Movatterモバイル変換


[0]ホーム

URL:


Jump to content
WikipediaThe Free Encyclopedia
Search

Debt: The First 5,000 Years

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Redirected fromDebt: The First 5000 Years)
2011 book by David Graeber

Debt: The First 5,000 Years
AuthorDavid Graeber
LanguageEnglish
PublisherMelville House
Publication date
2011
Pages534
ISBN978-1-933633-86-2
OCLC426794447

Debt: The First 5,000 Years is a book byanthropologistDavid Graeber published in 2011. It explores the historical relationship ofdebt with social institutions such asbarter,marriage,friendship,slavery,law,religion,war andgovernment. It draws on the history and anthropology of a number of civilizations, large and small, from the first known records of debt fromSumer in 3500BCE until the present. Reception of the book was mixed, with praise for Graeber's sweeping scope from earliest recorded history to the present; others criticizedDebt due to the book's interpretations of certain events and works.

Premises

[edit]

A major argument of the book is that the imprecise, informal, community-building indebtedness of "human economies" is only replaced by mathematically precise, firmly enforced debts through the introduction ofviolence, usuallystate-sponsored violence in some form of military or police. A second major argument of the book is that, contrary to standard accounts of thehistory of money, debt is probably the oldest means oftrade, with cash andbarter transactions being later developments. The book argues that debt has typically retained its primacy, with cash and barter usually limited to situations of lowtrust involving strangers or those not consideredcredit-worthy. Graeber proposes that the second argument follows from the first; that, in his words, "markets are founded and usually maintained by systematic state violence", though he goes on to show how "in the absence of such violence, they... can even come to be seen as the very basis of freedom and autonomy".[1]

Synopsis

[edit]

Graeber lays out the historical development of the idea of debt, starting from the first recorded debt systems in theSumer civilization around 3500 BCE. In this early form of borrowing and lending, farmers would often become so mired in debt that their children would be forced intodebt peonage. Because of the social tension that came with this enslavement of large parts of the population, kings periodically canceled all debts. In ancient Israel, the resulting amnesty came to be known as the Law ofJubilee.

Graeber argues thatdebt andcredit historically appeared beforemoney, which itself appeared beforebarter. This is the opposite of the narrative given in standard economics texts dating back toAdam Smith. To support this, he cites numerous historical, ethnographic and archaeological studies. He also claims that the standard economics texts cite no evidence for suggesting that barter came before money, credit and debt, and he has seen no credible reports suggesting such.

The primary theme of the book is that excessive popular indebtedness has sometimes led to unrest, insurrection, and revolt. He argues that credit systems originally developed as means of account long before the advent ofcoinage, which appeared around 600 BCE. Credit can still be seen operating in non-monetary economies. Barter, on the other hand, seems primarily to have been used for limited exchanges between different societies that had infrequent contact and often were in a context ofritualized warfare.

Graeber suggests that economic life originally related tosocial currencies. These were closely related to routine non-market interactions within a community. This created an "everyday communism" based on mutual expectations and responsibilities among individuals. This type of economy is contrasted with exchange based on formal equality and reciprocity (but not necessarily leading to market relations) and hierarchy. The hierarchies in turn tended to institutionalize inequalities in customs and castes.

The greatAxial Age civilizations (800 BCE–600 CE) began to use coins to quantify the economic values of portions of what Graeber calls "human economies". Graeber says these civilizations held a radically different conception of debt and social relations. These were based on the radical incalculability of human life and the constant creation and recreation of social bonds through gifts, marriages, and general sociability. The author postulates the growth of a "military–coinage–slave complex" around this time. These were enforced by mercenary armies that looted cities and cut human beings from their social context to work as slaves in Greece, Rome, and elsewhere. The extreme violence of the period marked by the rise of great empires in China, India, and the Mediterranean was, in this way, connected with the advent of large-scale slavery and the use of coins to pay soldiers. This was combined with obligations to pay taxes in currency; the obligation to pay taxes with money required people to engage in monetary transactions, often with very disadvantageous terms of trade. This typically increased debt and slavery. At this time, great religions also spread, and the general questions of philosophical inquiry emerged in world history. These included discussions of debt and its relation to ethics (e.g.,Plato'sRepublic).

