathis.  2003.  “Unsecular  Politics  and  Religious  Mobilization:  Beyond  Chris¬ tian  Democracy.”  European  Christian  Democracy:  Historical  Legacies  and  Compara¬ tive  Perspectives,  ed.  Thomas  Kselman  and  Joseph  A.  Buttigieg.  Notre  Dame:  Uni¬ versity  of  Notre  Dame  Press. Kamerman,  Sheila  B.,  Michelle  Neuman,  Jane  Waldfogel,  and  Jeanne  Brooks- Gunn.  2003.  Social  Policies,  Family  Types,  and  Child  Outcomes  in  Selected  OECD Countries.  Paris:  OECD.  OECD  Social,  Employment,  and  Migration  Working Papers  6. Kampfner,  John.  2004.  Blair’s  Wars.  London:  Free  Press. Kang,  Shin-Goo,  and  G.  Bingham  Powell  Jr.  2010.  “Representation  and  Policy  Re¬ sponsiveness:  The  Median  Voter,  Election  Rules,  and  Redistributive  Welfare Spending.”  Journal  of  Politics  72,  no.  4  (October),  1014-28. Kapstein,  Ethan.  1998.  “Trade  Liberalization  and  the  Politics  of  Trade  Adjustment Assistance.”  International  Labour  Review  137,  no.  4,  501-16. Karapin,  Roger.  1999.  “The  Politics  of  Immigration  Control  in  Britain  and  Germany.” Comparative  Politics  31,  no.  4,  423-44. Karasimeneov,  Georgi.  1995.  “Parliamentary  Elections  of  1994  and  the  Development of  the  Bulgarian  Party  System.”  Party  Politics  1,  no.  4  (October),  579-87. - .  2004.  Party  Systems  in  Post-communist  Europe.  Bonn:  Zentrum  fur  Euro- paische  Integrationsforschung,  Rheinische  Friedrich-Wilhelms  Universitat. Karatani,  Rieko,  and  Guy  S.  Goodwin-Gill.  2003.  Defining  British  Citizenship:  Empire, Commonwealth  and  Modem  Britain.  London:  Routledge. Katwala,  Sunder.  2008.  “Why  Europe’s  Left  Can  Rise  Again:  The  Policies  the  Center- Left  Promoted  Remain  Relevant,  but  They  Are  Now  Failing  as  Politics.”  Newsweek, 22  September. Katzenstein,  Peter.  1985.  Small  States  in  World  Markets:  Industrial  Policy  in  Europe. Ithaca:  Cornell  University  Press. Kautsky,  Karl.  1910.  The  Class  Struggle.  Chicago:  Charles  Kerr. Keech,  William  R.,  and  Kyoungsan  Pak.  1995.  “Partisanship,  Institutions,  and  Change in  American  Trade  Politics.”  Journal  of  Politics  57,  no.  4  (November),  1130-42. Keman,  Hans,  Kees  van  Kersbergen,  and  Barbara  Vis.  2006.  “Political  Parties  and New  Social  Risks:  The  Double  Backlash  against  Social  Democracy  and  Christian Democracy.”  The  Politics  of  Post-Industrial  Welfare  Society,  ed.  Klaus  Armingeon and  Giuliano  Bonoli,  27-51.  New  York:  Routledge. Kenworthy,  Lane.  2008.  Jobs  with  Equality.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Kesselman,  Mark,  and  Joel  Krieger,  eds.  2008.  European  Politics  in  Transition.  6th edn.  Boston:  Houghton  Mifflin. King,  Desmond,  and  David  Rueda.  2008.  “Cheap  Labor.”  Perspectives  on  Politics  6, no.  2  (June),  279-97. King,  Desmond,  and  Mark  Wickham-Jones.  1990.  “Review  Article:  Social  Democracy and  Rational  Workers.”  British  Journal  of  Political  Science  20,  no.  3  (July),  387-413. Kingdon,  John  W.  1999.  America  the  Unusual.  New  York:  St.  Martin’s  /  Worth. Kitschelt,  Herbert.  1992.  “The  Socialist  Discourse  and  Party  Strategy  in  West  Euro- 380  Bibliography pean  Democracies.”  The  Crisis  of  Socialism  in  Europe,  ed.  Christiane  Lemke  and Gary  Marks.  Durham:  Duke  University  Press. - .  1994.  The  Transformation  of  European  Social  Democracy.  New  York:  Cam¬ bridge  University  Press. - .  1999.  “European  Social  Democracy  between  Political  Economy  and  Electoral Competition.”  Continuity  and  Change  in  Contemporary  Capitalism,  ed.  Herbert Kitschelt  et  al.,  317-45.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. Kitschelt,  Herbert,  in  collaboration  with  Anthony  J.  McGann.  1995.  The  Radical  Right in  Western  Europe:  A  Comparative  Analysis.  Ann  Arbor:  University  of  Michigan Press. Kitschelt,  Herbert,  and  Philipp  Rehm.  2005.  “Work,  Family,  and  Politics:  Foundations of  Electoral  Partisan  Alignments  in  Postindustrial  Democracies.”  Paper  presented at  the  annual  meeting  of  the  American  Political  Science  Association,  Washington. Kjellberg,  Anders.  1983.  Facklig  organisering  i  tolv  lander.  Lund:  Arkiv. - .  2009.  “The  Swedish  Model  of  Industrial  Relations.”  Trade  Unionism  since 1945,  ed.  Craig  Phelan.  Oxford:  Peter  Lang,  forthcoming. Kopstein,  Jeffrey,  and  Sven  Steinmo,  eds.  2008.  Growing  Apart?  America  and  Europe in  the  Twenty-first  Century.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. Korpi,  Walter,  and  Joakim  Palme.  2003.  “New  Politics  and  Class  Politics  in  the  Con¬ text  of  Austerity  and  Globalization:  Welfare  State  Regress  in  18  Countries,  1975- 95.”  American  Political  Science  Review  97,  no.  3  (August),  425-46. Kotlikoff,  Laurence  J.,  and  Scott  Burns.  2004.  The  Coming  Generational  Storm:  What You  Need  to  Know  about  America’s  Economic  Future.  Cambridge:  MIT  Press. Kriesi,  Hanspeter,  et  al.  2008.  West  European  Politics  in  the  Age  of  Globalization. Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. Krugman,  Paul.  2005.  The  Great  Unraveling.  New  York:  W.  W.  Norton. Kuttner,  Robert.  2008a.  “The  Copenhagen  Consensus.”  Foreign  Affairs  87,  no.  2 (March-April),  78-84. - .  2008b.  Obama’s  Challenge:  America’s  Economic  Crisis  and  the  Power  of  a Transformative  Presidency.  White  River  Junction:  Chelsea  Green. Kuzio,  Taras.  2001.  “Transition  in  Post- Communist  States:  Triple  or  Quadruple?” Politics  21,  no.  3  (September),  168-77. Labour  Party  Manifesto.  2005.  http://image.guardian.co.uk/sys-files/Politics/ documents/2005/04/13/labourmanifesto.pdf. Laclau,  Ernesto.  2005.  On  Populist  Reason.  London:  Verso. Ladrech,  Robert.  2003.  “The  Party  of  European  Socialists:  Networking  Europe’s Social  Democrats.”  Journal  of  Policy  History  15,  no.  1, 113-29. Lamy,  Pascal.  2004.  La  democratie-monde.  Paris:  Autrement. Laqueur,  Walter.  1970.  Europe  since  Hitler.  New  York:  Penguin. Lavelle,  Ashley.  2008.  The  Death  of  Social  Democracy:  Political  Consequences  in  the  21st Century.  Aldershot:  Ashgate. LeBihan,  Blanche,  and  Claude  Martin.  2006.  “A  Comparative  Case  Study  of  Care Systems  for  Frail  Elderly  People:  Germany,  Spain,  France,  Italy,  United  Kingdom and  Sweden.”  Social  Policy  and  Administration  40,  no.  1  (February),  26-46. Lee,  Frances  E.  2009.  Beyond  Ideology:  Politics,  Principles,  and  Partisanship  in  the  U.S. Senate.  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press. Bibliography  381 Leibfried,  Stephan.  2000.  “Towards  a  European  Welfare  State?”  The  Welfare  State:  A Reader,  ed.  Christopher  Pierson  and  Francis  G.  Castles.  Cambridge:  Polity. Leonhardt,  David.  2010.  “Health  Care  Overhaul  Becomes  the  Law  of  the  Land:  In  the Process,  Pushing  Back  at  Inequality.”  New  York  Times,  24  March,  §  A,  1. Letki,  Natalia.  2002.  “Lustration  and  Democratization  in  East-Central  Europe.” Europe-Asia  Studies  54,  no.  4  (June),  529-52. Lewis,  Paul  G.  2004.  “What  Is  the  Right  Way  in  East-Central  Europe?  Concluding Remarks.”  Journal  of  Communist  Studies  and  Transition  Politics  20,  no.  3  (Septem¬ ber),  133-48. Lijphart,  Arend.  1977.  Democracy  in  Plural  Societies:  A  Comparative  Exploration.  New Haven:  Yale  University  Press. - ,  ed.  1990.  Conflict  and  Coexistence  in  Belgium:  Dynamics  of  a  Culturally  Di¬ vided  Society.  Berkeley:  University  of  California,  Institute  for  International  Studies. Linz,  Juan,  and  Alfred  Stepan.  1996.  Problems  of  Democratic  Transition  and  Consolida¬ tion:  Southern  Europe,  South  America,  and  Post-Communist  Europe.  Baltimore: Johns  Hopkins  University  Press. Lipset,  Seymour  Martin,  and  Gary  Marks.  2000.  It  Didn’t  Happen  Here:  Why  Socialism Failed  in  the  United  States.  New  York:  W.  W.  Norton. Lipset,  Seymour  M.,  and  Stein  Rokkan.  1967.  “Cleavage  Structures,  Party  Systems, and  Voter  Alignments:  An  Introduction.”  Party  Systems  and  Voter  Alignments: Cross-National  Perspectives.  London:  Free  Press. Little,  Richard,  and  Mark  Wickham-Jones,  eds.  2000.  New  Labour’s  Foreign  Policy:  A New  Moral  Crusade?  Manchester:  Manchester  University  Press. Lockhart,  Charles.  2003.  The  Roots  of  American  Exceptionalism:  Institutions,  Culture and  Policies.  New  York:  Palgrave  Macmillan. Ludlow,  Peter.  1982.  The  Making  of  the  European  Monetary  System.  Oxford:  Oxford University  Press. Lupu,  Noam,  and  Jonas  Pontusson.  2010.  “The  Structure  of  Inequality  and  the  Poli¬ tics  of  Redistribution.”  Paper  presented  at  the  annual  meeting  of  the  American Political  Science  Association,  Washington,  2-5  September. Luxembourg  Income  Study,  n.d.  “LIS  Key  Figures,”  http://www.lisproject.org/ keyfigures.htm. Lyon,  Dawn,  and  Miriam  Glucksman.  2008.  “Comparative  Configurations  of  Care Work  across  Europe.”  Sociology  42,  no.  1  (February),  101-18. Maas,  Willem.  2006.  “The  Politics  of  Immigration,  Employment  and  Amnesty  in Spain.”  Paper  presented  at  the  annual  meeting  of  the  International  Studies  Asso¬ ciation,  San  Diego,  22  March. MacArthur,  John  R.  2000.  The  Selling  of  “Free  Trade”:  NAFTA,  Washington,  and  the Subversion  of  American  Democracy.  New  York:  Hill  and  Wang. Madsen,  Per  Kongshoj.  2002.  “The  Danish  Model  of  Flexicurity.”  Labour  Market  and Social  Reforms  in  International  Perspective,  ed.  Giuliano  Bonoli  and  Hedva  Sarfati. Burlington,  Vt.:  Ashgate. Magone,  Jose.  2007.  “Conquering  Electoral  Hegemony:  A  New  Beginning  for  Portu¬ guese  Socialism?”  Pole  Sud  27, 121-43. Mahon,  Rianne.  2006.  “The  OECD  and  the  Work/Family  Reconciliation  Agenda: 382  Bibliography Competing  Frames.”  Children,  Changing  Families  and  Welfare  States,  ed.  Jane Lewis.  Cheltenham:  Edward  Elgar. Maier,  Charles.  1981.  “The  Two  Postwar  Eras.”  American  Historical  Review  86,  no.  2 (April),  327-52. Maier-Braun,  Karl-Heinz.  2006.  “Der  lange  Weg  ins  einwanderungsland  Deutsch¬ land.”  Zuwanderung  und  Integration  [Landeszentrale  der  politischen  Bildung Baden-Wiirttemberg],  vol.  4. Mair,  Peter.  2006.  “Ruling  the  Void?”  New  Left  Review  42  (November-December), 25-51. Mair,  Peter,  and  Cas  Mudde.  1998.  “The  Party  Family  and  Its  Study.”  Annual  Review  of Political  Science  1,  211-29. Mair,  Peter,  and  Ingrid  Van  Biezen.  2001.  “Party  Membership  in  Twenty  European Democracies,  1980-2000,”  Party  Politics  7,  no.  1,  5-21. Mansfield,  Edward,  and  Diana  C.  Mutz.  2009.  “Support  for  Free  Trade:  Self-Interest, Sociotropic  Politics,  and  Out-Group  Anxiety.”  International  Organization  63,  no.  3 (July),  425-57. Marglin,  Stephen,  and  Juliet  Schor.  1991.  The  Golden  Age  of  Capitalism.  New  York: Clarendon. Martin,  Andrew,  and  George  Ross,  eds.  1999.  The  Brave  New  World  of  European  Labor: European  Trade  Unions  at  the  Millennium.  New  York:  Berghahn. - ,  eds.  2004.  Euros  and  Europeans:  Monetary  Integration  and  the  European Model  Of  Society.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. Martin,  Cathie  Jo.  2004.  “Reinventing  Welfare  Regimes.”  World  Politics  57,  no.  1 (October),  39-69. Martin,  Cathie  Jo,  and  Kathleen  Thelen.  2007.  “The  State  and  Coordinated  Capital¬ ism.”  World  Politics  60,  no.  1  (October),  1-36. Mayer,  Frederick  W.  1998.  Interpreting  NAFTA:  The  Science  and  Art  of  Political  Analy¬ sis.  New  York:  Columbia  University  Press. McGowan,  Francis.  2001.  “Social  Democracy  and  the  European  Union:  Who’s  Chang¬ ing  Whom?”  Social  Democracy:  Global  and  National  Perspectives,  ed.  L.  Martell. New  York:  Palgrave. McKibbin,  Ross.  2009.  “Will  We  Notice  When  the  Tories  Have  Won?”  London  Review of  Books,  24  September,  9-10. Mehrtens,  F.  John,  III.  2004.  “Three  Worlds  of  Public  Opinion?  Values,  Variation,  and the  Effect  on  Social  Policy.”  International  Journal  of  Public  Opinion  Research  16, no.  2  (summer),  115-43. Meidner,  Rudolf.  1993.  “Why  Did  the  Swedish  Model  Fail?”  Socialist  Register,  ed. Ralph  Miliband  and  Leo  Panitch.  London:  Merlin. Mellman,  Mark,  Aaron  Strauss,  Anna  Greenberg,  Patrick  McCreesh,  and  Kenneth  D. Wald.  2006.  “The  Jewish  Vote  in  2004:  An  Analysis.”  