In 1956, "he joined theRAND Corporation as an adjunct fellow, becoming a full-time researcher for a year after leaving Yale, and returning to adjunct status through 2002."[5] In 1958 Schelling was appointed professor of economics at Harvard. That same year, he "co-founded the Center for International Affairs, which was [later] renamed theWeatherhead Center for International Affairs."[6]
In 1969, Schelling joined Harvard'sJohn F. Kennedy School of Government, where he was the Lucius N. Littauer Professor of Political Economy.[4] He was among the "founding fathers" of the "modern" Kennedy School, as he helped to shift the curriculum's emphasis away from administration and more toward leadership.[6]
Schelling was married to Corinne Tigay Saposs from 1947 to 1991, with whom he had four sons. Later in 1991 he married Alice M. Coleman, who brought two sons to the marriage; they became his stepsons.[14][15]
Schelling died on December 13, 2016, inBethesda, Maryland, from complications following a hip fracture at the age of 95.[7]
Schelling's family auctioned his Nobel award medal, fetching $187,000. They donated this money to theSouthern Poverty Law Center, an American 501 nonprofit legal advocacy organization specializing in civil rights and public interest litigation. Alice Schelling said her late husband had creditedSmoky the Cowhorse byWill James, the winner of theNewbery Medal in 1927, as the most influential book he had read.[16]
The Strategy of Conflict, which Schelling published in 1960,[17] pioneered the study of bargaining andstrategic behavior in what he refers to as "conflict behavior."[18]The Times Literary Supplement in 1995 ranked it as one of the 100 most influential books in the 50 years since 1945.[19] In this book Schelling introduced concepts such as the"focal point" and "credible commitment." In a 1961 review, International Relations scholarMorton Kaplan described the book as a "strikingly original contribution" and a "landmark in the literature."[20]
Schelling's book comprised a series of scholarly journal articles that he had published over the period 1957–1960.[20]
Schelling encourages in his work a strategic view toward conflict that is equally "rational" and "successful."[17] He believes that conflict cannot be based merely on one's intelligence but must also address the "advantages" associated with a course of action. He considers that the advantages that are gleaned should be firmly fixed in a value system that is both "explicit" and "consistent."[17]
Also, conflict has a distinct meaning. In Schelling's approach, it is not enough to defeat an opponent, but one must also seize opportunities to co-operate of which there are usually many. He points out that it is only on the rarest of occasions, in what is known as "pure conflict," that the participants' interests are implacably opposed.[17] He uses the example of "a war of complete extermination" to illustrate this phenomenon.[17]
Co-operation, if available, may take many forms and thus potentially involve everything from "deterrence, limited war, and disarmament" to "negotiation."[17] Indeed, it is through such actions that participants are left with less of a conflict and more of a "bargaining situation."[17] The bargaining itself is best thought of in terms of the other participant's actions, as any gains one might realize are highly dependent upon the "choices or decisions" of their opponent.[17]
Communication between parties, though, is another matter entirely. Verbal or written communication is known as "explicit," and involves such activities as "offering concessions."[17] What happens, though, when this type of communication becomes impossible or improbable? This is when something called "tacit maneuvers" become important.[17] Think of this as action-based communication. Schelling uses the example of one's occupation or evacuation of strategic territory to illustrate this latter communication method.
In an article celebrating Schelling's Nobel Memorial Prize for Economics,[21]Michael Kinsley,Washington Postop‑ed columnist and one of Schelling's former students, anecdotally summarizes Schelling's reorientation of game theory thus: "[Y]ou're standing at the edge of a cliff, chained by the ankle to someone else. You'll be released, and one of you will get a large prize, as soon as the other gives in. How do you persuade the other guy to give in, when the only method at your disposal—threatening to push him off the cliff—would doom you both? Answer: You start dancing, closer and closer to the edge. That way, you don't have to convince him that you would do something totally irrational: plunge him and yourself off the cliff. You just have to convince him that you are prepared to take a higher risk than he is of accidentally falling off the cliff. If you can do that, you win."
Schelling's theories about war were extended inArms and Influence, published in 1966.[22][23] According to the publisher, the book "carries forward the analysis so brilliantly begun in his earlierThe Strategy of Conflict (1960) andStrategy and Arms Control (withMorton Halperin, 1961), and makes a significant contribution to the growing literature on modern war anddiplomacy." Chapter headings includeThe Diplomacy of Violence,The Diplomacy of Ultimate Survival andThe Dynamics of Mutual Alarm.
Within the work, Schelling discusses military capabilities and how they can be used as bargaining power. Instead of considering only the choices that are available on a surface level, one can think ahead to try to influence the other party to come to the desired conclusion. Specifically, Schelling mentions the actions taken by the U.S. during the Cuban and Berlin crises and how they functioned as not only preparation for war but also signals. For example, Schelling points out that the bombing of North Vietnam "is as much coercive as tactical."[24] Not only was the bombing to cripple their enemies armies, but it also served to bring Vietnam to the table for negotiations. Much of this writing was influenced largely due to Schelling's personal interest in Game Theory and its application to nuclear armaments.
In 1969 and 1971, Schelling published widely cited articles dealing withracial dynamics and what he termed "a general theory oftipping."[27] In those papers, he showed that a preference that one's neighbors be of the same color, or even a preference for a mixture "up to some limit," can lead to totalsegregation. He thus argued that motives, malicious or not, were indistinguishable as to explaining the phenomenon of complete local separation of distinct groups. He used coins on graph paper to demonstrate his theory by placing pennies and dimes in different patterns on the "board" and then moving them one by one if they were in an "unhappy" situation.[citation needed]
Schelling's dynamics has been cited as a way of explaining variations that are found in what are regarded as meaningful differences – gender, age, race, ethnicity, language, sexual preference, and religion. A cycle of such change, once it has begun, may have a self-sustaining momentum. Schelling's 1978 bookMicromotives and Macrobehavior expanded on and generalized those themes[28][29] and is often cited in the literature ofagent-based computational economics.
Schelling was involved in theglobal warming debate since chairing a commission for PresidentJimmy Carter in 1980. He believedclimate change poses a serious threat to developing nations, but that the threat to the United States was exaggerated. He wrote that,
Today, little of ourgross domestic product is produced outdoors, and therefore, little is susceptible to climate. Agriculture and forestry are less than 3 percent of total output, and little else is much affected. Even ifagricultural productivity declined by a third over the next half-century, the per capita GNP we might have achieved by 2050 we would still achieve in 2051. Considering that agricultural productivity in most parts of the world continues to improve (and that many crops may benefit directly from enhancedphotosynthesis due to increasedcarbon dioxide), it is not at all certain that the net impact on agriculture will be negative or much noticed in thedeveloped world.[30]
Drawing on his experience with theMarshall Plan afterWorld War II, he argued that addressing global warming is abargaining problem: if the world were able to reduce emissions, poor countries would receive most of the benefits, but rich countries would bear most of the costs.
^Schelling, Thomas C. (2007)."Greenhouse Effect". In Henderson, David R. (ed.).Concise Encyclopedia of Economics (1st ed.). Library of Economics and Liberty. RetrievedDecember 7, 2017.
^Thomas C. Schelling, 2006 prologue to 'Meteors, Mischief, and War', inStrategies of commitment and other essays, Harvard University Press, 2006.
^Schelling, T. C. (1961). "INFORMS PubsOnline".Operations Research.9 (3):363–370.doi:10.1287/opre.9.3.363.
^Schelling, Thomas C., 1921–2016. (1984).Choice and consequence. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.ISBN0674127706.OCLC9893879.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)