Movatterモバイル変換


[0]ホーム

URL:


Jump to content
WikipediaThe Free Encyclopedia
Search

Consumer-resource model

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Class of ecological models

Intheoretical ecology andnonlinear dynamics,consumer-resource models (CRMs) are a class ofecological models in which acommunity of consumer species compete for a common pool of resources. Instead of species interacting directly, all species-species interactions are mediated through resource dynamics. Consumer-resource models have served as fundamental tools in the quantitative development of theories ofniche construction,coexistence, andbiological diversity. These models can be interpreted as a quantitative description of a singletrophic level.[1][2]

A general consumer-resource model consists ofM resources whose abundances areR1,,RM{\displaystyle R_{1},\dots ,R_{M}} andS consumer species whose populations areN1,,NS{\displaystyle N_{1},\dots ,N_{S}}. A general consumer-resource model is described by the system of coupled ordinary differential equations,dNidt=Nigi(R1,,RM),i=1,,S,dRαdt=fα(R1,,RM,N1,,NS),α=1,,M{\displaystyle {\begin{aligned}{\frac {\mathrm {d} N_{i}}{\mathrm {d} t}}&=N_{i}g_{i}(R_{1},\dots ,R_{M}),&&\qquad i=1,\dots ,S,\\{\frac {\mathrm {d} R_{\alpha }}{\mathrm {d} t}}&=f_{\alpha }(R_{1},\dots ,R_{M},N_{1},\dots ,N_{S}),&&\qquad \alpha =1,\dots ,M\end{aligned}}}wheregi{\displaystyle g_{i}}, depending only on resource abundances, is the per-capita growth rate of speciesi{\displaystyle i}, andfα{\displaystyle f_{\alpha }} is the growth rate of resourceα{\displaystyle \alpha }. An essential feature of CRMs is that species growth rates and populations are mediated through resources and there are no explicit species-species interactions. Through resource interactions, there areemergent inter-species interactions.

Originally introduced byRobert H. MacArthur[3] andRichard Levins,[4] consumer-resource models have found success in formalizing ecological principles and modeling experiments involving microbial ecosystems.[5][6]

Models

[edit]

Niche models

[edit]

Niche models are a notable class of CRMs which are described by the system of coupled ordinary differential equations,[7][8]

dNidt=Nigi(R),i=1,,S,dRαdt=hα(R)+i=1SNiqiα(R),α=1,,M,{\displaystyle {\begin{aligned}{\frac {\mathrm {d} N_{i}}{\mathrm {d} t}}&=N_{i}g_{i}(\mathbf {R} ),&&\qquad i=1,\dots ,S,\\{\frac {\mathrm {d} R_{\alpha }}{\mathrm {d} t}}&=h_{\alpha }(\mathbf {R} )+\sum _{i=1}^{S}N_{i}q_{i\alpha }(\mathbf {R} ),&&\qquad \alpha =1,\dots ,M,\end{aligned}}}

whereR(R1,,RM){\displaystyle \mathbf {R} \equiv (R_{1},\dots ,R_{M})} is a vector abbreviation for resource abundances,gi{\displaystyle g_{i}} is the per-capita growth rate of speciesi{\displaystyle i},hα{\displaystyle h_{\alpha }} is the growth rate of speciesα{\displaystyle \alpha } in the absence of consumption, andqiα{\displaystyle -q_{i\alpha }} is the rate per unit species population that speciesi{\displaystyle i} depletes the abundance of resourceα{\displaystyle \alpha } through consumption. In this class of CRMs, consumer species' impacts on resources are not explicitly coordinated; however, there are implicit interactions.

MacArthur consumer-resource model (MCRM)

[edit]