When the great empires in Rome and India collapsed, the resulting checkerboard of small kingdoms and republics saw a gradual decline in standing armies and cities. This included the creation of hierarchical caste systems, the retreat of gold and silver to the temples and theabolition of slavery. Although hard currency was no longer used in everyday life, its use as a unit of account and credit continued inmedieval Europe. Graeber insists that people in theMiddle Ages in Europe continued to use the concept of money, even though they no longer had the physical symbols. This contradicts the popular claims of economists that the Middle Ages saw the economy "revert to barter". During the Middle Ages more sophisticated financial instruments appeared. These includedpromissory notes andpaper money (in China, where the empire managed to survive the collapse observed elsewhere),letters of credit, andcheques (in the Islamic world).[2]

The emergence of theAtlantic slave trade and the massive amounts of gold and silver extracted from the Americas—most of which ended up inEast Asia, especially China—stimulated the reemergence of thebullion economy and large-scale military violence. All of these developments, according to Graeber, directly intertwined with the earlier expansion of theItalian mercantile city-states as centers of finance that defied the Catholic Church's ban on usury and led to the current age of great capitalist empires. As the new continent opened new possibilities for gain, it also created a new area for adventurous militarism backed by debts that required the economic exploitation of the Amerindian and, later, West African populations. As it did, cities again flourished in the European continent and capitalism advanced to encompass larger areas of the globe when European trade companies and military outposts disrupted local markets and pushed for colonial monopolies.

The bullion economy ended with theabandonment of thegold standard by the U.S. government in 1971. This return tocredit money increased uncertainties. For the moment, the dollar still stands as the primaryworld currency. This status of the dollar (as with all money) is based on its capacity to extend itsquantity through debts and deficits and, more importantly, by the unrestrained authority of theFederal Reserve tocreate money, which has enabled the USA to create a 21 trilliondollar debt by 2018. This may continue as long as (a) the United States maintains its status as the world's pre-eminent military power and (b) client states are eager to payseignorage for U.S.government bonds. By comparing the evolution of debt in our times to other historical eras and different societies, the author suggests that modern debt crises are not the inevitable product of history and must be resolved in the near future in a way similar to the solutions, at least in principle, as applied during the last 5000 years.[3]

Concept of "everyday communism"

[edit]
See also:Primitive communism,Original affluent society, andGift economy

InDebt: The First 5,000 Years, Graeber proposes a concept of "everyday communism" which he defines as situational behavior that conforms to the logic of 'from each according to their ability, to each according to their needs.' When analysing peasant lives, he writes: "The peasants' visions of communistic brotherhood did not come out of nowhere. They were rooted in real daily experience: of the maintenance of common fields and forests, of everyday cooperation and neighborly solidarity. It is out of such homely experience of everyday communism that grand mythic visions are always built".[4]: 326  Also, "society was rooted above in the 'love and amity' of friends and kin, and it found expression in all those forms of everyday communism (helping neighbors with chores, providing milk or cheese for old widows) that were seen to flow from it".[4]: 330 

Closer to home, he gives this example: "If someone fixing a broken water pipe says, 'Hand me the wrench,' his co-worker will not, generally speaking, say, 'And what do I get for it?' ... The reason is simple efficiency... : if you really care about getting something done, the most efficient way to go about it is obviously to allocate tasks by ability and give people whatever they need to do them."[4]: 95–96  Moreover, we tend to ask and give without thinking for things like asking directions, or

small courtesies like asking for a light, or even for a cigarette. It seems more legitimate to ask a stranger for a cigarette than for an equivalent amount of cash, or even food; in fact, if one has been identified as a fellow smoker, it's rather difficult to refuse such a request. In such cases—a match, a piece of information, holding the elevator—one might say the "from each" element is so minimal that most of us comply without even thinking about it. Conversely, the same is true if another person's need—even a stranger's—is particularly spectacular or extreme: if he is drowning, for example. If a child has fallen onto the subway tracks, we assume that anyone who is capable of helping her up will do so.[4]: 97 

The thing which makes it "everyday" is this argument: "communism is the foundation of all human sociability. It is what makes society possible. There is always an assumption that anyone who is not actually an enemy can be expected to act on the principle of "from each according to their abilities", at least to an extent,[4]: 96  which is to say, the extent just described. He proposes studying these practices and says that the "sociology of everyday communism is a potentially enormous field, but one which, owing to our peculiar ideological blinders, we have been unable to write about because we have been largely unable to see it".[4]: 101  Nevertheless, Graeber's ideas were later discussed by journalist Richard Swift as being a type of "a reciprocal economy"— which makes use of the "ethic of reciprocity" or the "Golden Rule".[5]

Publication

[edit]

Graeber recounted the book's publisher,Melville House, contacting him in 2007, prior tothe financial collapse, as an author who could have public appeal.[6] The Brooklyn-based independent publisher[7] was excited to hear about his work on the topic of debt, and Graeber was enticed at the prospect of writing for a broader audience than his activist and anthropologist peers, to influence a larger debate.[6] Melville House initially planned for a short book on the economy, which grew into a comprehensive exploration of financial relations. Melville House felt that an anthropologist and his knowledge of human impact would fulfill a missing need in the public dialogues on global finance.[8]

