Bimetallism,[a] also known as thebimetallic standard, is amonetary standard in which the value of themonetary unit is defined as equivalent to certain quantities of two metals, typicallygold andsilver, creating a fixedrate of exchange between them.[3]
For scholarly purposes, "proper" bimetallism is sometimes distinguished as permitting that both gold and silver money arelegal tender in unlimited amounts and that gold and silver may be taken to be coined by thegovernment mints in unlimited quantities.[4] This distinguishes it from "limping standard" bimetallism, where both gold and silver are legal tender but only one is freely coined (e.g. the monies of France, Germany, and the United States after 1873), and from "trade" bimetallism, where both metals are freely coined but only one is legal tender and the other is used as "trade money" (e.g. most monies in western Europe from the 13th to 18th centuries). Economists also distinguishlegal bimetallism, where the law guarantees these conditions, andde facto bimetallism, where gold and silver coins circulate at a fixed rate.
During the 19th century there was a great deal of scholarly debate and political controversy regarding the use of bimetallism in place of agold standard orsilver standard (monometallism).[5][6] Bimetallism was intended to increase the supply of money, stabilize prices, and facilitate setting exchange rates.[7] Some scholars argued that bimetallism was inherently unstable owing toGresham's law, and that its replacement by a monometallic standard was inevitable. Other scholars claimed that in practice bimetallism had a stabilizing effect on economies. The controversy became largely moot aftertechnological progress and theSouth African andKlondike Gold Rushes increased the supply of gold in circulation at the end of the century, ending most of the political pressure for greater use of silver. It became completely academic after the 1971Nixon shock; since then, all of the world's currencies have operated as more or less freelyfloatingfiat money, unconnected to the value of silver or gold. Nonetheless, academics continue to debate, inconclusively, the relative use of the metallic standards.[b]
From the 7th centuryBCE,Asia Minor, especially in the areas ofLydia andIonia, is known to have created a coinage based onelectrum, a natural occurring material that is a variable mix of gold and silver (with about 54% gold and 44% silver). BeforeCroesus, his fatherAlyattes had already started to mint various types of non-standardized electrum coins. They were in use in Lydia and surrounding areas for about 80 years.[1] The unpredictability of its composition implied that it had a variable value which was very hard to determine, which greatly hampered its development.[1]
Croesus (reignedc. 560–c. 546 BCE), king of Lydia, who became associated with great wealth. Croesus is credited with issuing theCroeseid, the first truegold coins with a standardised purity for general circulation,[1]
Herodotus mentioned the innovation made by the Lydians:[1]
"So far as we have any knowledge, they [the Lydians] were the first people to introduce the use of gold and silver coins, and the first who sold goods by retail"
— Herodotus, I94[1]
Many ancient bimetallic systems would follow, starting withAchaemenid coinage. From around 515 BCE underDarius I, the minting of Croesids inSardis was replaced by the minting ofDarics andSigloi. The earliest gold coin of theAchaemenid Empire, theDaric, followed the weight standard of the Croeseid, and is therefore considered to be later and derived from the Croeseid.[14] The weight of the Daric would then be modified through a metrological reform, probably under Darius I.[14]
Sardis remained the central mint for the Persian Darics and Sigloi of Achaemenid coinage, and there is no evidence of other mints for the new Achaemenid coins during the whole time of the Achaemenid Empire.[15] Although the gold Daric became an international currency which was found throughout the Ancient world, the circulation of the Sigloi remained very much limited to Asia Minor: important hoards of Sigloi are only found in these areas, and finds of Sigloi beyond are always very limited and marginal compared to Greek coins, even in Achaemenid territories.[15]
In 1881, a currency reform inArgentina introduced a bimetallic standard, which went into effect in July 1883.[16] Units of gold and silverpesos would be exchanged with paper peso notes at given par values, and fixed exchange rates against key international currencies would thus be established.[16] Unlike many metallic standards, the system was very decentralized: no national monetary authority existed, and all control over convertibility rested with the five banks of issue.[16] This convertibility lasted only 17 months: from December 1884 the banks of issue refused to exchange gold at par for notes.[16] The suspension of convertibility was soon accommodated[clarification needed] by the Argentine government, since, having no institutional power over the monetary system, there was little they could do to prevent it.[16]
A French law of 1803 granted anyone who brought gold or silver to its mint the right to have it coined at a nominal charge in addition to the official rates of 200 francs per kilogram of 90% silver, or 3100 francs per kilogram of 90% fine gold.[17] This effectively established a bimetallic standard at the rate which had been used for French coinage since 1785, i.e. a relative valuation of gold to silver of 15.5 to 1. In 1803 this ratio was close to the market rate, but for most of the next half century the market rate was above 15.5 to 1.[17] As a consequence, silver powered the French economy and gold was exported. But when theCalifornia Gold Rush increased the supply of gold, its value was reduced relative to silver. The market rate fell below 15.5 to 1, and remained below until 1866. Frenchmen responded by exporting silver to India and importing nearly two-fifths of the world's production of gold in the period from 1848 to 1870.[18]Napoleon III introduced five franc gold coins which provided a substitute for the silver five franc coins which were hoarded,[19] but still maintained the formal bimetallism implicit in the 1803 law.