The MacArthur consumer-resource model (MCRM), named afterRobert H. MacArthur, is a foundational CRM for the development of niche and coexistence theories.[9][10] The MCRM is given by the following set of coupled ordinary differential equations:[11][12][8]dNidt=τi1Ni(α=1MwαciαRαmi),i=1,,S,dRαdt=rαKα(KαRα)Rαi=1SNiciαRα,α=1,,M,{\displaystyle {\begin{aligned}{\frac {\mathrm {d} N_{i}}{\mathrm {d} t}}&=\tau _{i}^{-1}N_{i}\left(\sum _{\alpha =1}^{M}w_{\alpha }c_{i\alpha }R_{\alpha }-m_{i}\right),&&\qquad i=1,\dots ,S,\\{\frac {\mathrm {d} R_{\alpha }}{\mathrm {d} t}}&={\frac {r_{\alpha }}{K_{\alpha }}}\left(K_{\alpha }-R_{\alpha }\right)R_{\alpha }-\sum _{i=1}^{S}N_{i}c_{i\alpha }R_{\alpha },&&\qquad \alpha =1,\dots ,M,\end{aligned}}}whereciα{\displaystyle c_{i\alpha }} is the relative preference of speciesi{\displaystyle i} for resourceα{\displaystyle \alpha } and also the relative amount by which resourceα{\displaystyle \alpha } is depleted by the consumption of consumer speciesi{\displaystyle i};Kα{\displaystyle K_{\alpha }} is the steady-state carrying capacity of resourceα{\displaystyle \alpha } in absence of consumption (i.e., whenciα{\displaystyle c_{i\alpha }} is zero);τi{\displaystyle \tau _{i}} andrα1{\displaystyle r_{\alpha }^{-1}} are time-scales for species and resource dynamics, respectively;wα{\displaystyle w_{\alpha }} is the quality of resourceα{\displaystyle \alpha }; andmi{\displaystyle m_{i}} is the natural mortality rate of speciesi{\displaystyle i}. This model is said to have self-replenishing resource dynamics because whenciα=0{\displaystyle c_{i\alpha }=0}, each resource exhibits independentlogistic growth. Given positive parameters and initial conditions, this model approaches a uniqueuninvadablesteady state (i.e., a steady state in which the re-introduction of a species which has been driven to extinction or a resource which has been depleted leads to the re-introduced species or resource dying out again).[7] Steady states of the MCRM satisfy thecompetitive exclusion principle: the number of coexisting species is less than or equal to the number of non-depleted resources. In other words, the number of simultaneously occupiableecological niches is equal to the number of non-depleted resources.

Externally supplied resources model

[edit]

The externally supplied resource model is similar to the MCRM except the resources are provided at a constant rate from an external source instead of being self-replenished. This model is also sometimes called the linear resource dynamics model. It is described by the following set of coupled ordinary differential equations:[11][8]dNidt=τi1Ni(α=1MwαciαRαmi),i=1,,S,dRαdt=rα(καRα)i=1SNiciαRα,α=1,,M,{\displaystyle {\begin{aligned}{\frac {\mathrm {d} N_{i}}{\mathrm {d} t}}&=\tau _{i}^{-1}N_{i}\left(\sum _{\alpha =1}^{M}w_{\alpha }c_{i\alpha }R_{\alpha }-m_{i}\right),&&\qquad i=1,\dots ,S,\\{\frac {\mathrm {d} R_{\alpha }}{\mathrm {d} t}}&=r_{\alpha }(\kappa _{\alpha }-R_{\alpha })-\sum _{i=1}^{S}N_{i}c_{i\alpha }R_{\alpha },&&\qquad \alpha =1,\dots ,M,\end{aligned}}}where all the parameters shared with the MCRM are the same, andκα{\displaystyle \kappa _{\alpha }} is the rate at which resourceα{\displaystyle \alpha } is supplied to the ecosystem. In the eCRM, in the absence of consumption,Rα{\displaystyle R_{\alpha }} decays toκα{\displaystyle \kappa _{\alpha }} exponentially with timescalerα1{\displaystyle r_{\alpha }^{-1}}. This model is also known as a chemostat model.

Tilman consumer-resource model (TCRM)

[edit]

The Tilman consumer-resource model (TCRM), named afterG. David Tilman, is similar to the externally supplied resources model except the rate at which a species depletes a resource is no longer proportional to the present abundance of the resource. The TCRM is the foundational model for Tilman'sR* rule. It is described by the following set of coupled ordinary differential equations:[8]dNidt=τi1Ni(α=1MwαciαRαmi),i=1,,S,dRαdt=rα(KαRα)i=1SNiciα,α=1,,M,{\displaystyle {\begin{aligned}{\frac {\mathrm {d} N_{i}}{\mathrm {d} t}}&=\tau _{i}^{-1}N_{i}\left(\sum _{\alpha =1}^{M}w_{\alpha }c_{i\alpha }R_{\alpha }-m_{i}\right),&&\qquad i=1,\dots ,S,\\{\frac {\mathrm {d} R_{\alpha }}{\mathrm {d} t}}&=r_{\alpha }(K_{\alpha }-R_{\alpha })-\sum _{i=1}^{S}N_{i}c_{i\alpha },&&\qquad \alpha =1,\dots ,M,\end{aligned}}}where all parameters are shared with the MCRM. In the TCRM, resource abundances can become nonphysically negative.[7]