Washington:  Solomon  Project. Merkel,  Wolfgang.  1992a.  “After  the  Golden  Age:  Is  Social  Democracy  Doomed  to Decline?”  The  Crisis  of  Socialism  in  Europe,  ed.  Christiane  Lemke  and  Gary  Marks. Durham:  Duke  University  Press. - .  1992b.  “Between  Class  and  Catch-All:  Is  There  an  Electoral  Dilemma  for Bibliography  383 Social  Democratic  Parties  in  Western  Europe?”  Socialist  Parties  in  Europe  II:  Of Class,  Populars,  Catch-all?,  ed.  Wolfgang  Merkel  et  al.  Barcelona:  ICPS. - .  1992c.  “After  the  Golden  Age:  Is  Social  Democracy  Doomed  to  Decline?” Socialist  Parties  in  Europe,  ed.  Jose  Maravall  et  al.  Barcelona:  ICPS. - .  2001.  “The  Third  Ways  of  Social  Democracy.”  Multiple  Third  Ways,  ed. Rene  Cuperus,  Karl  Duffek,  and  Johannes  Kandel.  Amsterdam:  Wiardi  Beckman. Merkel,  Wolfgang,  Alexander  Petring,  Christian  Henkes,  and  Christoph  Egle.  2008. Social  Democracy  in  Power:  The  Capacity  to  Reform.  London:  Routledge. Meyer,  Thomas,  with  Lewis  P.  Hinchman.  2007.  The  Theory  of  Social  Democracy. Oxford:  Polity. Migration  Policy  Institute.  2004.  “To  Regularize  or  Not  to  Regularize.”  Briefing  with Ferrucio  Pastore,  deputy  director  of  the  Center  for  International  Policy  Studies (CesPI),  Rome,  30  June. Miliband,  David.  2008.  “Against  the  Odds  We  Can  Still  Win,  on  a  Platform  of Change.”  Guardian,  30  July. Miliband,  Ralph.  1977.  Marxism  and  Politics.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. Millard,  Frances.  2003.  “Poland.”  Developments  in  Central  and  East  European  Politics, ed.  Stephen  White,  Judy  Batt,  and  Paul  G.  Lewis,  23-40.  New  York:  Palgrave  Mac¬ millan. Miller,  Susan,  and  Heinrich  Potthoff.  1986.  A  History  of  German  Social  Democracy. New  York:  St.  Martin’s. Mink,  Georges,  and  Jean-Charles  Szurek.  1998.  “L’ancienne  elite  communiste  en Europe  centrale:  Strategies,  resources  et  reconstructions  identitaires.”  Revue frangaise  de  science  politique  48,  no.  1,  3-41. Mishra,  Ramesh.  1984.  The  Welfare  State  in  Crisis:  Social  Thought  and  Social  Change. New  York:  St.  Martin’s. - .  1999.  Globalization  and  the  Welfare  State.  Cheltenham:  Edward  Elgar. Money,  Jeannette.  1999.  Fences  and  Neighbors:  The  Political  Geography  of  Immigration Control.  Ithaca:  Cornell  University  Press. Moravscik,  Andrew.  1998.  The  Choice  for  Europe.  Ithaca:  Cornell  University  Press. - .  2002.  “In  Defence  of  the  ‘Democratic  Deficit’:  Reassessing  Legitimacy  in  the European  Union.”  Journal  of  Common  Market  Studies  40,  no.  4  (November),  603-24. Morel,  Nathalie.  2006.  “Providing  Coverage  against  New  Social  Risks  in  Bismarckian Welfare  States:  The  Case  of  Long-Term  Care.”  The  Politics  of  Post-Industrial  Welfare Society,  ed.  Klaus  Armingeon  and  Giuliano  Bonoli,  227-47.  New  York:  Routledge. Morone,  James  A.  2005.  “Storybook  Truths  about  America.”  Studies  in  American Political  Development  19,  no.  2  (October),  216-25. Moschonas,  Gerassimos.  2002.  In  the  Name  of  Social  Democracy:  The  Great  Transfor¬ mation,  1945  to  the  present.  London:  Verso. - .  2007.  “The  Party  of  European  Socialists.”  Encyclopedia  of  European  Elections, ed.  Yves  Deloye  and  M.  Bruter.  London:  Palgrave  Macmillan. - .  2008a.  “Reformism  in  a  Conservative  System:  European  Union  and  Social- Democratic  Identity.”  In  Search  of  Social  Democracy:  Responses  to  Crisis  and  Mod¬ ernisation,  ed.  John  Callaghan  et  al.  Manchester:  Manchester  University  Press. 384  Bibliography - .  2008b.  “Socialism  and  Its  Changing  Constituencies  in  France,  Great  Britain, Sweden  and  Denmark.”  Columbia  University,  Council  for  European  Studies,  Six¬ teenth  International  Conference,  Chicago. - .  2009.  “Reformism  in  a  ‘Conservative’  System:  European  Union,  Political Parties  and  Social  Democratic  Identity.”  Socialism  and  European  Unity,  ed.  Michael Newman.  London:  Junction. Moschonas,  Gerassimos,  and  George  Papanagnou.  2007.  “Posseder  une  longueur d’avance  sur  la  droite:  Expliquer  la  duree  gouvernementale  du  PSOE  (1982-96)  et du  PASOK  (1981-2004).”  Pole  Sud  27,  43-105. Mucciaroni,  Gary.  1990.  The  Political  Failure  of  Employment  Policy,  1945-1982.  Pitts¬ burgh:  University  of  Pittsburgh  Press. Mudde,  Cas.  2004.  “The  Populist  Zeitgeist.”  Government  and  Opposition  39,  no.  4 (January),  541-63. Miinz,  Rainer.  2004.  “New  German  Law  Skirts  Comprehensive  Immigration  Reform.” Migration  Information  Source,  August. Nannestadt,  Peter.  2007.  “Immigration  and  the  Welfare  State:  A  Survey  of  15  Years  of Research.”  European  Journal  of  Political  Economy  23,  no.  2  (June),  512-32. Noel,  Alain,  and  Jean-Philippe  Therien.  2008.  Left  and  Right  in  Global  Politics.  New York:  Cambridge  University  Press. Notermans,  Ton.  2001.  “The  German  Social  Democrats  and  Monetary  Union.”  Social Democracy  and  Monetary  Union,  ed.  Ton  Notermans.  New  York:  Berghahn. - ,  ed.  2001.  Social  Democracy  and  Monetary  Union.  New  York:  Berghahn. Oberlander,  Jonathan.  2003.  The  Political  Life  of  Medicare.  Chicago:  University  of Chicago  Press. Obinger,  Herbert,  Peter  Starke,  Julia  Moser,  Claudia  Bogedan,  Edith  Obinger- Gindulis,  and  Stephan  Leibfried.  2010.  Transformations  of  the  Welfare  State:  Small States,  Big  Lessons.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. OECD  (Organization  of  Economic  Co-operation  and  Development),  n.d.  “Social Expenditure  Database,”  http:^stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?datasetcode=SOCX _AGG. - .  1985.  Social  Expenditure,  1960-1990:  Problems  of  Growth  and  Control.  Paris: OECD. - .  2000.  Literacy  in  the  Information  Age.  Paris:  OECD. - .  2004.  Employment  Outlook  2004.  Paris:  OECD. - .  2007a.  Sweden:  Achieving  Results  for  Sustained  Growth.  Paris:  OECD. - .  2007b.  OECD  Factbook  2007.  Paris:  OECD. - .  2007c.  OECD  Health  Data  2007.  Paris:  OECD. - .  2oo7d.  Economic  Survey  of  Sweden,  2007.  Paris:  OECD. - .  2007e.  International  Migration  Outlook:  Sopemi.  2007  edn.  Paris:  OECD. - .  2008a.  StatExtracts:  2008  Annual  Labour  Force  Statistics.  Paris:  OECD. - .  2008b.  Economic  Outlook  2008  84.  Paris:  OECD. - .  2008c.  Employment  Outlook  2008.  Paris:  OECD. - .  2008d.  Labour  Force  Statistics,  1987-2007.  Paris:  OECD. - .  2oo8e.  Growing  Unequal?  Income  Distribution  and  Poverty  in  OECD  Countries. Paris:  OECD. Bibliography  385 Offe,  Claus.  1983.  “Competitive  Party  Democracy  and  the  Welfare  State.”  Policy  Sci¬ ences  15,  no.  3  (April),  225-46. - .  1984.  Contradictions  of  the  Welfare  State,  ed.  John  Keane.  Cambridge:  MIT Press. - .  1996.  Varieties  of  Transition:  The  East  European  and  East  German  Experience. Cambridge:  Polity. Oh,  Jennifer.  2009.  “Challenged  to  Open:  A  Comparative  Study  of  Agricultural  Mar¬ ket  Reform  in  Japan  and  Sweden.”  PhD  diss.,  Princeton  University. Orenstein,  Mitchell.  1995.  “Transitional  Social  Policy  in  the  Czech  Republic  and Poland.”  Czech  Sociological  Review  3,  no.  2, 179-96. Palier,  Bruno.  2002.  Gouvemer  la  securite  sociale.  Paris:  Presses  Universitaires  de France. - ,  ed.  2010.  A  Long  Goodbye  to  Bismarck?  The  Politics  of  Welfare  Reform  in Continental  Europe.  Amsterdam:  Amsterdam  University  Press. Palier,  Bruno,  and  Kathleen  Thelen.  2010.  “Institutionalizing  Dualism.”  Politics  and Society  38,  no.  3  (September),  119-48. Parness,  Diane.  1991.  The  SPD  and  the  Challenge  of  Mass  Politics.  Boulder:  Westview. Paterson,  William  E.,  and  James  Sloam.  2005.  “Learning  from  the  West:  Policy  Trans¬ fer  and  Political  Parties.”  Learning  from  the  West?  Policy  Transfer  and  Programmatic Change  in  the  Communist  Successor  Parties,  ed.  Dan  Hough,  William  E.  Paterson, and  James  Sloam.  New  York:  Routledge. Paterson,  William,  and  Alastair  H.  Thomas,  eds.  1977.  Social  Democratic  Parties  in Western  Europe.  London:  Groom  Helm. Pekkarinen,  Jukka.  2001.  “Finnish  Social  Democrats  and  EMU.”  Social  Democracy  and Monetary  Union,  ed.  Ton  Notermans.  New  York:  Berghahn. Perez,  Sofia  A.  1999.  “Constraint  or  Motor?  Monetary  Integration  and  the  Construc¬ tion  of  a  Social  Model  in  Spain.”  Euros  and  Europeans:  Monetary  Integration  and the  European  Model  of  Society,  ed.  Andrew  Martin  and  George  Ross.  Cambridge: Cambridge  University  Press. Perez,  Sofia,  and  J.  Fernandez-Adbertos.  2009.  “Immigration  and  Left  Party  Govern¬ ment  in  Europe.”  Paper  presented  at  the  annual  meeting  of  the  American  Political Science  Association,  Toronto,  3-6  September. Phillips,  Kevin.  1969.  The  Emerging  Republican  Majority.  New  York:  Arlington  House. Pierson,  Christopher.  2001.  Hard  Choices:  Social  Democracy  in  the  21st  Century. Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. - .  2007.  Beyond  the  Welfare  State:  The  New  Political  Economy  of  Welfare,  3rd edn.  University  Park:  Pennsylvania  State  University  Press. Pierson,  Paul.  1994.  Dismantling  the  Welfare  State:  Reagan,  Thatcher  and  the  Politics  of Retrenchment.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. - .  1996.  “The  New  Politics  of  the  Welfare  State.”  World  Politics  48,  no.  2  (Janu¬ ary),  143-79- - .  1998.  “The  Deficit  and  the  Politics  of  Domestic  Reform.”  The  Social  Divide: Political  Parties  and  the  Future  of  Activist  Government,  ed.  Margaret  Weir,  126-80. Washington:  Brookings  Institution. - .  2002.  “Coping  with  Permanent  Austerity:  Welfare  State  Restructuring  in 386  Bibliography Affluent  Democracies.”  Revue  frangaise  de  sociologie  43,  no.  2  (April-June),  369- 406. - ,  ed.  2001.  The  New  Politics  of  the  Welfare  State.  New  York:  Oxford  University Press. Piketty,  Thomas,  and  Emmanuel  Saez.  2003.  “Income  Inequality  in  the  United  States, 1913-1998.”  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics  118,  no.  1  (February),  1-39. Pittaway,  Mark.  2003.  “Hungary.”  Developments  in  Central  and  East  European  Politics, ed.  Stephen  White,  Judy  Batt,  and  Paul  G.  Lewis,  57-73.  New  York:  Palgrave  Mac¬ millan. Piven,  Frances  Fox,  ed.  1992.  Labor  Parties  in  Postindustrial  Societies.  New  York: Oxford  University  Press. Pochet,  Philippe,  and  Jonathan  Zeitlin,  eds.  2005.  The  Open  Method  of  Coordination in  Action:  The  European  Employment  and  Social  Inclusion  Strategies.  Brussels:  Peter Lang. PollingReport.com.  2009.  “Federal  Budget,  Taxes,  Economy.”  http://www.polling report.com/budget.htm. Pontusson,  Jonas,  n.d.  “Social  Democracy,  Varieties  of  Capitalism  and  Globalization.” Unpublished  paper. - .  1992.  The  Limits  of  Social  Democracy.  Ithaca:  Cornell  University  Press. - .  1997.  “Between  Neo-liberalism  and  the  German  Model:  Swedish  Capitalism in  Transition.”  Political  Economy  of  Modem  Capitalism,  ed.  Colin  Crouch  and  Wolf¬ gang  Streeck,  55-70.  London:  Sage. - .  2005a.  Inequality  and  Prosperity:  Social  Europe  vs.  Liberal  America.  Ithaca: Cornell  University  Press. - .  2005b.  “Varieties  and  Commonalities  of  Capitalism.”  Varieties  of  Capitalism, Varieties  of  Approaches,  ed.  David  Coates,  163-88.  New  York:  Palgrave  Macmillan. - .  2006.  “Whither  Social  Europe?”  Challenge  49,  no.  6  (November-December), 35-54- Pontusson,  Jonas,  and  Peter  Swenson.  1996.  “Labor  Markets,  Production  Strategies, and  Wage-Bargaining  Institutions.”  Comparative  Political  Studies  29,  no.  2  (April), 223-50. Potrafke,  Niklas.  2009.  “Did  Globalization  Restrict  Partisan  Politics?  An  Empirical Evaluation  of  Social  Expenditures  in  a  Panel  of  OECD  Countries.”  Public  Choice 140,  nos.  1-2  (July),  105-24. Preda,  Cristian,  and  Sorina  Soare.  2008.  Regimul,  partidele  si  sistemul  politic  din Romania.  Bucharest:  Nemira. Przeworski,  Adam.  1985.  Capitalism  and  Social  Democracy.  Cambridge:  Cambridge University  Press. Przeworski,  Adam,  and  John  Sprague.  1986.  Paper  Stones:  A  History  of  Electoral Socialism.  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press. Quatremer,  Jean,  and  Thomas  Klau.  1997.  Ces  hommes  qui  ontfait  VEuro.  