Graeber sought to apply anthropological research on human experience to contemporary issues—a practice, he has said, anthropologists abandoned. Graeber also wanted to expose "false views of money", such as debt as azero-sum resource. For instance, alternative to the understanding that debt cancellation requires taxpayers to bail out other sectors, debt can instead be made unenforceable and thus cancelled without countermeasure, as in his recommended jubilee.[9] The author intended the book's subtitle—"The First 5,000 Years"—as a provocation. He felt that the economic order at the time of publication was untenable and likely to change within one or two generations.[10]

Keith Hart was Graeber's foremost influence in writingDebt. Hart, among the first anthropologists to discussheterodox economics, distinguished between bullion and credit theories of money, and how money, paradoxically, is both. Atop this analysis, Graeber added historical examples of societies shifting between both uses.[6]

Intellectually, Graeber also saw himself as reconciling the traditions ofKarl Marx andMarcel Mauss. The Marxist tradition, as he puts it, is about seeing how all things fit into a totality based on exploitation, but as a perspective, it risks making its adherents into cynics overcome by powerlessness. Alternatively, in Graeber's description of the Maussian tradition of cooperativism, all social possibilities are present—including democracy, dictatorship, oligarchy, individualism, and communism at once—and reinforce rather than contradict each other.[11]

Debt was released in July 2011 and was a success for its publisher.[7] By December,Debt was in its sixth printing, with growing demand. Its release coincided with "debt crisis" newspaper headlines for theUnited States Congress debt ceiling standoff and, two months later,Occupy Wall Street, in which the author was a major figure. Print sales outpaced ebook sales, and the former were especially popular in independent bookstores. When chain buyers hesitated at the author's obscurity and the book's intellectual and political content, Melville House opted for "underground" publicity through the Internet. Leading blogs, such as the economic blogNaked Capitalism, broughtDebt enough visibility to catch the attention of mainstream outlets.[8] The book was translated first to German,[12] and subsequently into Spanish, French, Italian, Portuguese, Russian, Chinese, Dutch, and Slovenian.[13]

Reception

[edit]

The book won the inauguralBread and Roses Award for radical literature,[14] and the 2012 Bateson Award of the American Society for Cultural Anthropology.[15]

JournalistRobert Kuttner in theNew York Review of Books called the book "an encyclopedic survey ... an authoritative account of the background tothe recent crisis ... an exhaustive, engaging, and occasionally exasperating book."[16] Journalist and activistRaj Patel ofThe Globe and Mail said, "This is a big book of big ideas: Within its 500 pages, you’ll find a theory of capitalism, religion, the state, world history and money, with evidence reaching back more than 5,000 years, from the Inuit to the Aztecs, the Mughals to the Mongols.”[17] JournalistGillian Tett of theFinancial Times compared the book to the works ofMarcel Mauss,Karl Polanyi, andKeith Hart.[18]

Economist Julio Huato, associate professor of economics atSt. Francis College, writing inScience & Society cited some of the book's contradictions, such as Graeber's claim in p. 21, that money and debt appeared simultaneously, and his claim in p. 40, that money and debt did not appear simultaneously and that debt appeared first.[19] He also stated that, contrary to Graeber's claims, the "myth ofbarter" – i.e. the hypothesis that the accidental direct exchange of quasi-commodities predated money historically – is not an absurd fantasy.[19] Huato concluded by asserting that several other of Graeber's claims in the book, such as the claim that violent dispossession is the "secret scandal" ofmodern capitalism, are problematic.[19]

Jeffrey Rogers Hummel, a professor of economics atSan Jose State University and an adjunct scholar at the American libertarian think-tankCato Institute,[20] found several "serious conceptual confusions" in the book. For example, Hummel said that Graeber likely confused theAustrian school economistCarl Menger with his son, the mathematicianKarl Menger, which led to erroneous statements and accusations against the former, such as that he supposedly added "variousmathematical equations" to economics and that he came up with the term "transaction costs".[21] Hummel also contended that the book's tone is overly polemical and that it is "riddled with errors and distortions".[21] EconomistGeorge Selgin, aprofessor emeritus of economics at theTerry College of Business at theUniversity of Georgia and a fellow at the Cato Institute,[22] echoed similar criticisms, adding that Graeber had not read Menger at all, and that his reading ofAdam Smith was ungenerous.[23] According to Selgin, the foundation upon which Graeber's evaluation ofmodern economics andcommercial society rests is severely flawed.[23]