Microbial consumer-resource model (MiCRM)

[edit]

The microbial consumer resource model describes a microbial ecosystem with externally supplied resources where consumption can produce metabolic byproducts, leading to potentialcross-feeding. It is described by the following set of coupled ODEs:dNidt=τi1Ni(α=1M(1lα)wαciαRαmi),i=1,,S,dRαdt=καrRαi=1SNiciαRα+i=1Sβ=1MNiDαβlβwβwαciβRβ,α=1,,M,{\displaystyle {\begin{aligned}{\frac {\mathrm {d} N_{i}}{\mathrm {d} t}}&=\tau _{i}^{-1}N_{i}\left(\sum _{\alpha =1}^{M}(1-l_{\alpha })w_{\alpha }c_{i\alpha }R_{\alpha }-m_{i}\right),&&\qquad i=1,\dots ,S,\\{\frac {\mathrm {d} R_{\alpha }}{\mathrm {d} t}}&=\kappa _{\alpha }-rR_{\alpha }-\sum _{i=1}^{S}N_{i}c_{i\alpha }R_{\alpha }+\sum _{i=1}^{S}\sum _{\beta =1}^{M}N_{i}D_{\alpha \beta }l_{\beta }{\frac {w_{\beta }}{w_{\alpha }}}c_{i\beta }R_{\beta },&&\qquad \alpha =1,\dots ,M,\end{aligned}}}where all parameters shared with the MCRM have similar interpretations;Dαβ{\displaystyle D_{\alpha \beta }} is the fraction of the byproducts due to consumption of resourceβ{\displaystyle \beta } which are converted to resourceα{\displaystyle \alpha } andlα{\displaystyle l_{\alpha }} is the "leakage fraction" of resourceα{\displaystyle \alpha } governing how much of the resource is released into the environment as metabolic byproducts.[13][8]

Symmetric interactions and optimization

[edit]

MacArthur's Minimization Principle

[edit]

For the MacArthur consumer resource model (MCRM),MacArthur introduced an optimization principle to identify the uninvadable steady state of the model (i.e., the steady state so that if any species with zero population is re-introduced, it will fail to invade, meaning the ecosystem will return to said steady state). To derive the optimization principle, one assumes resource dynamics become sufficiently fast (i.e.,rα1{\displaystyle r_{\alpha }\gg 1}) that they become entrained to species dynamics and are constantly at steady state (i.e.,dRα/dt=0{\displaystyle {\mathrm {d} }R_{\alpha }/{\mathrm {d} }t=0}) so thatRα{\displaystyle R_{\alpha }} is expressed as a function ofNi{\displaystyle N_{i}}. With this assumption, one can express species dynamics as,dNidt=τi1Ni[αMrα1Kαwαciα(rαj=1SNjcjα)mi],{\displaystyle {\frac {\mathrm {d} N_{i}}{\mathrm {d} t}}=\tau _{i}^{-1}N_{i}\left[\sum _{\alpha \in M^{\ast }}r_{\alpha }^{-1}K_{\alpha }w_{\alpha }c_{i\alpha }\left(r_{\alpha }-\sum _{j=1}^{S}N_{j}c_{j\alpha }\right)-m_{i}\right],}whereαM{\displaystyle \sum _{\alpha \in M^{\ast }}} denotes a sum over resource abundances which satisfyRα=rαj=1SNjcjα0{\displaystyle R_{\alpha }=r_{\alpha }-\sum _{j=1}^{S}N_{j}c_{j\alpha }\geq 0}. The above expression can be written asdNi/dt=τi1NiQ/Ni{\displaystyle \mathrm {d} N_{i}/\mathrm {d} t=-\tau _{i}^{-1}N_{i}\,\partial Q/\partial N_{i}}, where,Q({Ni})=12αMrα1Kαwα(rαj=1ScjαNj)2+i=1SmiNi.{\displaystyle Q(\{N_{i}\})={\frac {1}{2}}\sum _{\alpha \in M^{\ast }}r_{\alpha }^{-1}K_{\alpha }w_{\alpha }\left(r_{\alpha }-\sum _{j=1}^{S}c_{j\alpha }N_{j}\right)^{2}+\sum _{i=1}^{S}m_{i}N_{i}.}