Paris:  Plon. Rajan,  Raghuram  G.  2010.  Fault  Lines:  How  Hidden  Fractures  Still  Threaten  the  World Economy.  Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press. Rattner,  Sidney.  1972.  The  Tariff  in  American  History.  New  York:  Van  Nostrand. Bibliography  387 Rawnsley,  Andrew.  2001.  Servants  of  the  People:  The  Inside  Story  of  New  Labour. London:  Penguin. Rentoul,  John.  2008.  “Daylight  Robbery  at  the  Library  of  Rhetoric.”  Independent, 29  March. Reynie,  Dominique.  2008.  “L’avenement  d’un  stato-scepticisme  en  Europe.”  L’opinion europeenne  en  2008,  ed.  Fondation  Robert  Schuman.  Paris:  Lignes  et  Reperes. Richards,  John.  2004.  “Clusters,  Competition  and  ‘Global  Players’  in  ICT  Markets: The  Case  of  Scandinavia.”  Building  High-Tech  Clusters,  ed.  Timothy  Bresnahan  and Alfonso  Gambardella,  160-89.  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press. Richardson,  Jeremy,  ed.  2006.  European  Union:  Power  and  Policy-making.  3rd  edn. London:  Routledge. Rieger,  Elmer,  and  Stephan  Leibfried.  2003.  Limits  to  Globalization:  Welfare  States and  the  World  Economy.  Oxford:  Polity. Romano,  Flavio.  2006.  Clinton  and  Blair:  The  Political  Economy  of  the  Third  Way.  New York:  Routledge. Room,  Graham.  2002.  “Education  and  Welfare:  Recalibrating  the  European  Debate.” Policy  Studies  23,  no.  1  (March),  37-50. Ross,  George.  1987.  “Destroyed  by  the  Dialectic:  Politics,  the  Decline  of  Marxism,  and the  New  Middle  Strata  in  France.”  Theory  and  Society  16,  no.  1  (January),  7-38. - .  1995.  Jacques  Delors  and  European  Integration.  Cambridge:  Polity. Ross,  George,  Stanley  Floffmann,  and  Sylvia  Malzacher,  eds.  1987.  The  Mitterrand Experiment.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. Rothstein,  Bo.  1992.  “Labor-Market  Institutions  and  Working-Class  Strength.”  Struc¬ turing  Politics,  ed.  Sven  Steinmo,  Kathleen  Thelen,  and  Frank  Longsteth,  33-56. New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press. Rueda,  David.  2008.  Social  Democracy  Inside  Out:  Partisanship  and  Labor  Market Policy  in  Advanced  Industrial  Democracies.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Ruggie,  John  G.  1982.  “International  Regimes,  Transactions,  and  Change:  Embedded Liberalism  in  the  Postwar  Economic  Order.”  International  Organization  36,  no.  2 (spring),  379-415- - ,  ed.  2008.  Embedded  Global  Markets:  An  Enduring  Challenge.  Aldershot:  Ash- gate. Russell,  Meg.  2005.  Building  New  Labour:  The  Politics  of  Party  Organisation.  London: Palgrave  Macmillan. Ryner,  Magnus.  1999.  “Neoliberal  Globalization  and  the  Crisis  of  Swedish  Social Democracy.”  Economic  and  Industrial  Democracy  20,  no.  1  (February),  39-79. Sainsbury,  Diane.  1990.  “Party  Strategies  and  the  Electoral  Trade-off  of  Class-Based Parties:  A  Critique  and  Application  of  the  ‘Dilemma  of  Electoral  Socialism.’” European  Journal  of  Political  Research  18,  no.  1  (January),  29-50. - ,  ed.  1999.  Gender  and  Welfare  State  Regimes.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. SAP.  1932.  Social-Demokraten  15  (September). Sartori,  Giovanni,  and  Giacamo  Sani.  1983.  “Polarization,  Fragmentation  and  Compe¬ tition  in  Western  Democracies.”  Western  European  Party  Systems,  ed.  Hans  Daadler and  Peter  Mair.  London:  Sage. 388  Bibliography Sassoon,  Donald.  1996,  2010.  One  Hundred  Years  of  Socialism:  The  West  European  Left in  the  Twentieth  Century.  London:  I.  B.  Tauris. Schain,  Martin  A.  2006.  “The  Politics  of  Immigration  in  France,  Britain  and  the United  States:  A  Transatlantic  Comparison.”  Immigration  and  the  Transformation  of Europe,  ed.  Craig  A.  Parsons  and  Timothy  M.  Smeeding,  362-92.  Cambridge: Cambridge  University  Press. Scharpf,  Fritz.  1987.  Crisis  and  Choice  in  European  Social  Democracy.  Ithaca:  Cornell University  Press. Schatz,  Joseph  J.  2008.  “Drawing  a  Fine  Line  on  Trade.”  CQ  Weekly,  8  December, 3230-38. Scheiber,  Noam.  2007.  “The  Centrists  Didn’t  Hold.”  New  York  Times,  28  July,  15. Scheve,  Kenneth  F.,  and  Matthew  J.  Slaughter.  2001.  “Labor  Market  Competition  and Individual  Preferences  over  Immigration  Policy.”  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics 83,  no.  1  (February),  133-45- - .  2006.  “Public  Opinion,  Integration,  and  the  Welfare  State.”  Globalization  and Egalitarian  Redistribution,  ed.  Pranab  Bardhan,  Samuel  Bowles,  and  Michael Wallerstein,  217-60.  Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press. - .  2007.  “A  New  Deal  for  Globalization.”  Foreign  Affairs  86,  no.  4  (July-August). Schickler,  Eric,  and  Devin  Caughey.  2010.  “Public  Opinion,  Organized  Labor,  and  the Limits  of  New  Deal  Liberalism,  1936-1945.”  Paper  presented  at  the  annual  meet¬ ing  of  the  American  Political  Science  Association,  Washington,  2-5  September. Schlesinger,  Arthur.  1986.  The  Cycles  of  American  History.  Boston:  Houghton  Mifflin. Schmidt,  Vivien.  2006.  Democracy  in  Europe:  The  EU  and  National  Polities.  Oxford: Oxford  University  Press. Schnietz,  Karen  E.,  and  Timothy  Nieman.  1999.  “Politics  Matters:  The  1997  Derail¬ ment  of  Fast-Track  Trade  Authority.”  Business  and  Politics  1,  no.  2,  233-51. Schroder,  Martin.  2008.  “Integrating  Welfare  and  Production  Typologies:  How  Re¬ finements  of  the  Variety  of  Capitalism  Approach  Call  for  a  Combination  of  Welfare Typologies.”  Journal  of  Social  Policy  38,  no.  1  (January),  19-43. Schumacher,  Kurt.  1986  [1945].  ‘“What  Do  the  Social  Democrats  Want?’  Speech Delivered  in  Kiel  on  October  27, 1945.”  A  History  of  German  Social  Democracy  from 1848  to  the  Present,  ed.  Susanne  Miller  and  Heinrich  Potthoff.  New  York:  St. Martin’s. Schwab,  Susan  C.  1994.  Trade-offs:  Negotiating  the  Omnibus  Trade  and  Competitiveness Act  of  1988.  Boston:  Harvard  Business  School  Press. Schwartz,  Joseph.  1995.  The  Permanence  of  the  Political.  Princeton:  Princeton  Univer¬ sity  Press. Seeleib-Kaiser,  Martin,  Silke  van  Dyk,  and  Martin  Roggenkamp.  2005.  “What  Do Parties  Want?  An  Analysis  of  Programmatic  Social  Policy  Aims  in  Austria,  Ger¬ many,  and  the  Netherlands.”  Bremen:  Universitat  Bremen.  ZeS-Arbeitspapier 01/2005. Seeleib-Kaiser,  Martin,  and  Timo  Fleckenstein.  2007.  “Discourse,  Learning  and  Wel¬ fare  State  Change:  The  Case  of  German  Labour  Market  Reforms.”  Social  Policy  and Administration  41,  no.  5  (October),  427-48. Bibliography  389 Seldon,  Anthony.  2007.  “Conclusion:  The  Net  Blair  Effect,  1994-2007.”  Blair’s  Britain, 1997-2007,  645-50.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. - ,  ed.  2007.  Blair’s  Britain,  1997-2007.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. Sen,  Amartya.  1992.  Inequality  Reconsidered.  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press. Shalev,  Michael.  1983.  “The  Social  Democratic  Model  and  Beyond:  Two  Generations of  Comparative  Research  on  the  Welfare  State.”  Comparative  Social  Research, vol.  6,  ed.  Richard  F.  Tomasson,  315-51.  Greenwich,  Conn.:  JAI. Shaw,  Eric.  2007.  Losing  Labour’s  Soul?  New  Labour  and  the  Blair  Government,  1997- 2007.  London:  Routledge. Sheils,  John,  and  Randall  Haught.  2004.  “The  Cost  of  Tax-Exempt  Health  Benefits  in 2004.”  Health  Affairs  web  exclusive  (25  February),  W4-106  to  W4-112. Shoch,  James.  2000.  “Contesting  Globalization:  Organized  Labor,  NAFTA,  and  the 1997  and  1998  Fast-Track  Fights.”  Politics  and  Society  28,  no.  1  (March),  119-50. - .  2001.  Trading  Blows:  Party  Competition  and  U.S.  Trade  Policy  in  a  Globalizing Era.  Chapel  Hill:  University  of  North  Carolina  Press. - .  2006.  “From  NAFTA  to  CAFTA:  Trade  Liberalization  and  Party  Politics  in  the U.S.  House  of  Representatives,  1993-2005.”  Paper  presented  at  the  annual  meet¬ ing  of  the  American  Political  Science  Association,  Philadelphia. - .  2008.  “Bringing  Public  Opinion  and  Electoral  Politics  Back  In:  Explaining the  Fate  of ‘Clintonomics’  and  Its  Contemporary  Relevance.”  Politics  and  Society 36,  no.  1  (March),  89-130. Shonfield,  Andrew.  1965.  Modem  Capitalism:  The  Changing  Balance  of  Private  and Public  Power.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Simms,  Brendan.  2002.  Unfinest  Hour.  London:  Penguin. Skidelsky,  Robert.  2009.  Keynes:  The  Return  of  the  Master.  New  York:  Public  Affairs. Skocpol,  Theda.  1996.  Boomerang:  Health  Care  Reform  and  the  Turn  against  Govern¬ ment.  New  York:  W.  W.  Norton. Smith,  Steven  S.  2007.  Party  Influence  in  Congress.  New  York:  Cambridge  University Press. Soare,  Sorina.  2004.  “La  construction  du  label  social-democrate  roumain  et  la  con¬ solidation  de  deux  poles  sociaux-democrates  a  tendance  antithetique.”  Politique  et societe  dans  la  Roumanie  contemporaine,  ed.  Alexandra  Ionescu  and  Odette  Hatto, 183-210.  Paris:  L’Harmattan. - .  2006.  “La  reconversion  sociale-democrate  des  anciens  partis  communistes  et leur  adhesion  a  l’economie  de  marche:  Le  cas  des  sociaux-democrates  roumains.” La  transition  vers  le  marche  et  la  democratic:  Europe  de  Vest,  Europe  centrale  et Afrique  du  sud,  ed.  Wladimir  Andreff,  173-90.  Paris:  La  Decouverte. Soare,  Sorina,  and  Cristian  Preda.  2008.  Regimul,  partidele  si  sistemul  politic  din Romania.  Bucharest:  Nemira. Sombart,  Werner.  1976  [1906].  Why  Is  There  No  Socialism  in  the  United  States?  Lon¬ don:  Macmillan. Soskice,  David.  1999.  “Divergent  Production  Regimes.”  Continuity  and  Change  in Contemporary  Capitalism,  ed.  Herbert  Kitschelt  et  al.,  101-34.  New  York:  Cam¬ bridge  University  Press. 390  Bibliography Sotiropoulos,  Dimitri  A.,  Ileana  Neam(u,  and  Maya  Stoyanova.  2003.  “The  Trajectory of  Post-Communist  Welfare  State  Development:  The  Cases  of  Bulgaria  and  Roma¬ nia.”  Social  Policy  and  Administration  37,  no.  6  (December),  656-73. Spiliotes,  Constantine  J.  2002.  Vicious  Cycle:  Presidential  Decision  Making  in  the American  Political  Economy.  College  Station:  Texas  A&M  Press. Spirova,  Maria  Stefanova.  2005.  “Political  Parties  in  Bulgaria:  Organizational  Trends in  Comparative  Perspectives.”  Party  Politics  11,  no.  5  (September),  601-22. Spyropoulou,  Vivian.  2008.  On  a  Tightrope?  Electoral  Dynamics  and  Governmental Stability  of  the  European  Social  Democracy,  1950-2007.  Athens:  Panteion  University of  Athens. Stan,  Lavinia.  2002.  “Moral  Cleansing  Romanian  Style.”  Problems  of  Postcommunism 49,  no.  4  (July-August),  52-62. Stanley,  Harold  W.,  and  Richard  G.  Niemi.  2008.  Vital  Statistics  on  American  Politics, 2007-2008.  Washington:  CQ  Press. Stephens,  Evelyn  Huber,  and  John  D.  Stephens.  2001.  Development  and  Crisis  in  the Welfare  State.  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press. Stephens,  John.  1986.  The  Transition  from  Capitalism  to  Socialism.  Chicago:  University of  Illinois  Press. Stephens,  John,  Evelyne  Huber,  and  Leonard  Ray.  1999.  “The  Welfare  State  in  Hard Times.”  Continuity  and  Change  in  Contemporary  Capitalism,  ed.  H.  Kitschelt  et  al. Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. Stewart,  Kitty.  2007.  “Equality  and  Social  Justice.”  Blair’s  Britain,  1997-2007,  ed. Anthony  Seldon,  408-35.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press. Stimson,  James  A.  2004.  Tides  of  Consent:  How  Public  Opinion  Shapes  American  Poli¬ tics.  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press. Stoesz,  David,  and  Howard  Jacob  Karger.  1992.  Reconstructing  the  American  Welfare State:  Pragmatic  Responses  to  the  Welfare  Crisis.  Lanham,  Md.:  Rowman  and  Little¬ field. Stoica,  Catalin  Augustin.  2004.  “From  Good  Communists  to  Even  Better  Capitalists? Entrepreneurial  Pathways  in  Post-Socialist  Romania.”  East  European  Politics  and Societies  18,  no.  2  (May),  236-77. - .  2005.  “Once  upon  a  Time  There  Was  a  Big  Party:  The  Social  Bases  of  the Romanian  Communist  Party.”  East  European  Politics  and  Societies  19,  no.  4  (Novem¬ ber),  686-71. Stratman,  Thomas.  2005.  “Some  Talk:  Money  in  Politics:  A  (Partial)  Review  of  the Literature.”  Public  Choice  124,  nos.  1-2  (July),  135-56. Straw,  Jack.  1993.  Policy  and  Ideology.  Blackburn:  Blackburn  Labour  Party. Summers,  Lawrence.  2008.  “America  Needs  to  Make  a  New  Case  for  Trade.”  Financial Times,  27  April. Sundberg,  Ian.  1999.  “The  Finnish  Social  Democratic  Party.”  Social  Democratic  Parties in  the  European  Union,  ed.  R.  Ladrech  and  P.  Marliere.  Hampshire:  Macmillan. Sundstrom,  Gerdt,  Lennarth  Johansson,  and  Linda  B.  Hassing.  2002.  “The  Shifting Balance  of  Long-Term  Care  in  Sweden.”  Gerontologist  42,  no.  3,  350-55. Suro,  Roberto,  Richard  Fry,  and  Jeffrey  Passel.  2005.  “Hispanics  and  the  2004  Elec¬ tion:  Population,  Electorate  and  Voters.”  Pew  Hispanic  Center. Bibliography  391 Svallfors,  Stefan,  and  Peter  Taylor-Gooby,  eds.  2007.  End  of  the  Welfare  State?  Re¬ sponses  to  State  Retrenchment.  New  York:  Routledge. Svensson,  Torsten.  1994.  “Socialdemokratins  Dominans.”  PhD  diss.,  Uppsala  Univer¬ sity. Swank,  Duane.  2002.  Global  Capital,  Political  Institutions,  and  Policy  Change  in  Devel¬ oped  Welfare  States.  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press. Swank,  Duane,  and  Hans-Georg  Betz.  2003.  “Globalization,  the  Welfare  State,  and Right  Wing  Populism  in  Western  Europe.”  Socio-Economic  Review  1,  no.  2  (May), 215-45- Swensson,  Peter.  2002.  Capitalists  against  Markets:  The  Making  of  Labor  Markets  and Welfare  States  in  the  United  States  and  Sweden.  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press. Szczerbiak,  Aleks.  1999.  “Testing  Party  Models  in  East-Central  Europe:  Local  Party Organisation  in  Postcommunist  Poland.”  Party  Politics  5,  no.  4  (October),  525-37. - .  2001.  “Party  Structure  and  Organisational  Development  in  Post- communist Poland.”  Journal  of  Communist  Studies  and  Transition  Politics  17,  no.  2  (June), 94-130. Taylor-Gooby,  Peter,  ed.  2004.  New  Risks,  New  Welfare:  The  Transformation  of  the European  Welfare  State.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Taylor-Gooby,  Peter,  and  Trine  Larsen.  2004.  “The  UK:  A  Test  Case  for  the  Liberal Welfare  State?”  New  Risks,  New  Welfare:  The  Transformation  of  the  European  Wel¬ fare  State,  ed.  Peter  Taylor-Gooby,  55-82.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Teitel,  Ruti  G.  2000.  Transitional  Justice.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Teixeira,  Ruy,  and  John  Halpin.  2010.  “Election  Results  Fueled  by  Jobs  Crisis  and Voter  Apathy  among  Progressives.”  Washington:  Center  for  American  Progress Action  Fund,  http: //www.americanprogressaction.org/issues/2oio/n/pdf/ election_results.pdf. Teixeira,  Ruy,  and  Joel  Rogers.  2000.  America’s  Forgotten  Majority:  Why  the  White Working  Class  Still  Matters.  New  York:  Basic  Books. Therborn,  Goran.  2007.  “After  Dialectics:  Radical  Social  Theory  in  a  Post-communist World.”  New  Left  Review  43,  63-114. Thurber,  James,  ed.  2009.  Rivals  for  Power:  Presidential-Congressional  Relations.  4th edn.  Lanham,  Md.:  Rowman  and  Littlefield. Timonen,  Virpi.  2004.  “New  Risks:  Are  They  Still  New  for  the  Nordic  Welfare  States?” New  Risks,  New  Welfare:  The  Transformation  of  the  European  Welfare  State,  ed. Peter  Taylor-Gooby,  83-110.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Tismaneanu,  Vladimir.  2000.  “Hypotheses  on  Populism:  The  Politics  of  Charismatic Protest.”  East  European  Politics  and  Societies  14,  no.  2  (March),  10-17. Toro-Morn,  Maura  I.  2004.  Migration  and  Immigration.  Westport,  Conn.:  Greenwood. Touykova,  Marta.  1997.  “La  strategic  de  survie  du  Parti  Socialiste  Bulgare.”  Etudes  du CERI  31,  http://www.ceri-sciencespo.com/publica/etude/etude31.pdf. Toynbee,  Polly,  and  David  Walker.  2010.  The  Verdict:  Did  Labour  Change  Britain? London:  Granta. Trentmann,  Frank.  2008.  Free  Trade  Nation.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Tucker,  Robert.  1970.  The  Marxian  Revolutionary  Idea.  Princeton.  Princeton  Univer¬ sity  Press. 392  Bibliography Ungerson,  Clare.  2003.  “Commodified  Care  Work  in  European  Labour  Markets.”  Euro¬ pean  Societies  5,  no.  4  (October),  377-96. Ungerson,  Clare,  and  Sue  Yeandle,  eds.  2007.  Cash  for  Care  in  Developed  Welfare States.  Houndsmill,  Basingstoke:  Palgrave  Macmillan. UNICEF.  2000.  A  League  Table  of  Child  Poverty  in  Rich  Nations.  Innocenti  Report Card  1.  Florence:  Innocenti  Research  Centre,  http://www.unicef-icdc.org. - .  2007.  Child  Poverty  in  Perspective:  An  Overview  of  Child  Well-being  in  Rich Countries.  Innocenti  Report  Card  7.  Florence:  Innocenti  Research  Centre,  http:// www. unicef-icdc.org. U.S.  Bureau  of  the  Census,  n.d.  “Historical  Poverty  Tables:  People,”  http://www .census.gov/hhes/www/poverty/histpov/perindex.html. - .  1992.  Measuring  the  Effect  of  Benefits  and  Taxes  on  Income  and  Poverty:  1979  to 1991.  Washington:  U.S.  Government  Printing  Office. - .  2001.  Poverty  in  the  United  States:  2000.  Washington:  U.S.  Government  Print¬ ing  Office. - .  2007.  The  Effect  of  Taxes  and  Transfers  on  Income  and  Poverty  in  the  United States:  2005.  Washington:  U.S.  Government  Printing  Office. U.S.  Congress,  Joint  Committee  on  Taxation.  2010.  Estimates  of  Federal  Tax  Expendi¬ tures  for  Fiscal  Years  2009-2113.  Washington:  U.S.  Government  Printing  Office. Van  Biezen,  Ingrid.  2003.  Political  Parties  in  New  Democracies.  London:  Palgrave Macmillan. Van  Biezen,  Ingrid,  and  Petr  Kopecky.  2007.  “The  State  and  the  Parties:  Public  Fund¬ ing,  Public  Regulation  and  Rent-Seeking  in  Contemporary  Democracy.”  Party Politics  13,  no.  2  (March),  235-54. Vedrine,  Hubert.  2009.  Interview  in  Le  Monde,  30  May. Veikou,  Mariangela,  and  Anna  Triandafyllidou.  2004.  “Italian  Immigration  Policy and  Its  Implementation:  A  Report  on  the  State  of  the  Art.”  Report  prepared  for  the research  project  “Does  Implementation  Matter?  Informal  Administration  Practices and  Shifting  Immigrant  Strategies  in  Four  Member  States”  funded  by  the  Euro¬ pean  Commission,  Research  DG,  contract  no.  HPSE-CT-1999-00001. Verba,  Sidney,  Kay  Lehman  Schlozman,  and  Henry  E.  Brady.  1995.  Voice  and  Equality: Civic  Voluntarism  in  American  Society.  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press. Victor,  Barbard.  1999.  Le  Matignon  de  Jospin.  Paris:  Flammarion. Vis,  Barbara.  2010.  Politics  of  Risk-taking:  Welfare  State  Reform  in  Advanced  Democra¬ cies.  Amsterdam:  Amsterdam  University  Press. Visser,  Jelle.  2006.  “Union  Membership  Statistics  in  24  Countries.”  Monthly  Labor Review  129,  no.  1  (January),  38-49. Visser,  Jelle,  and  Anton  Hemerijk.  1997.  A  Dutch  Miracle:  Job  Growth,  Welfare  Re¬ form,  and  Corporatism  in  the  Netherlands.  Amsterdam:  Amsterdam  University Press. Von  Beyme,  Klaus.  1985.  Political  Parties  in  Western  Democracies.  New  York:  St. Martin’s. Voulgaris,  Yannis.  2008.  “Les  elections  grecques  de  2007:  secousse  passagere  ou debut  d’un  seisme?”  Pole  Sud. Wade,  Robert.  2008.  “Financial  Regime  Change?”  New  Left  Review  53  (September- October),  5-21. Bibliography  393 Wall,  Stephen.  2008.  A  Stranger  in  Europe:  Britain  and  the  EU  from  Thatcher  to  Blair. Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Waller,  Michael.  1995.  “Adaptation  of  the  Former  Communist  Parties  of  East-Central Europe.”  Party  Politics  1,  no.  4  (October),  473-90. Wallerstein,  Michael,  and  Miriam  Golden.  2000.  “Postwar  Wage  Setting  in  the  Nordic Countries.”  Unions,  Employers,  and  Central  Banks:  Macroeconomic  Coordination and  Institutional  Change  in  Social  Market  Economies,  ed.  Torben  Iversen,  Jonas Pontusson,  and  David  Soskice,  107-37.  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press. Walter,  Stefanie.  2010.  “Globalization  and  the  Welfare  State:  Testing  the  Micro¬ foundations  of  the  Compensation  Hypothesis.”  International  Studies  Quarterly  54, no.  2  (June),  403-26. Walters,  William.  2004.  “Secure  Borders,  Safe  Haven,  Domopolitics.”  Citizenship Studies  8,  no.  3  (September),  237-60. Watts,  Julie.  2002.  “The  Unconventional  Immigration  Policy  Preferences  of  Labor Unions  in  Spain,  Italy,  and  France.”  San  Diego:  University  of  California,  San  Diego, Center  for  Comparative  Immigration  Studies.  Working  Paper  5. Weatherford,  M.  Stephen,  and  Lorraine  M.  McDonnell.  1996.  “Clinton  and  the  Econ¬ omy:  The  Paradox  of  Policy  Success  and  Political  Mishap.  Political  Science  Quar¬ terly  111,  no.  3  (fall),  403-36. Weaver,  R.  Kent.  2000.  Ending  Welfare  as  We  Know  It.  Washington:  Brookings  Institu¬ tion. Wickham-Jones,  Mark.  1995.  “Anticipating  Social  Democracy,  Pre-empting  Anticipa¬ tions:  Economic  Policy-Making  in  the  British  Labour  Party,  1987-1992.”  Politics and  Society  23,  no.  4  (December),  465-94. Wilensky,  Harold  L.  2002.  Rich  Democracies:  Political  Economy,  Public  Policy,  and Performance.  Berkeley:  University  of  California  Press. Wilentz,  Sean.  2008.  The  Age  of  Reagan:  A  History,  1974-2008.  New  York:  Harper Collins. Williams,  K.  2003.  “The  Czech  Republic  and  Slovakia.”  Developments  in  Central  and East  European  Politics,  ed.  Stephen  White,  Judy  Batt,  and  Paul  G.  Lewis,  41-56. New  York:  Palgrave  Macmillan. Wirls,  Daniel.  1998.  “The  Consequences  of  Equal  Representation:  The  Bicameral Politics  of  NAFTA  in  the  103rd  Congress.”  Congress  and  the  Presidency  25,  no.  2, 129-45- Wolf,  Martin.  2008.  “Keynes  Offers  Us  the  Best  Way  to  Think  about  the  Crisis.”  Finan¬ cial  Times,  24  December. Wolff,  Edward  N.  2007.  “Recent  Trends  in  Household  Wealth  in  the  United  States: Rising  Debt  and  the  Middle  Class  Squeeze.”  Annandale-on-Hudson,  N.Y.:  Levy Economics  Institute.  Working  Paper  502,  http://www.levy.org/pubs/wp.502.pdf. Wolfreys,  Jim.  2006.  “France  in  Revolt,  1995-2005.”  International  Socialism  109. Women’s  Voices,  Women  Vote.  2007.  “Unmarried  America.” Yergin,  Daniel,  and  Joseph  Stanislaw.  1998.  The  Commanding  Heights:  The  Battle  for the  World  Economy.  New  York:  Free  Press. Young,  Alasdair  R.,  and  John  Peterson.  2006.  “The  EU  and  the  New  Trade  Politics.” Journal  of  European  Public  Policy  13,  no.  6  (September),  795-814. Zaslove,  Andrej.  2007.  “Immigration  Politics  and  Policy  in  Germany  and  Italy:  The 394  Bibliography End  of  the  Hidden  Consensus.”  Paper  presented  at  the  annual  conference  of  the Political  Studies  Association,  University  of  Bath,  11-13  April. Zelizer,  Julian  E.  2003.  “The  Uneasy  Relationship:  Democracy,  Taxation,  and  State Building  Since  the  New  Deal.”  The  Democratic  Experiment:  New  Directions  in American  Political  History,  ed.  Meg  Jacobs,  William  J.  Novack,  and  Julian  E. Zelizer,  276-300.  Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press. Zielonka,  Jan.  2006.  Europe  as  Empire:  The  Nature  of  the  Enlarged  European  Union. Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press. Zysman,  John,  and  Abraham  Newman,  ed.  2006.  How  Revolutionary  Was  the  Digital Revolution?  National  Responses,  Market  Transitions,  and  Global  Technology.  Stan¬ ford:  Stanford  Business  Books. About  the  Contributors SHERI  BERMAN  is  an  associate  professor  of  political  science  at  Barnard  College, Columbia  University,  in  New  York  City.  She  is  the  author  of  The  Social  Democratic Moment:  Ideas  and  Politics  in  the  Making  of  Inter-War  Europe  (Cambridge:  Har¬ vard  University  Press,  1998)  and  The  Primacy  of  Politics:  Social  Democracy  and  the Making  of  Europe’s  Twentieth  Century  (Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press, 2006). JAMES  CRONIN  is  a  professor  of  history  at  Boston  College  and  an  affiliate  of  the Center  for  European  Studies  at  Harvard  University.  