The book was reviewed by way of a debate in thesocialist magazineJacobin. In the first review, economist Mike Beggs, a lecturer inpolitical economy at theUniversity of Sydney, wrote that while "there is a lot of fantastic material in there", he "found the main arguments wholly unconvincing ... Graeber is a wonderful storyteller. But the accumulation of anecdotes does not add up to an explanation, and certainly not one that would overturn the existing wisdom on the subject, conventional or otherwise".[24] In response, economist J. W. Mason, anassociate professor of economics atJohn Jay College, defended the book. He noted that the book's "key themes are in close harmony with the main themes ofheterodox economics work going back toKeynes [economics]", and that while it is "no substitute forMarx,Keynes andSchumpeter, forMinsky andLeijonhufvud, forHenwood andMehrling ... it is a fine complement."[25]

References

[edit]
  1. ^"Seminar on Debt: The First 5000 Years – Reply". April 2, 2012.
  2. ^According to Graeber, some of the "Western" tradition on free market and commerce outside of governmental intervention described byAdam Smith repeats almost verbatim the words of Islamic, Persian scholars likeNasir al-Din al-Tusi andAl-Ghazali, and Smith had Latin translations of some of their works in his library.Hilder, Trevor E. (August 8, 2012),Book Review: "Debt - The First 5,000 Years" by David Graeber, Muslim Heritage, retrievedMay 26, 2014
  3. ^Meaney, Thomas (December 8, 2011)."Anarchist Anthropology".The New York Times Book Review.The New York Times Company. pp. BR47. RetrievedDecember 11, 2011.
  4. ^abcdefGraeber, David (2011).Debt: The First 5,000 Years. Brooklyn, NY: Melville House Printing.ISBN 978-1612191294.
  5. ^Swift, Richard."Pathways & possibilities".New Internationalist.484 (July/August 2015). RetrievedAugust 15, 2015.
  6. ^abcAppel 2014, p. 168.
  7. ^abDeahl 2011.
  8. ^abHabash 2011.
  9. ^Houtman, Gustaaf (October 2012). "The Occupy Movement and Debt: An Interview with David Graeber".Anthropology Today.28 (5):17–18.doi:10.1111/j.1467-8322.2012.00898.x.ISSN 1467-8322.
  10. ^Lateu, Jo (February 1, 2014). "David Graeber".New Internationalist (469): 46.ISSN 0305-9529.
  11. ^Appel 2014, p. 170.
  12. ^Appel 2014, p. 169.
  13. ^
  14. ^Alison Flood (March 6, 2012)."New prize for radical writing announces shortlist".The Guardian. London. RetrievedMay 2, 2012.
  15. ^"David Graeber Awarded the 2012 Bateson Prize".Cultural Anthropology. Archived fromthe original on March 3, 2014. RetrievedAugust 24, 2013.
  16. ^Robert Kuttner (May 9, 2013)."The Debt We Shouldn't Pay".The New York Review of Book. New York. RetrievedMay 25, 2014.
  17. ^Raj Patel (May 3, 2018)."A key to unlock the door of debtor's prison".The Globe and Mail. Toronto. RetrievedJune 16, 2019.
  18. ^Gillian Tett, “Debt: it’s back to the future”,Financial Times (9 September 2011). Retrieved 13 November 2011.
  19. ^abcHuato, Julio (2015)."Graeber's Debt: When a Wealth of Facts Confronts a Poverty of Theory".Science & Society.79 (2):318–325.doi:10.1521/siso.2015.79.2.318.ISSN 0036-8237.
  20. ^"Jeffrey Rogers Hummel".Cato Institute. RetrievedApril 18, 2023.
  21. ^abHenderson, David (2012) "Hummel on Graeber".Liberty Fund.
  22. ^"George Selgin".Cato Institute. RetrievedApril 18, 2023.
  23. ^abSelgin, George (2016)."The Myth of the Myth of Barter".Alt-M. RetrievedAugust 28, 2022.
  24. ^Mike Beggs (August 2012)."Debt: The first 500 pages".Jacobin Magazine. RetrievedMay 25, 2014.
  25. ^J. W. Mason (September 2012)."In Defense of David Graeber's Debt".Jacobin Magazine. RetrievedNovember 10, 2015.

Bibliography

[edit]

External links

[edit]
Bibliography
Related
International
National
Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Debt:_The_First_5,000_Years&oldid=1276156514"
Categories:
Hidden categories:

[8]ページ先頭

©2009-2025 Movatter.jp