At un-invadable steady stateQ/Ni=0{\displaystyle \partial Q/\partial N_{i}=0} for all surviving speciesi{\displaystyle i} andQ/Ni>0{\displaystyle \partial Q/\partial N_{i}>0} for all extinct speciesi{\displaystyle i}.[14][15]

Minimum Environmental Perturbation Principle (MEPP)

[edit]

MacArthur's Minimization Principle has been extended to the more general Minimum Environmental Perturbation Principle (MEPP) which maps certain niche CRM models to constrained optimization problems. When the population growth conferred upon a species by consuming a resource is related to the impact the species' consumption has on the resource's abundance through the equation,qiα(R)=ai(R)bα(R)giRα,{\displaystyle q_{i\alpha }(\mathbf {R} )=-a_{i}(\mathbf {R} )b_{\alpha }(\mathbf {R} ){\frac {\partial g_{i}}{\partial R_{\alpha }}},} species-resource interactions are said to besymmetric. In the above equationai{\displaystyle a_{i}} andbα{\displaystyle b_{\alpha }} are arbitrary functions of resource abundances. When this symmetry condition is satisfied, it can be shown that there exists a functiond(R){\displaystyle d(\mathbf {R} )} such that:[7]dRα=hα(R)bα(R).{\displaystyle {\frac {\partial d}{\partial R_{\alpha }}}=-{\frac {h_{\alpha }(\mathbf {R} )}{b_{\alpha }(\mathbf {R} )}}.}After determining this functiond{\displaystyle d}, the steady-state uninvadable resource abundances and species populations are the solution to theconstrained optimization problem:minRd(R)s.t.,gi(R)0,i=1,,S,Rα0,α=1,,M.{\displaystyle {\begin{aligned}\min _{\mathbf {R} }&\;d(\mathbf {R} )&&\\{\text{s.t.,}}&\;g_{i}(\mathbf {R} )\leq 0,&&\qquad i=1,\dots ,S,\\&\;R_{\alpha }\geq 0,&&\qquad \alpha =1,\dots ,M.\end{aligned}}}The species populations are theLagrange multipliers for the constraints on the second line. This can be seen by looking at theKKT conditions, takingNi{\displaystyle N_{i}} to be the Lagrange multipliers:0=Nigi(R),i=1,,S,0=dRαi=1SNigiRα,α=1,,M,0gi(R),i=1,,S,0Ni,i=1,,S.{\displaystyle {\begin{aligned}0&=N_{i}g_{i}(\mathbf {R} ),&&\qquad i=1,\dots ,S,\\0&={\frac {\partial d}{\partial R_{\alpha }}}-\sum _{i=1}^{S}N_{i}{\frac {\partial g_{i}}{\partial R_{\alpha }}},&&\qquad \alpha =1,\dots ,M,\\0&\geq g_{i}(\mathbf {R} ),&&\qquad i=1,\dots ,S,\\0&\leq N_{i},&&\qquad i=1,\dots ,S.\end{aligned}}}Lines 1, 3, and 4 are the statements of feasibility and uninvadability: ifN¯i>0{\displaystyle {\overline {N}}_{i}>0}, thengi(R){\displaystyle g_{i}(\mathbf {R} )} must be zero otherwise the system would not be at steady state, and ifN¯i=0{\displaystyle {\overline {N}}_{i}=0}, thengi(R){\displaystyle g_{i}(\mathbf {R} )} must be non-positive otherwise speciesi{\displaystyle i} would be able to invade. Line 2 is the stationarity condition and the steady-state condition for the resources in nice CRMs. The functiond(R){\displaystyle d(\mathbf {R} )} can be interpreted as a distance by defining the point in the state space of resource abundances at which it is zero,R0{\displaystyle \mathbf {R} _{0}}, to be its minimum. TheLagrangian for thedual problem which leads to the above KKT conditions is,L(R,{Ni})=d(R)i=1SNigi(R).{\displaystyle L(\mathbf {R} ,\{N_{i}\})=d(\mathbf {R} )-\sum _{i=1}^{S}N_{i}g_{i}(\mathbf {R} ).} In this picture, the unconstrained value ofR{\displaystyle \mathbf {R} } that minimizesd(R){\displaystyle d(\mathbf {R} )} (i.e., the steady-state resource abundances in the absence of any consumers) is known as the resource supply vector.