His  most  recent  book  is  New Labour’s  Pasts:  The  Labour  Party  and  Its  Discontents  (London:  Longman,  2004). Among  his  earlier  books  are  The  World  the  Cold  War  Made  (London:  Routledge, 1996)  and  The  Politics  of  State  Expansion:  War,  State  and  Society  in  Twentieth- Century  Britain  (London:  Routledge,  1991). JEAN-MICHEL  DE  WAELE  is  dean  of  the  Faculty  of  Social  and  Political  Sciences, professor  of  political  science,  and  associate  of  the  Institute  for  European  Studies  at the  Free  University  of  Brussels.  He  is  the  author  of  L’Europe  des  communistes  (with Pascal  Delwit),  Les  partis  politiques  en  Belgique  (with  Pascal  Delwit),  L’extreme droite  en  France  et  Belgique  (with  Pascal  Delwit),  and  other  books. ARTHUR  GOLDHAMMER  is  an  affiliate  of  the  Center  for  European  Studies  at  Har¬ vard.  He  has  worked  primarily  as  a  translator  specializing  in  French  history,  litera¬ ture,  philosophy,  and  social  science.  He  has  translated  more  than  a  hundred  works by  many  of  France’s  most  noted  authors,  is  on  the  editorial  board  of  the  journal French  Politics,  Culture  and  Society,  and  in  1996  was  named  Chevalier  de  l’Ordre des  Arts  et  des  Lettres  by  the  French  Minister  of  Culture.  In  1997  he  was  awarded the  Medaille  de  Vermeil  by  the  Academie  Franqaise.  He  is  currently  working  on  a book  about  democracy  after  Tocqueville,  whose  Democracy  in  America  he  trans¬ lated  in  2004  and  for  which  he  received  the  Florence  Gould  Translation  Prize. In  addition,  Goldhammer  hosts  a  blog  on  French  politics  at  artgoldhammer.blog spot.com. CHRISTOPHER  HOWARD  is  a  professor  of  government  at  the  College  of  William and  Mary.  He  is  the  author  of  The  Welfare  State  Nobody  Knows:  Debunking  Myths 396  Contributors about  U.S.  Social  Policy  (Princeton:  Princeton  University  Press,  2007)  and  The  Hid¬ den  Welfare  State:  Tax  Expenditures  and  Social  Policy  in  the  United  States  (Prince¬ ton:  Princeton  University  Press,  1997). JANE  JENSON  is  a  professor  of  political  science  at  the  University  of  Montreal, where  she  holds  the  Canada  Research  Chair  in  Citizenship  and  Governance.  Her most  recent  books  are  L’etat  des  citoyennetes  en  Europe  et  dans  les  Ameriques  (Mon¬ treal:  Presses  de  l’Universite  de  Montreal,  2007),  edited  with  B.  Marques-Perreira and  E.  Remade;  La  politique  comparee:  Vhistoire,  les  enjeux,  les  approaches  (Mon¬ treal:  Presses  de  l’Universite  de  Montreal,  2003),  written  with  Mamoudou  Gazibo; and  Who  Cares?  Women's  Work,  Child  Care  and  Welfare  State  Redesign  (Toronto: University  of  Toronto  Press,  2001),  with  Mariette  Sineau  et  al. GERASSIMOS  MOSCHONAS  is  a  professor  of  political  science  at  Pantheon  Univer¬ sity  in  Athens  and  a  visiting  professor  at  the  Institute  for  European  Studies,  Free University  of  Brussels.  He  is  the  author  of  In  the  Name  of  Social  Democracy:  The Great  Transformation  from  1945  to  the  Present  (London:  Verso,  2002). SOFIA  A.  PEREZ  is  an  associate  professor  of  political  science  at  Boston  University. She  is  the  author  of  Banking  on  Privilege:  The  Politics  of  Spanish  Financial  Reform (Ithaca:  Cornell  University  Press,  1997)  and  a  co-author  with  Michael  Loriaux et  al.  of  Capital  Ungovemed:  Liberalizing  Finance  in  Interventionist  States  (Ithaca: Cornell  University  Press,  1996).  She  is  also  the  author  of  scholarly  articles,  re¬ views,  papers,  books,  and  book  chapters  on  such  topics  as  the  politics  of  exchange rate  regimes,  monetary  policy,  wage  bargaining,  social  pacts,  and  democratic transition.  Her  current  research  centers  on  the  impact  of  European  monetary  inte¬ gration  on  labor  markets  in  countries  of  the  European  Union,  in  particular  Italy and  Spain,  and  the  impact  of  immigration  on  politics. JONAS  PONTUSSON  is  a  professor  of  political  science  at  the  University  of  Geneva. He  has  written,  most  recently,  Inequality  and  Prosperity:  Social  Europe  vs.  Liberal America  (Ithaca:  Cornell  University  Press,  2005). GEORGE  ROSS  is  ad  personam  Chaire  Jean  Monnet  at  the  University  of  Montreal, Morris  Hillquit  Emeritus  Professor  in  Labor  and  Social  Thought  at  Brandeis  Uni¬ versity,  and  faculty  associate  of  the  Minda  de  Gunzburg  Center  for  European Studies  at  Harvard  University.  He  is  the  author  of  Jacques  Delors  and  Euro¬ pean  Integration  (New  York:  Oxford  University  Press,  1995)  and  the  editor,  with Andrew  Martin,  of  The  Brave  New  World  of  European  Unions  (Oxford:  Berghahn, 1999)  and  Euros  and  Europeans:  EMU  and  the  European  Social  Model  (Cambridge: Cambridge  University  Press,  2005). JAMES  SHOCH  is  an  associate  professor  of  government  at  California  State  Uni¬ versity,  Sacramento.  He  is  the  author  of  Trading  Blows:  Party  Competition  and  U.S. Contributors  397 Trade  Policy  in  a  Globalizing  Era  (Chapel  Hill:  University  of  North  Carolina  Press) and  of  articles  on  the  politics  of  American  trade  and  industrial  policy. SORINA  SOARE  is  a  researcher  at  CEVIPOL,  le  Centre  d’Etude  de  la  Vie  Politique, at  the  Free  University  of  Brussels. RUY  TEIXEIRA  is  a  senior  fellow  at  the  Center  for  American  Progress  and  the Century  Foundation,  as  well  as  a  fellow  of  the  New  Politics  Institute.  He  has  also held  positions  at  the  Economic  Policy  Institute,  the  Brookings  Institution,  and the  Progressive  Policy  Institute.  He  is  the  author  or  co-author  of  five  books  in¬ cluding,  with  John  Judis,  The  Emerging  Democratic  Majority  (New  York:  Scribner, 2004);  with  Joel  Rogers,  America’s  Forgotten  Majority:  Why  the  White  Working Class  Still  Matters  (New  York:  Basic  Books,  2001);  and  The  Disappearing  Ameri¬ can  Voter  (Washington:  Brookings  Institution  Press,  1992). Index Page  numbers  in  italics  refer  to  figures;  those  followed  by  a  t  refer  to  tables. abortion,  164, 176, 177 Abrajano,  Marisa,  164-65 acquis  communautaire,  338 active  labor  market  policies  (ALMP), 243-44;  in  Germany,  256-58;  in  Swe¬ den,  245-46;  in  United  Kingdom, 251-56 Afghanistan:  asylum  seekers  from,  273, 274;  UK  forces  in,  133-34;  U.S.  forces in,  206 African  Americans,  164, 165;  civil  rights movement  and,  176, 177,  349;  of  Mil¬ lennial  generation,  169 Aid  to  Families  with  Dependent  Children (AFDC),  191 ALMP  (active  labor  market  policies), 243-44;  in  Germany,  256-58;  in  Swe¬ den,  245-46;  in  United  Kingdom, 251-56 Alvarez,  Michael,  164-65 American  Recovery  and  Reinvestment Act  (2009),  22,  205-6,  231,  349 Americans  with  Disabilities  Act  (ADA, 1990),  192, 196,  200,  204 Amsterdam  Treaty  (1997),  340  n.  19 Anderson,  Perry,  140  n.  4 Asian  Americans,  164-66, 169 asylum  seekers,  269,  271,  273-77,  280, 284-85.  See  also  immigration  policies Aubry,  Martine,  160 Australia:  income  inequality  in,  194; as  liberal  market  economy,  114  n.  2; social  democrats  of,  63t,  64,  80 Austria:  European  integration  and, 333-35;  immigration  policies  of,  271; Keynesianism  in,  69,  72;  Social  Demo¬ crats  of,  53t,  54,  57,  6it,  63,  68,  82,  84 n.  7;  as  social  market  economy,  90 Bad  Godesberg  program,  38-39 Bajnai,  Gordon,  301 Balcerowicz,  Leszek,  296 Balkan  crisis,  133, 140  n.  6,  271,  272 Bahadur,  Edouard,  148, 149 Barre,  Raymond,  142 Bartels,  Larry  M.,  197 Bayrou,  Francois,  155 Belgium,  321;  social  democrats  of,  57, 59-60,  6it;  socialists  of,  54,  63;  as social  market  economy,  90, 114  n.  3; unemployment  insurance  in,  115  n.  8; unions  in,  100-102 Benda,  Vaclav,  315 Benn,  Tony,  118, 140  n.  2 Berlusconi,  Silvio,  17,  279,  285,  286,  361 n.  2 Berman,  Sheri,  20,  29-48,  345,  395 Bernstein,  Eduard,  1,  32-33.  35,  39,  45 Bertram,  Eva  C.,  208  n.  20 Beveridge  Report  (1942),  251 Bildt,  Carl,  247 Bismarckian  policies.  See  corporatism Blair,  Tony,  15, 121-25, 131, 136-39,  334, 348;  foreign  policy  of,  132-34;  French leftists  and,  160;  immigration  policies of,  277,  278,  280,  286;  Let  Us  Face  the 400  Index Blair,  Tony  ( continued ) Future,  135;  Lisbon  Agenda  and,  328; modernization  strategy  of,  70;  New Deal  of,  126-27,  253,  254;  public  ser¬ vice  programs  of,  128-30;  social  poli¬ cies  of,  252-56;  The  Third  Way,  116, 243-44,  258,  260,  262  n.  7 Blau,  Francine,  97 Blum,  Leon,  41,  51 Boix,  Carles,  234  n.  4 Bosnia  conflict,  133, 140  n.  6,  271,  272, 304,  340  n.  21 Bossi-Fini  law,  279,  283,  285 Brandt,  Willy,  40,  270-71 Brazil,  8,  212,  228 Bretton  Woods  Conference  (1944),  5,  7, 320, 322 Brown,  Gordon,  116, 121, 126,  255,  348; child  policies  of,  252,  263  n.  19;  on crime,  135;  failures  of,  136;  immigra¬ tion  policies  of,  280,  282;  Iraq  War and,  134;  tax  policies  of,  128 Bulgaria,  290,  291;  democratization  of, 310-12,  314;  parliamentary  elections in,  294-951;  party  membership  in, 297t Bundesbank,  2, 15, 144,  322,  324,  327, 346-47 Bush,  George  H.  W.,  196,  204;  poverty rate  under,  197;  trade  policies  of,  211, 219 Bush,  George  W.,  18,  349;  child  health¬ care  and,  203;  election  of,  167, 179, 227;  Hispanic  supporters  of,  164-65; Medicare  drug  plan  of,  193, 197, 199, 200;  New  Labour  and,  138;  No  Child Left  Behind  and,  207  n.  11;  poverty rate  under,  197;  trade  policies  of, 225-28 CAFTA  (Central  American  Free  Trade Agreement),  211,  225,  227-28 Callaghan,  James,  6, 118, 124, 140  n.  2, 288  n.  16 Cameron,  David,  69, 134,  348 Canada,  194;  educational  policies  of, 97;  healthcare  in,  202,  203;  as  liberal market  economy,  114  n.  2;  welfare  pro¬ grams  in,  192 CAP  (Common  Agricultural  Policy),  320, 322 capital:  inefficient,  94;  mobility  of, 99-100;  patient,  89,  99 capitalism,  1-3,  24,  31;  “democratiz¬ ing,”  344,  352;  financialized,  230;  re¬ form  of,  37-38,  45-48;  varieties  of,  8, 96,  98-102,  232,  237  n.  30;  welfare, 63-64, 80-81 Care  Insurance  Act  (1994),  258 Carter,  Jimmy,  6, 177-78, 197,  216 Castles,  Stephen,  193 CDU  (Christlich-Demokratische  Union), 40,  256-58,  346,  354;  immigration policies  of,  273-76,  280,  285 center-left  parties,  1,  4-7,  20-24,  6i-6st, 63,  66,  76-83,  319-39;  accomplish¬ ments  of,  343-44;  coalitions  of,  12-13, 59-60,  256-62,  285;  electability  of, 8-12;  future  of,  45-48,  72-83,  241-62, 331-39,  35i-6o;  golden  age  of,  2-3, 53,  60;  immigration  policies  of,  265- 87;  new  policy  challenges  of,  241-62; types  of,  3, 14-19,  344-51 Central  American  Free  Trade  Agreement (CAFTA),  211,  225,  227-28 CFDT  (Confederation  Franqaise Democratique  du  Travail),  149, 153, 161  n.  13 Charter  of  Fundamental  Social  Rights, 127,  325-26 Chereque,  Francois,  153 Chevenement,  Jean-Pierre,  146 childcare  policies,  13,  244,  288  n.  21; British,  251-56,  260,  283;  German, 259-60;  Italian,  283;  Spanish,  283; Swedish,  246-50,  260 children:  health  insurance  for,  192, 193, 196,  203,  204;  No  Child  Left  Behind and,  207  n.  11;  in  poverty,  97, 129, 196, 242-43,  249-55,  260,  262  n.  2 Index  401 Child  Tax  Credit:  in  United  Kingdom, 127,  254;  in  United  States,  191, 193, 195. 196. 199,  200,  205 Child  Trust  Fund,  255 China,  304;  as  emerging  economy,  8, 212,  228;  U.S.  trade  policies  toward, 211,  221,  224-29 CHIP  (State  Children’s  Health  Insurance Program;  SCHIP),  192, 193, 196,  203, 204 Chirac,  Jacques,  142, 148-55 Christian  Democrats,  16-17,  62-63,  321, 360  n.  2;  decommodification  and,  98; after  Second  World  War,  321;  SMEs and,  114  n.  2 Christlich-Demokratische  Union  (CDU), 40,  256-58,  346,  354;  immigration policies  of,  273-76,  280,  285 Christlich-Soziale  Union  (CSU),  273-74, 285 civil  rights  movement,  176, 177,  349 Clasen,  Jochen,  253-54 class:  Democratic  Party  and,  172-82;  in Eastern  Europe,  290;  education  and, 96-97;  French  Socialists  and,  153; ideology  of,  72-76;  Labour  Party  and, 120;  Marxist  view  of,  30-33,  35-36, 41-42 Clegg,  Daniel,  253-54 Clegg,  Nick,  137 clientelism,  16-17, 158-59,  298,  309, 320-21,  360  n.  2 Clinton,  Bill,  18, 126;  budget  proposal of,  201;  Child  Tax  Credit  and,  191, 193. 195. 196. 199,  200;  election  of, 163, 178-79,  202;  Family  and  Medical Leave  Act  and,  191, 194-96,  200,  204; New  Labour  and,  133;  Obama  and, 206;  Perot  and,  208  n.  17;  poverty rate  under,  197;  trade  policies  of,  211, 219-25;  welfare  reform  of,  127, 178- 79, 191,  204,  349 Clinton,  Hillary  Rodham:  healthcare plan  of,  192,  197,  200,  202;  presiden¬ tial  campaign  of,  203 CMEs  (coordinated  market  economies), 98-102,  237  n.  30.  