The national coinages introduced in Belgium (1832), Switzerland (1850), and Italy (1861) were based on France's bimetallic currency. These countries joined France in a treaty signed on 23 December 1865 which established theLatin Monetary Union (LMU).[18] Greece joined the LMU in 1868 and about twenty other countries adhered to its standards.[20] The LMU effectively adopted bimetallism by allowing unlimited free coinage of gold and silver at the 15.5 to 1 rate used in France, but also began to back away from bimetallism by allowing limited issues of low denomination silver coins struck to a lower standard for government accounts.[21] A surplus of silver led the LMU to limit free coinage of silver in 1874 and to end it in 1878, effectively abandoning bimetallism for the gold standard.[21]
Medieval and early modern England used both gold and silver, at fixed rates, to provide the necessary range of coin denominations; but silver coinage began to be restricted in the 18th century, first informally, and then by anAct of Parliament in 1774.[22] After the suspension of metal convertibility from 1797 to 1819,Peel's Bill set the country on the gold standard for the remainder of the century; however advocates of a return to bimetallism did not cease to appear. After the crash of 1825,William Huskisson argued strongly within the Government for bimetallism, as a way to increase credit (as well as to ease trade with South America).[23] Similarly, after the banking crisis of 1847,Alexander Baring headed an external bimetallist movement hoping to prevent the undue restriction of the currency.[24] It was, however, only in the last quarter of the century that the movement for bimetallism gathered real strength, drawing on Manchester cotton merchants and City financiers with Far East interests to offer a serious (if ultimately unsuccessful) challenge to the gold standard.[25]
In 1792, Secretary of the TreasuryAlexander Hamilton proposedfixing the silver to goldexchange rate at 15:1, as well as establishing themint for the public services offree coinage andcurrencyregulation "in order not to abridge the quantity of circulating medium".[26] With its acceptance,Sec.11 of theCoinage Act of 1792 established: "That the proportional value of gold to silver in all coins which shall by law be current as money within the United States, shall be as fifteen to one, according to quantity in weight, of pure gold or pure silver;" the proportion had slipped by1834 to sixteen to one. Silver took a further hit with theCoinage Act of 1853, when nearly all silver coin denominations were debased, effectively turning silver coinage into a fiduciary currency based on its face value rather than its weighted value. Bimetallism was effectively abandoned by theCoinage Act of 1873, but not formally outlawed as legal currency until the early 20th century. The merits of the system were the subject of debate in the late 19th century. If the market forces of supply and demand for either metal caused its bullion value to exceed its nominal currency value, ittends to disappear from circulation by hoarding or melting down.
In the United States, bimetallism became a center of political conflict toward the end of the 19th century. During theCivil War, to finance the war the U.S. switched from bimetallism to afiat money currency. After the war, in 1873, the government passed theFourth Coinage Act and soon resumption of specie payments began (without the free and unlimited coinage of silver, thus putting the U.S. on a mono-metallic gold standard.) Farmers, debtors, Westerners and others who felt they had benefited from wartime paper money formed the short-livedGreenback Party to press for cheap paper money backed by silver.[27] The latter element—"free silver"—came increasingly to the fore as the answer to the same interest groups' concerns, and was taken up as a central plank by thePopulist movement.[28] Proponents of monetary silver, known as thesilverites, referred back to the Fourth Coinage Act as "The Crime of '73", as it was judged to have inhibited inflation, and favored creditors over debtors. Some reformers, however, likeHenry Demarest Lloyd, saw bimetallism as a red herring and feared thatfree silver was "thecowbird of the reform movement", likely to push the other eggs out of the nest.[29] Nevertheless, thePanic of 1893, a severe nationwide depression, brought the money issue strongly to the fore again. The "silverites" argued that using silver would inflate the money supply and mean more cash for everyone, which they equated with prosperity. The gold advocates claimed that silver would permanently depress the economy, but thatsound money produced by agold standard would restore prosperity.
Bimetallism and "Free Silver" were demanded byWilliam Jennings Bryan who took over leadership of theDemocratic Party in 1896, as well as by the Populists. They were joined by a faction of Republicans from silver mining regions in the West, known as theSilver Republicans, who also endorsed Bryan.[30] TheRepublican Party itself nominatedWilliam McKinley on a platform supporting the gold standard, which was favored by financial interests on the East Coast.
In support of the cause, Bryan gave the famous"Cross of Gold" speech at the National Democratic Convention on July 9, 1896, asserting that "The gold standard has slain tens of thousands." He referred to "a struggle between 'the idle holders of idle capital' and 'the struggling masses, who produce the wealth and pay the taxes of the country;' and, my friends, the question we are to decide is: Upon which side will the Democratic party fight?" At theperoration, he said: "You shall not press down upon the brow of labor this crown of thorns, you shall not crucify mankind upon a cross of gold."[31] However, his presidential campaign was ultimately unsuccessful; this can be partially attributed to the discovery of thecyanide process by which gold could be extracted from low-grade ore. This process and the discoveries of large gold deposits in South Africa (Witwatersrand Gold Rush of 1887 – with large-scale production starting in 1898) and theKlondike Gold Rush (1896) increased the world gold supply and the subsequent increase in money supply that free coinage of silver was supposed to bring. The McKinley campaign was effective at persuading voters in the business East that poor economic progress and unemployment would be exacerbated by the adoption of the Bryan platform.[32] 1896 saw the election of McKinley. The direct link to gold was abandoned in 1934 inFranklin D. Roosevelt'sNew Deal program and later the link was broken byRichard Nixon when heclosed the gold window.
In 1992, economistMilton Friedman concluded that abandonment of the bimetallic standard in 1873 led to greater price instability than would have occurred otherwise, and thus resulted in long-term harm to the US economy. His retrospective analysis led him to write that the act of 1873 was "a mistake that had highly adverse consequences".[33]