Geometric perspectives

[edit]

The steady states of consumer resource models can be analyzed using geometric means in the space of resource abundances.[16][17][8]

Zero net-growth isoclines (ZNGIs)

[edit]

For a community to satisfy the uninvisibility and steady-state conditions, the steady-state resource abundances (denotedR{\displaystyle \mathbf {R} ^{\star }}) must satisfy,gi(R)0,{\displaystyle g_{i}(\mathbf {R} ^{\star })\leq 0,}for all speciesi{\displaystyle i}. The inequality is saturated if and only if speciesi{\displaystyle i} survives. Each of these conditions specifies a region in the space of possible steady-state resource abundances, and the realized steady-state resource abundance is restricted to the intersection of these regions. The boundaries of these regions, specified bygi(R)=0{\displaystyle g_{i}(\mathbf {R} ^{\star })=0}, are known as the zero net-growthisoclines (ZNGIs). If speciesi=1,,S{\displaystyle i=1,\dots ,S^{\star }}survive, then the steady-state resource abundances must satisfy,g1(R),,gS(R)=0{\displaystyle g_{1}(\mathbf {R} ^{\star }),\ldots ,g_{S^{\star }}(\mathbf {R} ^{\star })=0}. The structure and locations of the intersections of the ZNGIs thus determine what species and feasibly coexist; the realized steady-state community is dependent on the supply of resources and can be analyzed by examining coexistence cones.

Coexistence cones

[edit]

The structure of ZNGI intersections determines what species can feasibly coexist but does not determine what set of coexisting species will be realized. Coexistence cones determine what species determine what species will survive in an ecosystem given a resource supply vector. A coexistence cone generated by a set of speciesi=1,,S{\displaystyle i=1,\ldots ,S^{\star }} is defined to be the set of possible resource supply vectors which will lead to a community containing precisely the speciesi=1,,S{\displaystyle i=1,\ldots ,S^{\star }}.

To see the cone structure, consider that in the MacArthur or Tilman models, the steady-state non-depleted resource abundances must satisfy,K=R+i=1SNiCi,{\displaystyle \mathbf {K} =\mathbf {R} ^{\star }+\sum _{i=1}^{S}N_{i}\mathbf {C} _{i},} whereK{\displaystyle \mathbf {K} } is a vector containing the carrying capacities/supply rates, andCi=(ci1,,ciM){\displaystyle \mathbf {C} _{i}=(c_{i1},\ldots ,c_{iM^{\star }})} is thei{\displaystyle i}th row of the consumption matrixciα{\displaystyle c_{i\alpha }}, considered as a vector. As the surviving species are exactly those with positive abundances, the sum term becomes a sum only over surviving species, and the right-hand side resembles the expression for aconvex cone with apexR{\displaystyle \mathbf {R} ^{\star }} and whose generating vectors are theCi{\displaystyle \mathbf {C} _{i}} for the surviving speciesi{\displaystyle i}.

Complex ecosystems

[edit]

In an ecosystem with many species and resources, the behavior of consumer-resource models can be analyzed using tools from statistical physics, particularlymean-field theory and thecavity method.[18][19][20] In the large ecosystem limit, there is an explosion of the number of parameters. For example, in the MacArthur model,O(SM){\displaystyle O(SM)} parameters are needed. In this limit, parameters may be considered to be drawn from some distribution which leads to a distribution of steady-state abundances. These distributions of steady-state abundances can then be determined by deriving mean-field equations for random variables representing the steady-state abundances of a randomly selected species and resource.

MacArthur consumer resource model cavity solution

[edit]

In the MCRM, the model parameters can be taken to be random variables with means and variances:ciα=μ/M,var(ciα)=σ2/M,mi=m,var(mi)=σm2,Kα=K,var(Kα)=σK2.{\displaystyle \langle c_{i\alpha }\rangle =\mu /M,\quad \operatorname {var} (c_{i\alpha })=\sigma ^{2}/M,\quad \langle m_{i}\rangle =m,\quad \operatorname {var} (m_{i})=\sigma _{m}^{2},\quad \langle K_{\alpha }\rangle =K,\quad \operatorname {var} (K_{\alpha })=\sigma _{K}^{2}.}