See  also  social  mar¬ ket  economies COBRA  (Consolidated  Omnibus  Budget Reconciliation  Act),  192, 194 cold  war,  7, 16-19, 188,  265,  290,  343, 358;  Democratic  Party  and,  176;  Euro¬ pean  Union  and,  326-27;  GATT  and, 214-15;  human  rights  and,  224;  New Labour  and,  133-34;  trade  policies and,  214,  215,  224 Colombia,  228,  229,  230 Commission  on  Social  Justice  (UK),  252 Common  Agricultural  Policy  (CAP),  320, 322,  339  n.  4 Commonwealth  immigration  acts,  269, 270,  276-77,  287  n.  4 communists,  34-35;  of  Bulgaria,  310;  of Czech  Republic,  301-4,  315,  3*7  n.  3; demise  of,  6-8, 16-19, 188,  290,  313, 316,  343,  358;  of  Great  Britain,  122; of  Romania,  307;  after  Second  World War,  320-22;  of  Slovakia,  302 communitarianism,  35, 135,  309 Confederation  Fran^aise  Democratique du  Travail  (CFDT),  149, 153, 161  n.  13 Consolidated  Omnibus  Budget  Recon¬ ciliation  Act  (COBRA,  1986),  192, 194 contribution  sociale  generalisee  (CSG), 145, 149 Cook,  Robin,  133 coordinated  market  economies  (CMEs), 98-102,  237  n.  30.  See  also  social  mar¬ ket  economies corporatism,  99, 119,  325,  346;  Rueda on,  115  n.  15;  social  democracy  and, 245,  262  n.  1 Craxi,  Bettino,  17,  41 Cronin,  James,  1-24,  395;  on  left’s  ac¬ complishments,  343-44;  on  left’s  dif¬ ferences,  344-51;  on  left’s  future,  351- 60;  on  New  Labour,  20, 116-39,  348 Crosland,  C.  A.  R.,  37, 139  n.  2 CSG  (contribution  sociale  generalisee), 145, 149 402  Index CSU  (Christlich-Soziale  Union),  273-74, 285 Cuba,  163,  304 Czechoslovakia,  291,  301-2 Czech  Republic,  290,  291,  293,  301,  317 n.  3;  democratization  of,  302-5,  314, 315;  parliamentary  elections  in,  294- 95t;  party  membership  in,  297L  317 n.  11;  unemployment  rate  of,  317  n.  12 Dahrendorf,  Ralf,  29 Darling,  Alastair,  137 Debray,  Regis,  161  n.  10 decommodification,  43,  63,  64,  97-98, 234  n.  3 de  Gaulle,  Charles,  322,  346 Delanoe,  Bertrand,  160 Delors,  Jacques,  147-48;  on  economic growth,  327-29,  33i,  334;  as  French finance  minister,  144;  Social  Charter of,  127,  324-25 Delwit,  Pascal,  85  n.  20 De  Man,  Hendrik,  34 Democratic  Leadership  Council  (DLC), 178,  202,  219,  221 Democratic  Party,  4, 18-19;  Asian- American  supporters  of,  165-66; coalition  of,  162-85;  minority  support of,  163-66, 169, 174, 178, 180;  New Deal  of,  3, 17, 174  -77, 190,  214,  348; “New  Democrats”  in,  178,  202,  219, 226,  227;  platform  website  for,  208 n.  19;  poverty  rates  and,  197;  Reagan supporters  in,  216;  religious  support¬ ers  of,  170-71;  social  spending  by, 22;  Teixeira  on,  21;  trade  policies  of, 210-33;  union  supporters  of,  171-72, 175,  215,  219,  224,  226-27,  229;  wel¬ fare  reform  and,  189-90, 196-206; women  in,  166-67;  working-class  sup¬ porters  of,  172-82;  young  supporters of,  168-70 democratization,  290,  292-93;  of  Bul¬ garia,  310-12,  314;  of  Czech  Repub¬ lic,  302-5,  314,  315;  of  Hungary,  291, 298-301,  314;  of  Poland,  291,  294- 95t,  295-98,  314;  of  Romania,  307-10, 313-14;  of  Slovakia,  305-6,  314 Demos  (organization),  136 Denmark,  71;  economic  growth  in,  102- 8;  educational  policies  of,  96;  employ¬ ment  trends  in,  108-10,  mt;  European integration  and,  330,  334~35,  337! “flexicurity”  in,  14, 15, 106,  333,  344- 45;  globalization  and,  47-48;  immi¬ gration  laws  of,  271;  inequality  mea¬ sures  in,  93t;  Social  Democrats  of,  54, 60,  6it,  63,  70,  89-91;  unemployment in,  92, 115  n.  10,  253-54,  257;  unions in,  100-102.  See  also  Nordic  countries De  Waele,  Jean-Michel,  20,  290-317, 350,  395 DLC  (Democratic  Leadership  Council), 178,  202,  219,  221 dualism,  17;  labor-market,  102, 108,  nit; social,  10-11 Duclos,  Jacques,  142 Dukakis,  Michael,  180,  218-19 Earned  Income  Tax  Credit  (EITC),  191, 193, 195-97,  200,  201,  204,  205 EC  (European  Community),  322-26,  339 n.  1 ECB  (European  Central  Bank),  146,  324, 327,  339  n.  11,  359 Economic  and  Monetary  Union  (EMU), 7, 143-44, 146-47, 149,  319,  324-34, 337 Economic  Opportunity  Act  (1964),  199 economic  stimulus  package,  22,  205-6, 231,  349 education:  Blair’s  policies  for,  253;  class and,  96-97;  Democratic  affiliation and,  166-67, 179-82;  French  policies on,  144;  No  Child  Left  Behind  and, 207  n.  11;  Nordic  model  for,  96-97, 248;  Thatcher’s  policies  for,  128;  voca¬ tional,  89,  96, 100, 127 EEC  (European  Economic  Community), 56-58,  68,  320-22,  339  n.  1 Index  403 egalitarianism,  44-45,  74-75,  81,  91-98, 107, 124,  237,  357 Eisenhower,  Dwight,  175 elderly  persons,  241-43;  British  policies for,  255;  European  spending  on,  244; German  policies  for,  258-59;  poverty rate  for,  191;  Swedish  policies  for,  247, 248 Emergency  Medical  Treatment  and Labor  Act  (1986),  192 Emmanuelli,  Henri,  148 Employee  Free  Choice  Act,  172 employment,  part-time,  108-10 EMU  (Economic  and  Monetary  Union), 7, 143-44,  146-47, 149,  319,  324-34, 337 Engels,  Friedrich,  30,  32 environmentalism,  11, 175-77, 183,  206, 213;  green  parties  and,  3, 147,  306,  354 Epinay  Congress  (1971),  147 Erfurt  Programme,  72 Ericsson  Corporation,  104 Esping-Andersen,  Gosta,  26  n.  8,  63-64, 91,  262  n.  1;  critique  of,  97-98,  234 n.  3 Ethiopia,  273,  274 European  Central  Bank  (ECB),  146,  324, 327,  339  n.  11,  359 European  Coal  and  Steel  Community (ECSC),  320 European  Community  (EC),  322-26,  339 n.  1 European  Economic  Community  (EEC), 320-22,  339  n.  1;  socialist  parties  of, 56-58, 68 European  Employment  Strategy  (EES), 334 European  Monetary  System  (EMS), 142-44, 323 European  Trade  Union  Confederation, 335 European  Union  (EU):  center-left  parties in,  15-19,  23-24,  61-65L  63,  66,  76- 83,  241-62,  319-39;  constitutional referendum  of,  154, 156,  330,  336;  eco¬ nomic  growth  in,  102-8;  employment trends  in,  108-10,  lilt;  expansion  of, 57,  290-91;  fiftieth  anniversary  of, 326-27;  future  of,  45-48,  72-83,  241- 62,  331-39,  35i-6o;  history  of,  319- 24;  immigration  policies  of,  265-87; public  opposition  to,  329-31;  socialist parties  of,  56-58,  73-75;  unemploy¬ ment  in,  327-29,  340  n.  19;  in  Yugo¬ slav  conflicts,  340  n.  21 evangelicals,  167, 170, 171 exceptionalism:  American,  21,  25  n.  7, 189,  234  n.  9;  Finnish,  114  n.  1;  French, 141;  Norwegian,  15 Exchange  Rate  Mechanism  (ERM),  323, 339  n.  7,  339  n.  8 Fabius,  Laurent,  154, 155, 159 Falklands  War,  133 families:  British  policies  for,  251-56; Democratic  Party  and,  178;  European spending  on,  244;  feminists  and,  176; immigrant,  269,  275,  278;  single¬ parent,  13,  23, 166-67,  241-43,  246- 49,  253,  254;  Swedish  policies  for, 247-50;  working  women  and,  22-23, 108-10,  259,  261 Family  and  Medical  Leave  Act  (FMLA, 1993),  191, 194-96,  200,  204 fascism,  2,  9,  35 FDP  (Freie  Demokratische  Partei),  273 Fico,  Robert,  291,  306 Filipino  immigrants,  283 Fillon,  Francois,  153 Finland,  15,  345;  economic  growth  in, 102-8;  educational  policies  of,  96-97; employment  trends  in,  108-10;  excep¬ tionalism  of,  114  n.  1;  inequality  mea¬ sures  in,  93t;  social  democrats  of,  53L 54,  57,  59-6o,  6it,  63L  89-91;  unem¬ ployment  in,  25  n.  6;  unions  in,  100- 102.  See  also  Nordic  countries First  World  War,  2,  33-34 flexible  work  forces,  14, 15,  92-94, 106, 145,  333,  344-46,  350-51 404  Index Food  Stamps  (U.S.),  190, 191,  206,  274 food  vouchers  (Germany),  274 Ford,  Gerald  R.,  177, 196 Fordist  manufacturing  system,  5,  215-17 Foreign  Policy  Center,  136 Fourastie,  Jean,  141 France,  15-16,  90, 149,  345-46;  EU  Con¬ stitution  rejected  by,  154, 156,  330, 336;  European  integration  and,  322- 26,  334;  fragmentation  of  left  in,  141, i58t;  green  party  of,  147;  immigra¬ tion  policies  of,  155,  267,  269-72,  285, 286,  287  n.  8;  presidentialism  in,  142, 157-59;  social  democrats  of,  52-79; socialist  parties  of,  41-42,  84  n.  7,  84 n.  11, 141-61 Free  Trade  Agreement  of  the  Americas, 225,  227 Freie  Demokratische  Partei  (FDP),  273 Friedman,  Thomas,  45 Front  National  (France),  147, 150, 155,  354 Gaitskell,  Hugh,  139  n.  2 Galston,  William,  178 General  Agreement  on  Tariffs  and  Trade (GATT),  7,  211,  214,  215;  Doha  Round of,  227;  Uruguay  Round  of,  221,  222 General  Social  Survey,  208  n.  13 Generation  X,  168, 170 Germany,  345;  childcare  policies  in, 259-60;  economic  growth  in,  102-8; employment  trends  in,  108-10,  mt; Grand  Coalition  in,  256-62,  285;  high technology  in,  104-5;  immigration policies  of,  268-76,  280-86;  inequali¬ ties  in,  93t,  194;  Keynesianism  and,  2, 16,  322;  monetarism  in,  15, 144,  322, 324,  327,  346-47;  NATO  and,  40;  as social  market  economy,  90;  social policy  challenges  in,  256-60;  unifi¬ cation  of,  16, 146,  274,  290,  340  n.  15, 346-47;  unions  in,  100-102,  257,  334, 346,  347;  vocational  training  in,  96, 100 Gerring,  John,  201 Ghent  system,  115  n.  8 Giddens,  Anthony,  26  n.  8,  29, 136 Gill,  Stephen,  140  n.  4 Gingrich,  Newt,  204,  223 Gini  coefficient,  193-94, 197 Giscard  d’Estaing,  Valery,  142-43, 146, 154 globalization,  7-8,  22-23,  210-13,  343- 45.  353;  of  finance,  99-100;  immigra¬ tion  and,  266-68;  Labour  Party  and, 122-23;  opponents  of,  4,  45;  social democratic  approach  to,  29-30,  45, 81-82, 112-13,  232;  unemployment and,  208  n.  22 Glotz,  Peter,  59 Goldhammer,  Arthur,  20, 141-61,  346, 395 gold  standard,  5,  322 Gonzalez,  Felipe,  308 Gorbachev,  Mikhail,  133 Gore,  Al,  163-65, 179, 180,  202,  226 Gramsci,  Antonio,  45 Great  Depression,  2,  25  n.  3,  206,  214, 355;  social  democrats  and,  34,  36 Great  Recession,  24,  206,  229-30,  269, 348, 355-59 Great  Society,  176, 190, 199,  349; revampings  of,  200-203,  205 Grebenicek,  Miroslav,  302-3 Greece,  17,  80-81,  347,  360;  as  European Community  member,  323;  insolvency of,  356;  Panhellenic  Socialist  Move¬ ment  in,  55-57,  60,  62t,  67-71,  82,  84 n.  7,  323;  social  democrats  of,  53L  60, 62t,  67,  82 green  parties,  3, 147,  306,  354-  See  also environmentalism Green  Party  (Germany),  40,  256,  258, 259,  261,  334,  347;  immigration  poli¬ cies  of,  268,  274-76,  280,  285;  die Linke  in,  161,  333 Greenspan,  Alan,  219 Guillebaud,  Jean-Claude,  161  n.  10 gypsies,  279 Gyurcsany,  Ferenc,  300 Index  405 Hall,  Peter,  25  n.  3,  81 Hamon,  Benoit,  160 Handl,  Vladimir,  317  n.  13 Hansen,  Randall,  288  n.  16 Hansson,  Per  Albin,  35 Hartz  reforms,  263  n.  24,  267,  282 Haught,  Randall,  195 Havel,  Vaclav,  305 Haymarket  riot  (1886),  9 healthcare,  242;  in  Canada,  202,  203;  for children  in  United  States,  192, 193, 196,  203,  204;  Clintons’  plan  for,  192, 196,  200,  202;  Family  and  Medical Leave  Act,  191, 194-96,  200,  204;  in France,  145-46, 149-53;  in  Germany, 258-59;  for  immigrants,  281;  immi¬ grant  workers  in,  283-84;  Medicare drug  benefit  and,  207  n.  5;  Obama’s reform  of,  18,  22, 183-85,  203-4,  206, 349;  in  Sweden,  248;  in  United  King¬ dom,  128,  255 Health  Insurance  Portability  and  Ac¬ countability  Act  (HIPAA,  1996),  192, 194, 196 Heath,  Edward,  120 Hegel,  G.  W.  F.,  32 Hewitt,  Patricia,  121 high  technology,  104-5 Hispanics,  163-65, 169 Hix,  Simon,  341  n.  29 Hobsbawm,  Eric,  10,  72-73 Hollande,  Francois,  154-55 Horak,  Jiri,  302 Howard,  Christopher,  21-22, 188-206, 242,  349,  395-96 Huber,  Evelyne,  91,  208  n.  22 Hungary:  democratization  of,  291,  298- 301,  314;  parliamentary  elections  in, 294-951;  party  membership  in,  297t; revolt  of  1956  in,  298-99 Hussein,  Saddam,  304 Iliescu,  Ion,  307-8 immigrants,  196,  266-68;  asylum seekers  as,  269,  271,  273-77,  280, 284-85;  childcare  policies  for,  288 n.  21;  family  reunification  for,  269, 275,  278;  social  integration  of,  23, 280,  282-84,  288  n.  11;  violence against,  274,  276;  women  as,  281-83 immigration  policies,  4,  287;  conse¬ quences  of,  265-68;  of  France,  155, 267,  269-72,  285,  286,  287  n.  8;  of Germany,  268-76,  280-86;  history of,  269-72;  of  Italy,  272,  278-86; of  Netherlands,  270;  race  and,  277; rights-based,  286-87;  of  Spain,  272, 278-86,  288  n.  21;  of  Sweden,  270;  of United  Kingdom,  131,  269-72,  276- 78,  280-83,  286,  288  n.  16;  of  United States,  21,  201 income:  inequality  of,  194,  243;  redistri¬ bution  of,  92,  93t,  247 India,  8,  212,  228 Inglehart,  Ronald,  287 Institute  for  Public  Policy  Research (IPPR),  136,  252 internationalism,  2,  25  n.  2,  30;  Bern¬ stein  on,  32;  in  France,  147-48 International  Monetary  Fund  (IMF),  7, 122-23,  356,  359 Internet,  11-12;  computer  literacy  and,  93L 97, 108,  248;  dot-com  bubble  and,  227 Iran,  206 Iraq  War,  304;  Blair’s  policies  for,  132- 34, 138;  Obama’s  policies  for,  206 Ireland,  330,  336;  economic  growth in,  90,  i03t,  115  n.  9;  insolvency  of, 356;  as  liberal  market  economy,  114 n.  2;  poor  children  in,  262  n.  2;  social democrats  of,  53t,  63L  64 Italy,  16-17,  327,  334,  354-551  European integration  and,  334;  immigration policies  of,  270,  272,  278-86;  income inequality  in,  194;  solvency  of,  356 Iverson,  Torben,  25  n.  5,  96, 115  n.  14 Jacobs,  Michael,  48 Japan,  5;  trade  policies  of,  211,  215,  219, 220 406  Index Jenson,  Jane,  22-23, 188,  207  n.  5,  241- 62,  351,  396 job  security,  92 Johnson,  Lyndon  B.,  177, 190, 197 Jospin,  Lionel,  147, 148, 150-52, 158,  334, 354 Jouyet,  Jean-Pierre,  151, 161  n.  14 Juppe,  Alain,  149, 150, 153 Kaczynski,  Jaroslaw,  298 Kadar,  Janos,  299 Kahn,  Lawrence,  97 Kamarck,  Elaine,  178 Kanis,  Pavol,  301 Kant,  Immanuel,  32 Karapin,  Roger,  267 Katzenstein,  Peter,  107 Kautsky,  Karl,  1,  30-31,  39 Kennedy,  Edward,  203 Kennedy,  John  F.,  167, 197 Kenya,  277 Kerry,  John,  163-65, 167, 179, 180;  Mil¬ lennial  supporters  of,  169;  union  sup¬ porters  of,  171;  welfare  platform  of, 202 Keynesianism,  2-3,  214,  258,  349,  353; alternatives  to,  13;  Austrian  version of,  69,  72;  French  version  of,  142,  322, 323,  325;  German  version  of,  258,  322; Greek  version  of,  67;  revival  of,  355, 361  n.  4;  shift  from,  18,  74,  82, 117-18, 188,  215-17,  323,  325,  343;  welfare policies  and,  5,  72,  321 King,  Desmond,  108 Kinnock,  Neil,  121, 123 Kitschelt,  Herbert,  25  n.  8,  85  n.  19,  268 Kjellberg,  Anders,  101 Klaus,  Vaclav,  302-4 Kohl,  Helmut,  257,  273,  274,  324-25 Korea:  North,  304;  South,  229 Kosovo  crisis,  133,  271 Kwasniewski,  Alexander,  296,  298 Labour  Party,  2,  4, 15,  54,  69,  251,  339 n.  2;  electoral  status  of,  59,  60;  immi¬ gration  policies  of,  276-77,  288  n.  16; modernization  of,  70,  72, 118-25, 121; oil  shocks  and,  6;  social  democrats and,  64, 135;  Thatcher  and,  339  n.  5; trade  unions  and,  123-25.  See  also New  Labour  Party Laclau,  Ernesto,  74 Lang,  Jack,  155 Latinos,  163-65, 169 Lenin,  Vladimir,  32 Le  Pen,  Jean-Marie,  147 LGBT  issues,  176 Liberal  Democrats  (UK),  137-39 liberalism,  3;  “embedded,”  214-15,  232; laissez-faire,  34,  37,  48, 112;  Lockean, 235  n.  10;  neoliberalism  vs.,  218,  344; social  democracy  and,  37,  47,  262  n.  1; socialism  and,  135 liberal  market  economies  (LMEs),  93b CMEs  versus,  99-100,  237  n.  30;  em¬ ployment  trends  in,  108-10,  mt; growth  of,  103-51;  inequality  mea¬ sures  in,  93t,  95;  social  market  econo¬ mies  vs.,  102, 114  n.  2 Linke,  die  (Germany),  16,  40, 161,  333, 354 Lisbon  Agenda  (2000),  328-29,  334,  336 Lisbon  Treaty  (2008),  330,  336 literacy,  96;  computer,  93b  97, 108,  248 LMEs.  See  liberal  market  economies Locke,  John,  235  n.  10 Luxembourg,  54;  social  democrats  of, 53b  57,  59-6o,  6it Luxembourg  Income  Study,  194 Maastricht  Treaty  (1992),  146-48,  319, 324,  340  n.  15 Macmillan,  Harold,  276 Making  Work  Pay  Tax  Credit,  205 Mandelson,  Peter,  121 Marchais,  Georges,  142 Martin,  Cathie  Jo,  102 Marx,  Karl:  on  anarchism,  1;  on  class struggle,  30-33,  35-36,  41-42 Marxism,  290,  292,  303;  Labour  Party Index  407 and,  120;  orthodox,  30-36,  40-41,  48 n.  2;  social  democracy  vs.,  39 Mauroy,  Pierre,  143 McGovern,  George,  177 Meciar,  Vladimir,  305 Medgyessy,  Peter,  300 media:  French,  143, 155;  political  cam¬ paigns  and,  11 Medicare,  Medicaid,  190, 191, 196,  203; cost-control  measures  for,  200;  drug benefit  of,  193, 197, 199,  200,  207  n.  5 Meidner,  Rudolf,  43,  94,  107, 112,  246 Merkel,  Angela,  257-60,  354 Merkel,  Wolfgang,  26  n.  8;  on  class  inter¬ ests,  75;  typology  of,  58-60,  6it,  62t, 80-81,  84  n.  7,  84  n.  9 Miliband,  David,  132, 134,  252 Miliband,  Ed,  117 Millennial  generation,  168-70 Miller,  Leszek,  297 Milosevic,  Slobodan,  304 minorities,  11;  Democratic  Party  and, 163-66, 169, 174, 178, 180.  See  also race “misery  index,”  178 Mitterrand,  Francois,  6, 156, 158-59,  321; economic  policies  of,  143-47,  323-26; election  of,  142-44,  323;  scandals  in¬ volving,  147 Mladenov,  Petar,  310 Mollet,  Guy,  41-42,  321 Mondale,  Walter,  178 monetarism,  5;  of  Bundesbank,  15, 144, 322,  324,  327,  346-47;  Maastricht Treaty  and,  146 Money,  Jeannette,  266 Morone,  James,  235  n.  10 Moschonas,  Gerassimos,  20,  25  n.  8, 50-83, 112,  341  n.  32,  347,  351,  396 Moscovici,  Pierre,  160 Muslims,  170,  288  n.  11 NAFTA  (North  American  Free  Trade Agreement),  211,  221-23,  228,  229, 236  n.  16 Nagler,  Jonathan,  164-65 NATO  (North  Atlantic  Treaty  Organiza¬ tion),  40, 132-33 Nenni,  Pietro,  40-41 neoliberalism,  4-7, 188,  205,  353;  of Blair,  160;  of  Clinton,  219-25;  “com¬ pensatory,”  119, 140  n.  4;  “disci¬ plinary,”  140  n.  4;  in  Eastern  Europe, 290,  303,  306;  liberalism  vs.,  218,  344; New  Labour  and,  69-70; of  Reagan, 211,  216-18,  225;  of  Thatcher,  15, 118-19 Netherlands,  54,  61,  63,  321,  345;  EU Constitution  rejected  by,  330,  336;  im¬ migration  policies  of,  270;  low-paid jobs  in,  110,  mt;  social  democrats  of, 53*.  57,  59-6o,  6it;  as  social  market economy,  90 New  Deal,  205;  of  Blair,  126-27,  253,  254; Clinton’s  view  of,  178,  200;  of  Roose¬ velt,  3, 17, 174-77, 190,  214,  349 “New  Democrats,”  178,  202,  219,  226,  227 New  Labour  Party,  15,  72, 116, 135,  333, 334,  348,  357;  Clinton  and,  133;  com- munitarianism  of,  135;  crime  policies of,  131;  economic  policies  of,  125-27; emergence  of,  20, 117-25;  employ¬ ment  policies  of,  125-28,  253-56; foreign  policy  of,  132-34;  future  of, 136-39;  immigration  policies  of,  131, 277,  278,  280,  286;  Iraq  War  and, 132, 138;  public  services  and,  128-30; unions  and,  127-28.  See  abo  Labour Party;  Third  Way New  Liberalism  (UK),  135 New  Zealand,  96;  social  democrats  of, 63b  64,  80 Nice  Treaty  (2001),  330 Nixon,  Richard,  5,  167, 177 No  Child  Left  Behind,  207  n.  11 Nokia  Corporation,  104 Nordic  countries,  6, 14-15,  89-90,  99, 111-13,  262  n.  1,  339  n.  2,  344-45, 350;  collective  bargaining  in,  92-95, 100-102;  deregulation  in,  105-6;  eco- 408  Index Nordic  countries  ( continued ) nomic  growth  in,  102-8;  educational policies  of,  96-97,  248;  egalitarian¬ ism  in,  91-98;  employment  policies in,  108-10,  mt,  245-46;  free  trade and,  210-11,  232;  social  democrats  of, 35-36, 52-79,  333 North  American  Free  Trade  Agreement (NAFTA),  211,  221-23,  228;  Bush’s  role in,  236  n.  16;  Obama’s  view  of,  229 North  Atlantic  Treaty  Organization (NATO),  40, 132-33 Northern  League  (Italy),  279,  286 North  Korea,  304 Norway,  15,  60,  63,  82,  333,  345;  eco¬ nomic  growth  in,  102-8;  educational policies  of,  96-97;  employment trends  in,  108-10,  nit;  income  in¬ equality  in,  194;  inequality  measures in,  93t;  social  democrats  of,  6it,  70, 89-91;  unemployment  rate  in,  115 n.  10;  unions  in,  100-102 nuclear  weapons,  132-33 Obama,  Barack,  12, 19,  349,  355;  ap¬ proval  ratings  for,  184;  economic stimulus  package  of,  22,  205-6;  elec¬ tion  of,  163-65, 169, 171, 180-81,  357; environmental  policies  of,  183,  206; healthcare  reform  of,  18,  22, 183-85, 203-4,  206,  349;  Millennial  support¬ ers  of,  169;  reelection  prospects  of, 21-22, 179, 182-85,  206,  361  n.  6; trade  policies  of,  22, 183,  212-13, 228-33 OECD  (Organisation  for  Economic  Co¬ operation  and  Development),  81,  90, 192-93,  244,  359;  deregulation  and, 105-6;  educational  policies  and,  97; employment  protections  and,  92-94 oil  shocks  (1973, 1979),  6,  270,  322 Ollenhauer,  Erich,  38-39 Omnibus  Trade  and  Competitiveness  Act (1988),  217 Open  Method  of  Coordination  (OMC), 328-29, 334 Orban,  Viktor,  300 Organisation  for  Economic  Coopera¬ tion  and  Development  (OECD),  81,  90, 192-93,  244,  359;  deregulation  and, 105-6;  educational  policies  and,  97; employment  protections  and,  92-94 Osborne,  George,  139 Palier,  Bruno,  108 Panama,  229 Panhellenic  Socialist  Movement (PASOK),  55-57,  60,  62t,  67-71,  82,  84 n.  7,  323 Paris  Commune  (1871),  9 Parti  Communiste  Franqais  (PCF),  141, 320;  decline  of,  144, 146;  immigration policies  of,  267;  Mitterrand  and,  142, 147,  321 Partido  Popular,  279 Partido  Socialista,  279-81 Partido  Socialista  Obrero  Espahol (PSOE),  55-56,  62t,  67-69,  333,  357 Parti  Socialiste  (PS),  141, 143-45, 150-55, 268;  European  integration  and,  320- 21,  325,  333,  334;  fragmentation  of, 156-59;  French  communists  and,  142, 323;  Gaullists  and,  148, 159;  Maas¬ tricht  Treaty  and,  146-48 Partito  Comunista  Italiano  (PCI),  40-41, 320,  321,  354,  360  n.  2 Partito  Socialista  Italiano  (PSI),  40-41, 51,  83  n.  1,  320,  321 part-time  employment,  108-10 Party  of  European  Socialists,  335 PASOK  (Panhellenic  Socialist  Move¬ ment),  55-57,  60,  62t,  67-71,  82,  84 n.  7,  323 Pasqua  laws  (1986),  271 PCF  (Parti  Communiste  Franqais),  141, 320;  decline  of,  144, 146;  immigration policies  of,  267;  Mitterrand  and,  142, 147,  321 Index  409 PCI  (Partito  Comunista  Italiano),  40-41, 320,  321,  354,  360  n.  2 Pell  Grants,  236  n.  29 Pelosi,  Nancy,  203 pension  plans,  91,  241,  347;  of  Mitter¬ rand,  145-46;  in  United  States,  195, 204, 349 “people’s”  parties,  35-36,  43,  290,  316 Perez,  Sofia,  23,  265-87,  396 Perot,  Ross,  179,  208  n.  17,  219,  220 Peyrefitte  law  (1981),  271 Phares  et  Balises  (organization),  161  n.  10 Philippines,  283 Phillips,  Kevin,  176 Pierson,  Paul,  208  n.  17 Poland:  democratization  of,  291,  294- 95h  295-98,  314;  migrants  from, 274-75,  287  n.  2;  parliamentary  elec¬ tions  in,  294-95t;  party  memberships of,  297t Policy  Network,  136 Pontusson,  Jonas,  20-21,  89-113,  263 n.  17,  344,  396 Portugal,  17,  80-81,  347,  360;  childcare policies  of,  288  n.  21;  as  European Community  member,  323,  324;  insol¬ vency  of,  356;  migrants  from,  282; social  democrats  of,  53t,  60;  socialists of,  55-57,  62t,  67,  82,  85  n.  18 post-Fordist  economy,  5, 120,  216-19, 268,  290 poverty:  children  in,  97, 129, 196,  242- 43,  249-55,  260;  income  inequality and,  194;  single-parent  families  and, 242-43;  U.S.  welfare  reform  and,  191- 97,  201-2,  205-6 Powell,  Enoch,  276 Prague  Spring  (1968),  301 Prodi,  Romano,  279 Progressive  Governance  Network,  136 Progressive  Policy  Institute,  202 progressivism,  3,  9;  British,  135;  Demo¬ cratic  Party  and,  176-77;  unions  and, 171-72 Przeworski,  Adam,  72-75,  79,  290 PS.  