With this parameterization, in the thermodynamic limit (i.e.,M,S{\displaystyle M,S\to \infty } withS/M=Θ(1){\displaystyle S/M=\Theta (1)}), the steady-state resource and species abundances are modeled as a random variable,N,R{\displaystyle N,R}, which satisfy the self-consistent mean-field equations,[18]0=R(KμSMNR+σK2+SMσ2N2ZR+σ2SMνR),0=N(μRmσ2χN+σ2R2+σm2ZN),{\displaystyle {\begin{aligned}0&=R(K-\mu {\tfrac {S}{M}}\langle N\rangle -R+{\sqrt {\sigma _{K}^{2}+{\tfrac {S}{M}}\sigma ^{2}\langle N^{2}\rangle }}Z_{R}+\sigma ^{2}{\tfrac {S}{M}}\nu R),\\0&=N(\mu \langle R\rangle -m-\sigma ^{2}\chi N+{\sqrt {\sigma ^{2}\langle R^{2}\rangle +\sigma _{m}^{2}}}Z_{N}),\end{aligned}}} whereN,N2,R,R2{\displaystyle \langle N\rangle ,\langle N^{2}\rangle ,\langle R\rangle ,\rangle R^{2}\rangle } are all moments which are determined self-consistently,ZR,ZN{\displaystyle Z_{R},Z_{N}} are independentstandard normal random variables, andν=N/m{\displaystyle \nu =\langle \partial N/\partial m\rangle } andχ=R/K{\displaystyle \chi =\langle \partial R/\partial K\rangle } are average susceptibilities which are also determined self-consistently.

This mean-field framework can determine the moments and exact form of the abundance distribution, the average susceptibilities, and the fraction of species and resources that survive at a steady state.

Similar mean-field analyses have been performed for the externally supplied resources model,[11] the Tilman model,[12] and the microbial consumer-resource model.[20] These techniques were first developed to analyze therandom generalized Lotka–Volterra model.

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^Chase, Jonathan M.; Leibold, Mathew A. (2003).Ecological Niches. University of Chicago Press.doi:10.7208/chicago/9780226101811.001.0001.ISBN 978-0-226-10180-4.
  2. ^Pimm, Stuart L. (September 1983)."TILMAN, D. 1982. Resource competition and community structure. Monogr. Pop. Biol. 17. Princeton University Press, Princeton, N.J. 296 p. $27.50".Limnology and Oceanography.28 (5):1043–1045.Bibcode:1983LimOc..28.1043P.doi:10.4319/lo.1983.28.5.1043.
  3. ^MacArthur, Robert (1970-05-01)."Species packing and competitive equilibrium for many species".Theoretical Population Biology.1 (1):1–11.doi:10.1016/0040-5809(70)90039-0.ISSN 0040-5809.PMID 5527624.
  4. ^Levins, Richard (1968).Evolution in Changing Environments: Some Theoretical Explorations. (MPB-2). Princeton University Press.doi:10.2307/j.ctvx5wbbh.ISBN 978-0-691-07959-2.JSTOR j.ctvx5wbbh.
  5. ^Goldford, Joshua E.; Lu, Nanxi; Bajić, Djordje; Estrela, Sylvie; Tikhonov, Mikhail; Sanchez-Gorostiaga, Alicia; Segrè, Daniel; Mehta, Pankaj; Sanchez, Alvaro (2018-08-03)."Emergent simplicity in microbial community assembly".Science.361 (6401):469–474.Bibcode:2018Sci...361..469G.doi:10.1126/science.aat1168.ISSN 0036-8075.PMC 6405290.PMID 30072533.
  6. ^Dal Bello, Martina; Lee, Hyunseok; Goyal, Akshit; Gore, Jeff (October 2021)."Resource–diversity relationships in bacterial communities reflect the network structure of microbial metabolism".Nature Ecology & Evolution.5 (10):1424–1434.Bibcode:2021NatEE...5.1424D.doi:10.1038/s41559-021-01535-8.hdl:1721.1/141887.ISSN 2397-334X.PMID 34413507.S2CID 256708107.
  7. ^abcdMarsland, Robert; Cui, Wenping; Mehta, Pankaj (2020-09-01)."The Minimum Environmental Perturbation Principle: A New Perspective on Niche Theory".The American Naturalist.196 (3):291–305.arXiv:1901.09673.doi:10.1086/710093.ISSN 0003-0147.PMID 32813998.S2CID 59316948.
  8. ^abcdefCui, Wenping; Marsland III, Robert; Mehta, Pankaj (2024-03-08). "Les Houches Lectures on Community Ecology: From Niche Theory to Statistical Mechanics".arXiv:2403.05497 [q-bio.PE].
  9. ^"Resource Competition and Community Structure. (MPB-17), Volume 17 | Princeton University Press".press.princeton.edu. 1982-08-21. Retrieved2024-03-18.
  10. ^Chase, Jonathan M.; Leibold, Mathew A.Ecological Niches: Linking Classical and Contemporary Approaches. Interspecific Interactions. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
  11. ^abcCui, Wenping; Marsland, Robert; Mehta, Pankaj (2020-07-21)."Effect of Resource Dynamics on Species Packing in Diverse Ecosystems".Physical Review Letters.125 (4): 048101.arXiv:1911.02595.Bibcode:2020PhRvL.125d8101C.doi:10.1103/PhysRevLett.125.048101.PMC 8999492.PMID 32794828.
  12. ^abCui, Wenping; Marsland, Robert; Mehta, Pankaj (2021-09-27)."Diverse communities behave like typical random ecosystems".Physical Review E.104 (3): 034416.Bibcode:2021PhRvE.104c4416C.doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.104.034416.PMC 9005152.PMID 34654170.
  13. ^Marsland, Robert; Cui, Wenping; Mehta, Pankaj (2020-02-24)."A minimal model for microbial biodiversity can reproduce experimentally observed ecological patterns".Scientific Reports.10 (1): 3308.arXiv:1904.12914.Bibcode:2020NatSR..10.3308M.doi:10.1038/s41598-020-60130-2.ISSN 2045-2322.PMC 7039880.PMID 32094388.
  14. ^Arthur, Robert Mac (December 1969)."Species Packing, and What Competition Minimizes".Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.64 (4):1369–1371.doi:10.1073/pnas.64.4.1369.ISSN 0027-8424.PMC 223294.PMID 16591810.
  15. ^MacArthur, Robert (1970-05-01)."Species packing and competitive equilibrium for many species".Theoretical Population Biology.1 (1):1–11.doi:10.1016/0040-5809(70)90039-0.ISSN 0040-5809.PMID 5527624.
  16. ^Mancuso, Christopher P; Lee, Hyunseok; Abreu, Clare I; Gore, Jeff; Khalil, Ahmad S (2021-09-03). Shou, Wenying; Walczak, Aleksandra M; Shou, Wenying (eds.)."Environmental fluctuations reshape an unexpected diversity-disturbance relationship in a microbial community".eLife.10: e67175.doi:10.7554/eLife.67175.ISSN 2050-084X.PMC 8460265.PMID 34477107.
  17. ^Tikhonov, Mikhail; Monasson, Remi (2017-01-27)."Collective Phase in Resource Competition in a Highly Diverse Ecosystem".Physical Review Letters.118 (4): 048103.arXiv:1609.01270.Bibcode:2017PhRvL.118d8103T.doi:10.1103/PhysRevLett.118.048103.PMID 28186794.
  18. ^abAdvani, Madhu; Bunin, Guy; Mehta, Pankaj (2018-03-20)."Statistical physics of community ecology: a cavity solution to MacArthur's consumer resource model".Journal of Statistical Mechanics: Theory and Experiment.2018 (3): 033406.Bibcode:2018JSMTE..03.3406A.doi:10.1088/1742-5468/aab04e.ISSN 1742-5468.PMC 6329381.PMID 30636966.
  19. ^Marsland, Robert; Cui, Wenping; Mehta, Pankaj (2020-02-24)."A minimal model for microbial biodiversity can reproduce experimentally observed ecological patterns".Scientific Reports.10 (1): 3308.arXiv:1904.12914.Bibcode:2020NatSR..10.3308M.doi:10.1038/s41598-020-60130-2.ISSN 2045-2322.PMC 7039880.PMID 32094388.
  20. ^abMehta, Pankaj; Marsland III, Robert (2021-10-10),Cross-feeding shapes both competition and cooperation in microbial ecosystems,arXiv:2110.04965

Further reading

[edit]
General
Producers
Consumers
Decomposers
Microorganisms
Food webs
Example webs
Processes
Defense,
counter
Ecology:Modelling ecosystems: Other components
Population
ecology
Species
Species
interaction
Spatial
ecology
Niche
Other
networks
Other
Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Consumer-resource_model&oldid=1285065507"
Categories:
Hidden categories:

[8]ページ先頭

©2009-2025 Movatter.jp