See  Parti  Socialiste PSI  (Partito  Socialista  Italiano),  40-41, 51,  83  n.  1,  320,  321 PSOE  (Partido  Socialista  Obrero  Espa- nol),  55-56,  62t,  67-69,  333,  357 Qatar,  227 race,  11;  anti-immigrant  violence  and, 274,  276;  civil  rights  movement and,  176, 177,  349;  Democratic  Party and,  163-66, 169, 174, 178, 180;  im¬ migration  policies  and,  277;  Republi¬ can  Party  and,  178;  working  class  and, 172-82 Radiohead,  50 Raffarin,  Jean-Pierre,  153, 154 Rassemblement  pour  la  Republique (RPR),  148-50 Reagan,  Ronald,  18, 132, 185,  204; poverty  rate  under,  197;  reelection of,  202;  trade  policies  of,  211,  216-18, 225;  white  working-class  supporters of,  178 Reciprocal  Trade  Agreements  Act  (1934), 214 Rehn-Meidner  model,  43,  94, 107, 112,  246 religion:  conservative  voters  and,  21, 167, 170;  liberal  voters  and,  170, 171, 174 Republican  Party,  21, 182;  Contract  with America  of,  196;  evangelical  support¬ ers  of,  21, 167, 170;  Hispanic  support¬ ers  of,  163-65;  poverty  rates  and,  197; race  and,  178;  social  spending  by,  22; “Tea  Party”  activists  and,  184-85; trade  policies  of,  211,  215,  225-28, 232-33;  welfare  reform  and,  189-90, 196-99,  204-6;  young  supporters  of, 170 revenu  minimum  d’insertion  (RMI),  145, 161  n.  8 Ricardo,  David,  233  n.  2 Rocard,  Michel,  146, 147 410  Index Rokkan,  Stein,  340  n.  22 Romania,  291;  democratization  of, 307-10,  313-14;  migrants  from,  279, 287  n.  2;  parliamentary  elections  in, 294-95^  party  memberships  of,  297t; Socialist  Labor  Party  of,  291 Roman,  Petre,  307-8 Rome  Treaties  (1957),  319-21,  324,  339 n.  3 Roosevelt,  Franklin  D.,  3, 17, 174-77, 190, 214,  348 Ross,  George,  1-24,  396;  on  European center  lefts,  23-24;  on  European  inte¬ gration,  319-39;  on  French  left,  20, 141-61,  346;  on  left’s  accomplish¬ ments,  343-44;  on  left’s  differences, 344-51;  on  left’s  future,  351-60;  on social  democratic  identity,  74 Rothstein,  Bo,  114  n.  8 Royal,  Segolene,  12, 155, 159, 160,  285 RPR  (Rassemblement  pour  la  Repu- blique),  148-50 Rueda,  David,  108, 115  n.  15 Ruggie,  John,  36-37 Russia,  2,  9;  as  emerging  economy,  8, 212,  228 Samuelson,  Paul,  233  n.  2 SAP.  See  Socialdemokratiska Arbetareparti Sarkozy,  Nicolas,  151, 154-56,  285 Scandinavia.  See  Nordic  countries Schain,  Martin  A.,  266-67 Scharpf,  Fritz,  25  n.  8 Schily  law,  275,  285 SCHIP  (State  Children’s  Health  Insurance Program),  192, 193, 196,  203,  204 Schlesinger,  Arthur,  76 Schmidt,  Helmut,  40, 142,  273,  274 Schmidt,  Vivien,  340  n.  24 Schonfield,  Andrew,  37 Schroder,  Gerhard,  259,  334;  immigra¬ tion  policies  of,  274-75,  282,  285-86; The  Third  Way,  116,  243-44,  258,  260, 262  n.  7 Schumacher,  Kurt,  38,  39 SEA  (Single  European  Act),  324,  340 n.  13 Second  World  War,  2;  Christian  Demo¬ crats  after,  321;  French  left  after,  141- 42;  political  campaigns  after,  11;  social democracy  after,  36-45,  320-21 Section  Franqaise  de  l’lnternationale Ouvriere  (SFIO),  41-42,  84  n.  7,  321 September  11  attacks,  133-34, 138, 162, 269 SGP  (Stability  and  Growth  Pact),  327,  331 Sheils,  John,  195 Shoch,  James,  1-24,  396-97;  on  glob¬ alization,  22,  210-33;  on  left’s  ac¬ complishments,  343-44;  on  left’s differences,  344-51;  on  left’s  future, 351-60;  on  Perot,  208  n.  17 Simeon  II  of  Bulgaria,  311-12 Single  European  Act  (SEA),  324,  340 n.  13 Slovakia,  291,  301-2;  democratization of,  305-6,  314;  parliamentary  elec¬ tions  in,  294-95L  party  membership in,  297t SMEs.  See  social  market  economies Smith,  John  (Labour  Party  leader),  121, 123,  251-52 Smoot-Hawley  Tariff  Act  (1930),  214 Soare,  Sorina,  20,  290-317,  350,  397 Social  Charter,  127 social  democracy,  3,  4,  262  n.  1;  “classi¬ cal,”  58-64;  crises  in,  51-52,  67-72, 290;  declines  in,  55-61,  63L  66, 72-79;  electoral  dynamics  of,  50-83; electoral  phases  of,  52-58;  future  of, 45-48,  72-83,  241-62,  331-39,  351- 60;  globalization  and,  29,  45,  81-82, 112-13,  211,  232;  liberalism  and,  37, 47,  262  n.  1;  Nordic,  35-36,  52-79, 333;  after  Second  World  War,  36-45; socialism  and,  30-36,  39,  290;  social policy  challenges  of,  241-62;  varieties of  capitalism  and,  98-102;  working class  and,  72-74 Index  411 Socialdemokratiska  Arbetareparti  (SAP, Social  Democratic  Labour  Party  of Sweden),  4,  20-21,  89-91,  260,  357; immigration  policies  of,  270;  ori¬ gins  of,  35-36;  policy  challenges  for, 245-50,  252;  after  Second  World  War, 42-45,  60 socialism,  1-3,  335;  collapse  of,  6-8, 16-19, 188,  265;  democratic,  39;  Gid- dens  on,  29;  liberalism  and,  135;  New Labour  rhetoric  and,  121, 135;  “pope” of,  30;  after  Second  World  War, 38-45,  320-21;  social  democrats  and, 30-36,  39,  290;  “supply-side,”  127;  in United  States,  188 social  market  economies  (SMEs):  de¬ fined,  90;  deregulation  of,  105-6; egalitarianism  among,  91-98;  em¬ ployment  trends  in,  108-10,  mt; growth  of,  102-8;  liberal  market economies  vs.,  102, 114  n.  2 Social  Security,  190-91, 198 Solidarnosc  (Polish  Solidarity  move¬ ment),  295,  296 South  Africa,  8 South  Korea,  229 Soviet  Union,  2,  9,  315;  demise  of,  6-8, 16-19, 188,  290,  313,  343,  358;  inter¬ nationalism  of,  2,  25  n.  2;  nuclear weapons  of,  133;  Prague  Spring  and, 301;  social  democracy  and,  34.  See also  cold  war Sozialdemokratische  Partei  Deutsch- lands  (SPD),  32,  82,  334;  immigration policies  of,  268,  273-76,  280-82,  285; die  Linke  and,  16,  40, 161,  333,  354; after  Second  World  War,  38-40,  60, 320,  321;  social  policy  challenges  for, 256-62 Sozialdemokratische  Partei  Osterreichs (SPO),  53t,  54,  57,  6it,  63,  68,  82,  84 n.  7 Spaak,  Paul-Henri,  321 Spain,  17,  80-81,  347,  357,  360;  as  Euro¬ pean  Community  member,  323,  324, 327;  foreign  residents  in,  270,  278; immigration  policies  of,  272,  278-86, 288  n.  21;  social  democrats  of,  53t,  60, 62t,  67;  solvency  of,  3 Sprague,  John,  73-75,  79,  290 Sri  Lanka,  273,  274 Stability  and  Growth  Pact  (SGP),  327,  331 stagflation,  5,  6, 177-78,  322 “stakeholder  society,”  135 State  Children’s  Health  Insurance  Pro¬ gram  (SCHIP),  192, 193, 196,  203,  204 Stephens,  John,  25  n.  5,  91,  96,  208  n.  22 Stockholm  School,  72 Strauss-Kahn,  Dominique,  147-48, 151, 154, 155, 159, 160 Straw,  Jack,  122, 134 Summers,  Lawrence,  232 Sure  Start  program  (UK),  254 Svoboda, Jin,  302-3 Sweden,  14,  47-48,  344;  childcare  poli¬ cies  in,  246-50,  260;  deregulation in,  106;  economic  growth  in,  102-8; educational  policies  of,  96-97;  em¬ ployment  trends  in,  108-10,  nit; EU  membership  for,  25  n.  6;  Euro¬ pean  integration  and,  333-35;  immi¬ gration  policies  of,  270;  income  in¬ equality  in,  194;  inequality  measures in,  93t;  Keynesianism  and,  2, 15;  poor children  in,  249-50;  social  policy challenges  in,  245-50;  unemploy¬ ment  policies  in,  92,  260;  unions  in, 100-102.  See  also  Socialdemokratiska Arbetareparti Switzerland,  59-60;  social  democrats  of, 53t,  6it,  63t;  as  social  market  econ¬ omy,  90 Tangentopoli  scandals,  17 “Tea  Party”  activists,  184-85 Teixeira,  Ruy,  21, 162-85,  349.  397 telecommunications  industry,  104-5 Temporary  Assistance  for  Needy  Fami¬ lies  (TANF),  191,  201.  See  also  welfare policies 412  Index terrorism,  206;  Blair  on,  132, 138;  Bush on,  164, 179;  immigration  policies and,  269;  September  11  attacks  and, 133-34. 138, 162 Thatcher,  Margaret,  132-33, 139,  251, 348-49;  deregulation  by,  106, 107, 333;  election  of,  6, 122, 124,  339  n.  5; European  Monetary  System  and,  323, 324;  immigration  policies  of,  277;  neo¬ liberalism  of,  15, 118-19,  303 Thelen,  Kathleen,  102, 108 Therborn,  Goran,  25  n.  4 Third  Way,  15,  69-70,  76,  348;  Blair  and Schroder  on,  116, 136,  243-44,  258, 260,  262  n.  7;  European  integration and,  334;  in  Hungary,  300;  ideological coherence  of,  34-35,  76, 136;  reforms of,  26  n.  8,  69-70;  in  Slovakia,  306; in  Sweden,  245.  See  also  New  Labour Party Tory  Party,  133,  250;  in  election  of  1992, 121;  in  election  of  2010,  34, 137, 138, 348;  financial  policies  of,  122, 126; trade  unions  and,  120, 124-25, 127 Trade  Adjustment  Assistance  (TAA),  212, 215,  217,  226,  230,  231 trade  policies,  210;  of  Bush,  225-28;  of Clinton,  211,  219-25;  development  of, 214-19;  of  Obama,  22, 183,  212-13, 228-33;  protectionist,  214-15;  “spe¬ cific  factors”  model  of,  233  n.  2; strategies  for,  213-14 trade  promotion  authority  (TPA),  225-28 Trans  Pacific  Partnership,  229 trente  glorieuses,  141, 144,  261 Truman,  Harry  S.,  174,  214 Turkish  immigrants,  273-75 unemployment,  92-94,  242;  child poverty  and,  252;  in  Czech  Republic, 317  n.  12;  in  European  Union,  244, 327-29,  334,  340  n.  19;  in  France, 143-45, 150-54;  globalization  and, 208  n.  22;  immigration  policies  and, 265-68,  282-83;  New  Labour’s  pro¬ grams  for,  125-28,  253-56;  in  Nordic countries,  110,  mt,  114  n.  8,  245-48, 257,  260;  during  Obama’s  presidency, 184, 185;  part-time  jobs  and,  108-10, 257;  stagflation  and,  177-78;  Trade Adjustment  Assistance  for,  215;  U.S. welfare  reform  and,  196,  253,  349; youth  programs  for,  151, 153, 154,  248, 258 Union  pour  la  Democratic  Franchise (UDF),  146 unions,  4,  94,  loit,  188,  335;  Democratic Party  and,  171-72, 175,  215,  219,  224, 226-27,  229;  flexible  work  forces  and, 14, 15,  92-94, 106, 145,  333;  immi¬ grant  workers  and,  282-83,  288  n.  20; Labour  Party  and,  123-25;  member¬ ship  rates  in,  10,  95,  loit,  113,  347;  in Nordic  countries,  92-95, 100-102; Republican  Party  and,  226-27;  Tory Party  and,  120, 124-25, 127 United  Kingdom,  15,  347-49,  351,  354; childcare  policies  in,  251-56,  260, 283;  deregulation  in,  106, 107;  Euro¬ pean  Economic  Community  and,  339 n.  2;  European  Monetary  System  and, 323,  324;  foreign  residents  in,  270; immigration  policies  of,  131,  269-72, 276-78,  280-83,  286,  288  n.  16;  in¬ come  inequality  in,  194;  as  liberal market  economy,  114  n.  2;  poor  chil¬ dren  in,  251-55,  262  n.  2;  social  demo¬ crats  of,  52-79;  social  policy  chal¬ lenges  in,  250-56;  stagflation  in,  322. See  also  Labour  Party United  States,  348,  349,  351,  354;  China trade  policies  of,  211,  221,  224-29; economic  growth  in,  i03-5t;  employ¬ ment  trends  in,  108-10,  mt;  excep- tionalism  of,  21,  25  n.  7, 189,  234  n.  9; globalization  policies  of,  210-33;  high technology  in,  104-5;  immigration policies  of,  21,  201;  income  inequality in,  194;  inequality  measures  in,  93b, poor  children  in,  262  n.  2;  unioniza- Index  413 tion  rates  in,  loit;  Washington  Con¬ sensus  and,  7;  welfare  reform  in,  126- 27, 188-206 utopianism,  7,  9,  39,  352 varieties  of  capitalism  (VofC),  8,  96, 98-102,  232,  237  n.  30 Vedrine,  Hubert,  353 Velvet  Revolution  (1989),  301-2 Venezuela,  8 Vietnam  War,  349;  asylum  seekers  from, 273;  U.S.  movement  against,  176, 177 Villepin,  Dominique  de,  154 Walesa,  Lech,  296 Washington  consensus,  7 Weiss,  Peter,  301,  305 welfare  policies,  59,  62-64,  80-81, 192-95,  201,  262  n.  1,  343-44;  of  Blair, 254-55;  of  Clinton,  127, 178-79, 191, 204,  349;  food  stamps  and,  190, 191, 206,  274;  of  Johnson,  176, 190, 199, 349;  Keynesianism  and,  5,  72,  321; literature  on,  25  n.  8;  of  Nordic  coun¬ tries,  6,  89-113,  339  n.  2;  of  Roosevelt, 3, 17, 174-77, 190,  214,  349;  U.S.  party politics  and,  189-90, 196-206;  work- fare  and,  196,  253,  349 Westminster  model,  130 Wilson,  Harold,  6,  72, 124, 140  n.  2, 276-77 women:  in  Democratic  Party,  166, 176, 177;  as  immigrants,  281-83;  rights  of, 11,  244,  246-49;  as  single  parents,  13, 23, 166-67,  246-49,  253,  254;  wage ratios  for,  93t,  95;  working,  22-23, 108-10,  259,  261 workfare,  196,  253,  349 Working  Families  Tax  Credit  (UK),  127, 254 World  Bank,  7 World  Economic  Forum,  105-6 World  Trade  Organization  (WTO),  7,  221, 225 Wren,  Anne,  115  n.  14 youth  job  programs,  151, 153, 154,  248, 258 Yugoslavia,  133, 140  n.  6,  271,  272,  304, 340  n.  21 Zapatero,  Jose  Luis,  279,  281,  283,  357, 360 Zhelev,  Zhelyu,  310-11 Zhivkov,  Todor,  310 JAMES  CRONIN  is  a  professor  of  history  at  Boston  College. GEORGE  ROSS  is  ad  personam  Chaire  Jean  Monnet  at  the  University  of  Montreal. JAMES  SHOCH  is  an  associate  professor  in  the  Department  of  Government  at California  State  University,  Sacramento. Library  of  Congress  Cataloging-in-Publication  Data What’s  left  of  the  left :  Democrats  and  Social  Democrats  in  challenging  times  / edited  by  James  Cronin,  George  Ross,  and  James  Shoch. p.  cm. Includes  bibliographical  references  and  index. ISBN  978-0-8223-5061-3  (cloth  :  alk.  paper)  — ISBN  978-0-8223-5079-8  (pbk.  :  alk.  paper) 1.  Political  parties— United  States— History.  2.  Political  parties— Europe— History. 3.  Right  and  left  (Political  science)  4.  Globalization— Political  aspects.  I.  Cronin, James  E.  II.  Ross,  George,  1940-  III.  Shoch,  James. JF2011.W438  2011 324.2'i7094  — dc22 2011006368 ..■diiji’i’isSiSiPwi i&g£Ssg£j ISBN  13:  978- 0-8223-  5061-  3 AC99Z0St70a >: i&SittSiiC ••  ■ saueiqn  AjjsjaAiun  a>ina S'5Saec2352Sl3

[8]ページ先頭

©2009-2025 Movatter.jp